How do we live together peaceably and justly? How do
we create a society with no victims?
Most of us, if asked, would say that we generally live
by the Golden Rule (the one that says "Do unto others as
you would have them do unto you," not the one that says
"he who has the most gold rules").
We teach it to our children. We look to it to help
us respond to day to day situations. We explain our
behavior with reference to it. But if you've read
widely on this website, you may reach the conclusion that
many of us operate with a rather superficial version of
the Golden Rule.
If you are familiar with the phrase "cognitive
dissonance," you may be finding that you are experiencing
some of that.
If your primary perspective is Christian, you may relate
this idea to the two commandments: Love God with
all your heart, and love your neighbor as yourself.
How does loving our neighbor as ourselves relate to our
individual and shared theories of justice, and then to
our constitution and laws and social and economic
system?
Henry George's ideas about taxing land values seem to
me to be the political economy implementation of the
golden rule.
Henry George: Thy Kingdom
Come (1889 speech)
... The story goes on to describe how
the roads of heaven, the streets of the New Jerusalem, were
filled with disconsolate tramp angels, who had pawned their
wings, and were outcasts in Heaven itself.
You laugh, and it is ridiculous. But
there is a moral in it that is worth serious thought. Is it
not ridiculous to imagine the application to God’s
heaven of the same rules of division that we apply to
God’s earth, even while we pray that His will may be
done on earth as it is done in Heaven?
Really, if we could imagine it, it is
impossible to think of heaven treated as we treat this
earth, without seeing that, no matter how salubrious were
its air, no matter how bright the light that filled it, no
matter how magnificent its vegetable growth, there would be
poverty, and suffering, and a division of classes in heaven
itself, if heaven were parcelled out as we have parceled
out the earth. And, conversely, if people were to act
towards each other as we must suppose the inhabitants of
heaven to do, would not this earth be a very
heaven?
“Thy kingdom come.” No one
can think of the kingdom for which the prayer asks without
feeling that it must be a kingdom of justice and equality
— not necessarily of equality in condition, but of
equality in opportunity. And no one can think of it without
seeing that a very kingdom of God might be brought on this
earth if people would but seek to do justice —
if people would but acknowledge the
essential principle of Christianity, that of doing to
others as we would have others do to us, and of recognising
that we are all here equally the children of the one
Father, equally entitled to share His bounty, equally
entitled to live our lives and develop our faculties, and
to apply our labour to the raw material that He has
provided. ... Read the whole
speech
Henry George: The Condition of Labor
— An Open Letter to Pope Leo XIII in response to
Rerum Novarum (1891)
Nor do we hesitate to say that this way of securing
the equal right to the bounty of the Creator and the
exclusive right to the products of labor is the way
intended by God for raising public revenues. For we are
not atheists, who deny God; nor semi-atheists, who deny
that he has any concern in politics and legislation.
It is true as you say — a salutary truth too
often forgotten — that “man is older than the
state, and he holds the right of providing for the life
of his body prior to the formation of any state.”
Yet, as you too perceive, it is also true that the state
is in the divinely appointed order. For He who foresaw
all things and provided for all things, foresaw and
provided that with the increase of population and the
development of industry the organization of human society
into states or governments would become both expedient
and necessary.
No sooner does the state arise than, as we all know,
it needs revenues. This need for revenues is small at
first, while population is sparse, industry rude and the
functions of the state few and simple. But with growth of
population and advance of civilization the functions of
the state increase and larger and larger revenues are
needed.
Now, He that made the world and placed man in it, He
that pre-ordained civilization as the means whereby man
might rise to higher powers and become more and more
conscious of the works of his Creator, must have foreseen
this increasing need for state revenues and have made
provision for it. That is to say: The increasing need for
public revenues with social advance, being a natural,
God-ordained need, there must be a right way of raising
them — some way that we can truly say is the way
intended by God. It is clear that this right way of
raising public revenues must accord with the moral
law.
Hence:
It must not take from individuals what rightfully
belongs to individuals.
It must not give some an advantage over others, as by
increasing the prices of what some have to sell and
others must buy.
It must not lead men into temptation, by requiring
trivial oaths, by making it profitable to lie, to swear
falsely, to bribe or to take bribes.
It must not confuse the distinctions of right and
wrong, and weaken the sanctions of religion and the state
by creating crimes that are not sins, and punishing men
for doing what in itself they have an undoubted right to
do.
It must not repress industry. It must not check
commerce. It must not punish thrift. It must offer no
impediment to the largest production and the fairest
division of wealth.
Let me ask your Holiness to consider the taxes on the
processes and products of industry by which through the
civilized world public revenues are collected — the
octroi duties that surround Italian cities with barriers;
the monstrous customs duties that hamper intercourse
between so-called Christian states; the taxes on
occupations, on earnings, on investments, on the building
of houses, on the cultivation of fields, on industry and
thrift in all forms. Can these be the ways God has
intended that governments should raise the means they
need? Have any of them the characteristics indispensable
in any plan we can deem a right one?
All these taxes violate the moral law. They take by
force what belongs to the individual alone; they give to
the unscrupulous an advantage over the scrupulous; they
have the effect, nay are largely intended, to increase
the price of what some have to sell and others must buy;
they corrupt government; they make oaths a mockery; they
shackle commerce; they fine industry and thrift; they
lessen the wealth that men might enjoy, and enrich some
by impoverishing others.
Yet what most strikingly shows how opposed to
Christianity is this system of raising public revenues is
its influence on thought.
Christianity teaches us that all men are
brethren; that their true interests are harmonious, not
antagonistic. It gives us, as the golden rule of life,
that we should do to others as we would have others do to
us. But out of the system of taxing the products
and processes of labor, and out of its effects in
increasing the price of what some have to sell and others
must buy, has grown the theory of
“protection,” which denies this gospel, which
holds Christ ignorant of political economy and proclaims
laws of national well-being utterly at variance with his
teaching. This theory sanctifies national
hatreds; it inculcates a universal war of hostile
tariffs; it teaches peoples that their prosperity lies in
imposing on the productions of other peoples restrictions
they do not wish imposed on their own; and instead of the
Christian doctrine of man’s brotherhood it makes
injury of foreigners a civic virtue.
“By their fruits ye shall know them.” Can
anything more clearly show that to tax the products and
processes of industry is not the way God intended public
revenues to be raised?
But to consider what we propose — the raising of
public revenues by a single tax on the value of land
irrespective of improvements — is to see that in
all respects this does conform to the moral law.
Let me ask your Holiness to keep in mind that the
value we propose to tax, the value of land irrespective
of improvements, does not come from any exertion of labor
or investment of capital on or in it — the values
produced in this way being values of improvement which we
would exempt. The value of land irrespective of
improvement is the value that attaches to land by reason
of increasing population and social progress. This is a
value that always goes to the owner as owner, and never
does and never can go to the user; for if the user be a
different person from the owner he must always pay the
owner for it in rent or in purchase-money; while if the
user be also the owner, it is as owner, not as user, that
he receives it, and by selling or renting the land he
can, as owner, continue to receive it after he ceases to
be a user.
Thus, taxes on land irrespective of improvement cannot
lessen the rewards of industry, nor add to prices,* nor
in any way take from the individual what belongs to the
individual. They can take only the value that attaches to
land by the growth of the community, and which therefore
belongs to the community as a whole.
* As to this point it may be well to add
that all economists are agreed that taxes on land
values irrespective of improvement or use — or
what in the terminology of political economy is styled
rent, a term distinguished from the ordinary use of the
word rent by being applied solely to payments for the
use of land itself — must be paid by the owner
and cannot be shifted by him on the user. To explain in
another way the reason given in the text: Price is not
determined by the will of the seller or the will of the
buyer, but by the equation of demand and supply, and
therefore as to things constantly demanded and
constantly produced rests at a point determined by the
cost of production — whatever tends to increase
the cost of bringing fresh quantities of such articles
to the consumer increasing price by checking supply,
and whatever tends to reduce such cost decreasing price
by increasing supply. Thus taxes on wheat or tobacco or
cloth add to the price that the consumer must pay, and
thus the cheapening in the cost of producing steel
which improved processes have made in recent years has
greatly reduced the price of steel. But land has no
cost of production, since it is created by God, not
produced by man. Its price therefore is fixed
—
1 (monopoly rent), where land is held
in close monopoly, by what the owners can extract
from the users under penalty of deprivation and
consequently of starvation, and amounts to all that
common labor can earn on it beyond what is necessary
to life;
2 (economic rent proper), where there is no special
monopoly, by what the particular land will yield to
common labor over and above what may be had by like
expenditure and exertion on land having no special
advantage and for which no rent is paid; and,
3 (speculative rent, which is a species of monopoly
rent, telling particularly in selling price), by the
expectation of future increase of value from social
growth and improvement, which expectation causing
landowners to withhold land at present prices has the
same effect as combination.
Taxes on land values or economic rent
can therefore never be shifted by the landowner to the
land-user, since they in no wise increase the demand
for land or enable landowners to check supply by
withholding land from use. Where rent depends on mere
monopolization, a case I mention because rent may in
this way be demanded for the use of land even before
economic or natural rent arises, the taking by taxation
of what the landowners were able to extort from labor
could not enable them to extort any more, since
laborers, if not left enough to live on, will die. So,
in the case of economic rent proper, to take from the
landowners the premiums they receive, would in no way
increase the superiority of their land and the demand
for it. While, so far as price is affected by
speculative rent, to compel the landowners to pay taxes
on the value of land whether they were getting any
income from it or not, would make it more difficult for
them to withhold land from use; and to tax the full
value would not merely destroy the power but the desire
to do so.
To take land values for the state, abolishing all
taxes on the products of labor, would therefore leave to
the laborer the full produce of labor; to the individual
all that rightfully belongs to the individual. It would
impose no burden on industry, no check on commerce, no
punishment on thrift; it would secure the largest
production and the fairest distribution of wealth, by
leaving men free to produce and to exchange as they
please, without any artificial enhancement of prices; and
by taking for public purposes a value that cannot be
carried off, that cannot be hidden, that of all values is
most easily ascertained and most certainly and cheaply
collected, it would enormously lessen the number of
officials, dispense with oaths, do away with temptations
to bribery and evasion, and abolish man-made crimes in
themselves innocent.
But, further: That God has intended the state to
obtain the revenues it needs by the taxation of land
values is shown by the same order and degree of evidence
that shows that God has intended the milk of the mother
for the nourishment of the babe.
See how close is the analogy. In that primitive
condition ere the need for the state arises there are no
land values. The products of labor have value, but in the
sparsity of population no value as yet attaches to land
itself. But as increasing density of population and
increasing elaboration of industry necessitate the
organization of the state, with its need for revenues,
value begins to attach to land. As population still
increases and industry grows more elaborate, so the needs
for public revenues increase. And at the same time and
from the same causes land values increase. The connection
is invariable. The value of things produced by labor
tends to decline with social development, since the
larger scale of production and the improvement of
processes tend steadily to reduce their cost. But the
value of land on which population centers goes up and up.
Take Rome or Paris or London or New York or Melbourne.
Consider the enormous value of land in such cities as
compared with the value of land in sparsely settled parts
of the same countries. To what is this due? Is it not due
to the density and activity of the populations of those
cities — to the very causes that require great
public expenditure for streets, drains, public buildings,
and all the many things needed for the health,
convenience and safety of such great cities? See how with
the growth of such cities the one thing that steadily
increases in value is land; how the opening of roads, the
building of railways, the making of any public
improvement, adds to the value of land. Is it not clear
that here is a natural law — that is to say a
tendency willed by the Creator? Can it mean anything else
than that He who ordained the state with its needs has in
the values which attach to land provided the means to
meet those needs?
That it does mean this and nothing else is confirmed
if we look deeper still, and inquire not merely as to the
intent, but as to the purpose of the intent. If we do so
we may see in this natural law by which land values
increase with the growth of society not only such a
perfectly adapted provision for the needs of society as
gratifies our intellectual perceptions by showing us the
wisdom of the Creator, but a purpose with regard to the
individual that gratifies our moral perceptions by
opening to us a glimpse of his beneficence.
Consider: Here is a natural law by which as society
advances the one thing that increases in value is land
— a natural law by virtue of which all growth of
population, all advance of the arts, all general
improvements of whatever kind, add to a fund that both
the commands of justice and the dictates of expediency
prompt us to take for the common uses of society. Now,
since increase in the fund available for the common uses
of society is increase in the gain that goes equally to
each member of society, is it not clear that the law by
which land values increase with social advance while the
value of the products of labor does not increase, tends
with the advance of civilization to make the share that
goes equally to each member of society more and more
important as compared with what goes to him from his
individual earnings, and thus to make the advance of
civilization lessen relatively the differences that in a
ruder social state must exist between the strong and the
weak, the fortunate and the unfortunate? Does it not show
the purpose of the Creator to be that the advance of man
in civilization should be an advance not merely to larger
powers but to a greater and greater equality, instead of
what we, by our ignoring of his intent, are making it, an
advance toward a more and more monstrous inequality?
...
For in this beautiful provision made by natural law
for the social needs of civilization we see that God has
intended civilization; that all our discoveries and
inventions do not and cannot outrun his forethought, and
that steam, electricity and labor-saving appliances only
make the great moral laws clearer and more important. In
the growth of this great fund, increasing with social
advance — a fund that accrues from the growth of
the community and belongs therefore to the community
— we see not only that there is no need for the
taxes that lessen wealth, that engender corruption, that
promote inequality and teach men to deny the gospel; but
that to take this fund for the purpose for which it was
evidently intended would in the highest civilization
secure to all the equal enjoyment of God’s bounty,
the abundant opportunity to satisfy their wants, and
would provide amply for every legitimate need of the
state. We see that God in his dealings with men has not
been a bungler or a niggard; that he has not brought too
many men into the world; that he has not neglected
abundantly to supply them; that he has not intended that
bitter competition of the masses for a mere animal
existence and that monstrous aggregation of wealth which
characterize our civilization; but that these evils which
lead so many to say there is no God, or yet more
impiously to say that they are of God’s ordering,
are due to our denial of his moral law. We see
that the law of justice, the law of the Golden Rule, is
not a mere counsel of perfection, but indeed the law of
social life. We see that if we were only to
observe it there would be work for all, leisure for all,
abundance for all; and that civilization would tend to
give to the poorest not only necessities, but all
comforts and reasonable luxuries as well. We see that
Christ was not a mere dreamer when he told men that if
they would seek the kingdom of God and its right-doing
they might no more worry about material things than do
the lilies of the field about their raiment; but that he
was only declaring what political economy in the light of
modern discovery shows to be a sober truth. ... read the whole
letter
Henry George: Thou
Shalt Not Steal (1887 speech)
The laws of this universe are the laws of God, the
social laws as well as the physical laws, and He, the
Creator of all, has given us room for all, work for all,
plenty for all.
- If today people are in places so crowded that
it seems as though there were too many people in the
world;
- if today thousands of men who would gladly be
at work do not find the opportunity to go to
work;
- if today the competition for employment crowds
wages down to starvation rates;
- if today, amidst abounding wealth, there are
in the centers of our civilization human beings who are
worse off than savages in any normal times, it is not because the Creator has been
niggardly; it is simply because
of our own injustice — simply because we have not
carried the idea of doing to others as we would have them
do unto us into the making of our
statutes.
The Anti-Poverty Society has no patent remedy for
poverty. We propose no new thing. What we propose is
simply to do justice. The principle that we propose to
carry into our laws is neither more nor less than the
golden rule. We propose to abolish poverty by the
sovereign remedy of doing to others as we would have
others do to us, by giving to all their just rights.
And we propose to begin by assuring to
every child of God who, in our country, comes into this
world, its full and equal share of the common
heritage.... read the whole
article
Henry George: The Wages of
Labor
What most strikingly shows how opposed
to Christianity is the existing system of raising public
revenue is its influence on thought.
Christianity teaches us that all men
are brethren; that their true interests are harmonious, not
antagonistic. It gives us, as the golden
rule of life, that we should do to others as we would have
others do to us. But, out of the system of taxing
the products and processes of labor, and out of its effects
in increasing the price of what some have to sell and
others must buy, has grown the theory of “Protection,” which denies this
gospel, which holds Christ ignorant of political economy,
and proclaims laws for the nation utterly at variance with
His teaching.
This theory sanctifies national
hatreds; it inculcates a universal war of hostile tariffs;
it teaches peoples that their prosperity lies in imposing
on the productions of other peoples restrictions they do
not wish imposed, on their own; and, instead of the Christian doctrine of man’s
brotherhood, it makes injury of foreigners a civic
virtue. ...
We see that the law of justice, the law of the
Golden Rule, is not a mere counsel of perfection, but
indeed the law of social life. We see that, if we were
only to observe it, there would be work for ail, leisure
for all, abundance for all; and that civilisation would
tend to give to the poorest not only necessaries, but all
reasonable comforts and luxuries.
We see that Christ was not a mere dreamer when He
told men that if they would seek the kingdom of God and
its right doing they might no more worry about material
things that do the lilies of the field about their
raiment; but that He was only declaring what political
economy in the light of modern discovery shows to be a
sober truth. ...
To persist in a wrong, to refuse to
undo it, is always to become involved in other
wrongs!
Those who defend private property in
land, and thereby deny the first and most important of all
human rights, the equal right to the material substratum of
life, are compelled to one of two courses. Either they must, as do those whose gospel is
“Devil take the hindmost,” deny the equal right
to life, and, by some theory like that to which
Malthus has given his name, assert that Nature brings into
the world more men than there is provision for; or, they
must, as do the Socialists, assert as rights what in
themselves are wrongs. ... read the whole
article
Nic Tideman:
Global
Economic Justice, followed by Creating Global Economic
Justice
The Functions of a Theory of
Justice
What is the use of a theory of justice? A theory
is an abstraction. By itself, it can't make anything
happen. But when a theory of justice
takes root in us, it modulates our emotional responses to
distributive outcomes. If you should come to realize that
the theory of justice to which you subscribe says that
something you thought you wanted to do is unjust, you
will find that course of action no longer so
appealing. If you come to a new realization that
justice is on your side, you are likely to feel
emboldened and ready to persist despite
obstructions.
If you should come to
the realization that justice requires of you a course of
action that you had not planned on, you will feel a pull in
that direction, and if you do not follow through, you are
likely to feel guilty. If your theory of justice
informs you that another person is treated unjustly, even a
stranger, you are likely to feel compassion for that
person, and you may also feel a chivalrous impulse to take
up that person's cause and seek redress of the injustice.
It was because of feelings of injustice that slavery was
abolished and women were granted the right to
vote.
As the world shrinks, nations impinge
upon one another in more and more ways, providing
applications for a theory of justice among
nations.... Read the
whole article
|
To share this page with a friend:
right click, choose "send," and add your
comments.
|
|
Red links have not been
visited; .
Green links are pages you've seen
|
Essential Documents pertinent
to this theme:
|
|