Desperado
despair, desperate, desperation,
de-spero
Desperate — literally, without hope.
On earth as it is in heaven, or hell on
earth for a significant portion of our society and
our planet-mates? Which will it be? And what are you
and I to do about it? (see also: serenity prayer,
courage, wisdom to know the difference, radical, young
martyrs.)
This theme comes out of a dance performance I saw at a
CGO meeting,
to the Eagles' song Desperado. While
interpretive dance doesn't normally "speak" to me, I
found this quite moving. And it set me to
thinking about the day-to-day realities of what our
severely tilted playing field does to individual human
beings. Some of us are buffered from it, some
benefit from it, but many more are at its mercy.
Some self-medicate legally with alcohol or nicotine;
others self-medicate with so-called "recreational"
drugs (the trade in which produces undesirable
results); and still others receive prescribed
medications (some with the cost shared by all their
fellow income-tax payers through tax
deductibility). The costs and effects of some of
these forms of self-medication drive people to
crime.
Some of us are homeless, some lack food. But many
more are simply not having enough income to be full
participants in our society, despite working full time
and beyond full time.
Some will argue that since many of the poor have color
TV's, ipods and air conditioners, and some years back
only the wealthiest had such things, they must not really
be poor. Henry George anticipated this argument as
follows (in a footnote quoted further down this
page):
It is true that the poorest may now in certain
ways enjoy what the richest a century ago could not
have commanded, but this does not show improvement of
condition so long as the ability to obtain the
necessaries of life is not increased. The beggar in a
great city may enjoy many things from which the
backwoods farmer is debarred, but that does not prove
the condition of the city beggar better than that of
the independent farmer.
Our tilted playing field is the direct result of
specific traditions and policies, and no amount of
charity can make up for the injustice those traditions
and policies produce.
"The mass of men lead lives of quiet desperation"
(Henry David Thoreau, 1817-1862, Walden). While
Thoreau was observing the scene a few years before George
was, perhaps he was speaking of the same phenomena that
George was writing about, without having seen the
systemic causes of much of that desperation. Can
we agree that if there is something we can do to
relieve the underlying causes of that
desperation — remedying an unjust system —
that to do so is our responsibility as human
beings?
Thoreau also said, "There are thousands hacking at the
branches of evil to one who is striking at the root."
Let's strike at the root of land monopoly.
H.G. Brown:
Significant Paragraphs from Henry George's
Progress & Poverty: 13 Effect
of Remedy Upon Social Ideals (in the unabridged
P&P:
Part IX: Effects of the Remedy — 4. Of the changes
that would be wrought in social organization and social
life)
From whence springs this lust for gain, to gratify
which men tread everything pure and noble under their
feet; to which they sacrifice all the higher
possibilities of life; which converts civility into a
hollow pretense, patriotism into a sham, and religion
into hypocrisy; which makes so much of civilized
existence an Ishmaelitish warfare, of which the weapons
are cunning and fraud?
Does it not spring from the existence of want? Carlyle
somewhere says that poverty is the hell of which the
modern Englishman is most afraid. And he is right.
Poverty is the openmouthed, relentless hell which yawns
beneath civilized society. And it is hell enough. The
Vedas declare no truer thing than when the wise crow
Bushanda tells the eagle-bearer of Vishnu that the
keenest pain is in poverty. For poverty is not merely
deprivation; it means shame, degradation; the searing of
the most sensitive parts of our moral and mental nature
as with hot irons; the denial of the strongest impulses
and the sweetest affections; the wrenching of the most
vital nerves. You love your wife, you love your children;
but would it not be easier to see them die than to see
them reduced to the pinch of want in which large classes
in every highly civilized community live? The strongest
of animal passions is that with which we cling to life,
but it is an everyday occurrence in civilized societies
for men to put poison to their mouths or pistols to their
heads from fear of poverty, and for one who does this
there are probably a hundred who have the desire, but are
restrained by instinctive shrinking, by religious
considerations, or by family ties.
From this hell of poverty, it is but natural that men
should make every effort to escape. With the impulse to
self-preservation and self-gratification combine nobler
feelings, and love as well as fear urges in the struggle.
Many a man does a mean thing, a dishonest thing, a greedy
and grasping and unjust thing, in the effort to place
above want, or the fear of want, mother or wife or
children.
And out of this condition of things arises a public
opinion which enlists, as an impelling power in the
struggle to grasp and to keep, one of the strongest
perhaps with many men the very strongest springs of human
action. The desire for approbation, the feeling that
urges us to win the respect, admiration, or sympathy of
our fellows, is instinctive and universal. Distorted
sometimes into the most abnormal manifestations, it may
yet be everywhere perceived. It is potent with the
veriest savage, as with the most highly cultivated member
of the most polished society; it shows itself with the
first gleam of intelligence, and persists to the last
breath. It triumphs over the love of ease, over the sense
of pain, over the dread of death. It dictates the most
trivial and the most important actions. ...
read the whole chapter
H.G. Brown:
Significant Paragraphs from Henry George's
Progress & Poverty: 14
Liberty, and Equality of Opportunity (in the unabridged
P&P:
Part X: The Law of Human Progress — Chapter 5: The
Central Truth)
The truth to which we were led in the
politico-economic branch of our inquiry is as clearly
apparent in the rise and fall of nations and the growth
and decay of civilizations, and it accords with those
deep-seated recognitions of relation and sequence that we
denominate moral perceptions. Thus are given to our
conclusions the greatest certitude and highest
sanction.
This truth involves both a menace and a promise. It
shows that the evils arising from the unjust and unequal
distribution of wealth, which are becoming more and more
apparent as modern civilization goes on, are not
incidents of progress, but tendencies which must bring
progress to a halt; that they will not cure themselves,
but, on the contrary, must, unless their cause is
removed, grow greater and greater, until they sweep us
back into barbarism by the road every previous
civilization has trod. But it also shows that these evils
are not imposed by natural laws; that they spring solely
from social maladjustments which ignore natural laws, and
that in removing their cause we shall be giving an
enormous impetus to progress.
The poverty which in the midst of abundance
pinches and embrutes men, and all the manifold evils
which flow from it, spring from a denial of justice. In
permitting the monopolization of the opportunities which
nature freely offers to all, we have ignored the
fundamental law of justice — for, so far as we can
see, when we view things upon a large scale, justice
seems to be the supreme law of the universe. But
by sweeping away this injustice and asserting the rights
of all men to natural opportunities, we shall conform
ourselves to the law —
- we shall remove the great cause of unnatural
inequality in the distribution of wealth and
power;
- we shall abolish poverty;
- tame the ruthless passions of greed;
- dry up the springs of vice and misery;
- light in dark places the lamp of knowledge;
- give new vigor to invention and a fresh impulse to
discovery;
- substitute political strength for political
weakness; and
- make tyranny and anarchy impossible. ...
Our primary social adjustment is a denial of justice.
In allowing one man to own the land on which and from
which other men must live, we have made them his bondsmen
in a degree which increases as material progress goes on.
This is the subtile alchemy that in ways they do not
realize is extracting from the masses in every civilized
country the fruits of their weary toil; that is
instituting a harder and more hopeless slavery in place
of that which has been destroyed; that is bringing
political despotism out of political freedom, and must
soon transmute democratic institutions into anarchy.
It is this that turns the blessings of material
progress into a curse. It is this that crowds human
beings into noisome cellars and squalid tenement houses;
that fills prisons and brothels; that goads men with want
and consumes them with greed; that robs women of the
grace and beauty of perfect womanhood; that takes from
little children the joy and innocence of life's
morning.
Civilization so based cannot continue. The eternal
laws of the universe forbid it. Ruins of dead empires
testify, and the witness that is in every soul answers,
that it cannot be. It is something grander than
Benevolence, something more august than Charity —
it is Justice herself that demands of us to right this
wrong. Justice that will not be denied; that cannot be
put off — Justice that with the scales carries the
sword. Shall we ward the stroke with liturgies and
prayers? Shall we avert the decrees of immutable law by
raising churches when hungry infants moan and weary
mothers weep?
Though it may take the language of prayer, it is
blasphemy that attributes to the inscrutable decrees of
Providence the suffering and brutishness that come of
poverty; that turns with folded hands to the All-Father
and lays on Him the responsibility for the want and crime
of our great cities. We degrade the Everlasting. We
slander the Just One. A merciful man would have better
ordered the world; a just man would crush with his foot
such an ulcerous ant-hill! It is not the Almighty, but we
who are responsible for the vice and misery that fester
amid our civilization. The Creator showers upon us his
gifts — more than enough for all. But like swine
scrambling for food, we tread them in the mire —
tread them in the mire, while we tear and rend each
other!
In the very centers of our civilization today are want
and suffering enough to make sick at heart whoever does
not close his eyes and steel his nerves. Dare we turn to
the Creator and ask Him to relieve it? Supposing the
prayer were heard, and at the behest with which the
universe sprang into being there should glow in the sun a
greater power; new virtue fill the air; fresh vigor the
soil; that for every blade of grass that now grows two
should spring up, and the seed that now increases
fiftyfold should increase a hundredfold! Would poverty be
abated or want relieved? Manifestly no! Whatever benefit
would accrue would be but temporary. The new powers
streaming through the material universe could be utilized
only through land.
This is not merely a deduction of political economy;
it is a fact of experience. We know it because we have
seen it. Within our own times, under our very eyes, that
Power which is above all, and in all, and through all;
that Power of which the whole universe is but the
manifestation; that Power which maketh all things, and
without which is not anything made that is made, has
increased the bounty which men may enjoy, as truly as
though the fertility of nature had been increased. Into
the mind of one came the thought that harnessed steam for
the service of mankind. To the inner ear of another was
whispered the secret that compels the lightning to bear a
message round the globe. In every direction have the laws
of matter been revealed; in every department of industry
have arisen arms of iron and fingers of steel, whose
effect upon the production of wealth has been precisely
the same as an increase in the fertility of nature. What
has been the result? Simply that landowners get all the
gain. ...
read the whole chapter
Henry George: The Land Question
(1881)
Distress and Famine
BUT it will be asked: If the land system which
prevails in Ireland is essentially the same as that which
prevails elsewhere, how is it that it does not produce
the same results elsewhere?
I answer that it does everywhere
produce the same kind of results. As there is nothing
essentially peculiar in the Irish land system, so is there
nothing essentially peculiar in Irish distress. Between the
distress in Ireland and the distress in other countries
there may be differences in degree and differences in
manifestation; but that is all.
The truth is, that as there is
nothing peculiar in the Irish land system, so is there
nothing peculiar in the distress which that land system
causes. We hear a great deal of Irish emigration, of the
millions of sons and daughters of Erin who have been
compelled to leave their native soil. But have not the
Scottish Highlands been all but depopulated? Do not the
English emigrate in the same way, and for the same reasons?
Do not the Germans and Italians and Scandinavians also
emigrate? Is there not a constant emigration from the
Eastern States of the Union to the Western – an
emigration impelled by the same motives as that which sets
across the Atlantic? Nor am I sure that this is not in some
respects a more demoralizing emigration than the Irish, for
I do not think there is any such monstrous disproportion of
the sexes in Ireland as in Massachusetts. If French and
Belgian peasants do not emigrate as do the Irish, is it not
simply because they do not have such "long
families"?
There has recently been deep and
wide-spread distress in Ireland, and but for the
contributions of charity many would have perished for want
of food. But, to say nothing of such countries as India,
China, Persia, and Syria, is it not true that within the
last few years there have been similar spasms of distress
in the most highly civilized countries – not merely
in Russia and in Poland, but in Germany and England? Yes,
even in the United States.
Have there not been, are there not
constantly occurring, in all these countries, times when
the poorest classes are reduced to the direct straits, and
large numbers are saved from starvation only by
charity?
When there is famine among savages it
is because food enough is not to be had. But this was not
the case in Ireland. In any part of Ireland, during the
height of what was called the famine, there was food enough
for whoever had means to pay for it. The trouble was not in
the scarcity of food. There was, as a matter of fact, no
real scarcity of food, and the proof of it is that food did
not command scarcity prices. During all the so-called
famine, food was constantly exported from Ireland to
England, which would not have been the case had there been
true famine in one country any more than in the other.
During all the so-called famine a practically unlimited
supply of American meat and grain could have been poured
into Ireland, through the existing mechanism of exchange,
so quickly that the relief would have been felt
instantaneously. Our sending of supplies in a national
war-ship was a piece of vulgar ostentation, fitly
paralleled by their ostentatious distribution in British
gunboats under the nominal superintendence of a royal
prince. Had we been bent on relief, not display, we might
have saved our government the expense of fitting up its
antiquated warship, the British gunboats their coal, the
Lord Mayor his dinner, and the Royal Prince his valuable
time. A cable draft, turned in Dublin into postal orders,
would have afforded the relief, not merely much more easily
and cheaply, but in less time than it took our war-ship to
get ready to receive her cargo; for the reason that so many
of the Irish people were starving was, not that the food
was not to be had, but that they had not the means to buy
it. Had the Irish people had money or its equivalent, the
bad seasons might have come and gone without stinting any
one of a full meal. Their effect would merely have been to
determine toward Ireland the flow of more abundant
harvests.
I wish clearly to bring to view this
point. The Irish famine was not a true famine arising from
scarcity of food. It was what an English writer styled the
Indian famine – a "financial famine," arising not
from scarcity of food but from the poverty of the people.
The effect of the short crops in producing distress was not
so much in raising the price of food as in cutting off the
accustomed incomes of the people. The masses of the Irish
people get so little in ordinary times that they are barely
able to live, and when anything occurs to interrupt their
accustomed incomes they have nothing to fall back
on.
Yet is this not true of large classes
in all countries? And are not all countries subject to just
such famines as this Irish famine? Good seasons and bad
seasons are in the order of nature, just as the day of
sunshine and the day of rain, the summer's warmth and the
winter's snow. But agriculture is, on the whole, as certain
as any other pursuit, for even those industries which may
be carried en regardless of weather are subject to
alternations as marked as those to which agriculture is
liable. There are good seasons and bad seasons even in
fishing and hunting, while the alternations are very marked
in mining and in manufacturing. In fact, the more highly
differentiated branches of industry which advancing
civilization tends to develop, though less directly
dependent upon rain and sunshine, heat and cold, seem
increasingly subject to alternations more frequent and
intense. Though in a country of more diversified industry
the failure of a crop or two could not have such
wide-spread effects as in Ireland, yet the countries of
more complex industries are liable to a greater variety of
disasters. A war on another continent produces famine in
Lancashire; Parisian milliners decree a change of fashion,
and Coventry operatives are saved from starvation only by
public alms; a railroad combination decides to raise the
price of coal, and Pennsylvania miners find their earnings
diminished by half or totally cut off; a bank breaks in New
York, and in all the large American cities soup-houses must
be opened!
In this Irish famine which provoked
the land agitation, there is nothing that is peculiar. Such
famines on a smaller or a larger scale are constantly
occurring. Nay, more! the fact is, that famine, just such
famine as this Irish famine, constantly exists in the
richest and most highly civilized lands. It persists even
in "good times" 'when trade is "booming;" it spreads and
rages whenever from any cause industrial depression comes.
It is kept under, or at least kept from showing its worst
phases, by poor-rates and almshouses, by private
benevolence and by vast organized charities, but it still
exists, gnawing in secret when it does not openly rage. In
the very centers of civilization, where the machinery of
production and exchange is at the highest point of
efficiency, where bankvaults hold millions, and
show-windows flash with more than a prince's ransom, where
elevators and warehouses are gorged with grain, and markets
are piled with all things succulent and toothsome, where
the dinners of Lucullus are eaten every day, and, if it be
but cool, the very greyhounds wear dainty blankets–in
these centers in wealth and power and refinement, there are
always hungry men and women and little children. Never the
sun goes down but on human beings prowling like wolves far
food, or huddling together like vermin for shelter and
warmth. "Always with You" is the significant heading under
which a New York paper, in these most prosperous times,
publishes daily the tales of chronic famine; and in the
greatest and richest city in the world – in that very
London where the plenty of meat in the butchers' shops
seemed to some savages the most wondrous of all its
wonderful sights – in that very London, the mortuary
reports have a standing column for deaths by
starvation.
But no more in its chronic than in
its spasmodic forms is famine to be measured by the deaths
from starvation. Perfect, indeed, in all its parts must be
the human machine if it can run till the last bit of
available tissue be drawn to feed its fires. It is under
the guise of disease to which physicians can give less
shocking names, that famine – especially the chronic
famine of civilization – kills. And the statistics of
mortality, especially of infant mortality, show that in the
richest communities famine is constantly at its work.
Insufficient nourishment, inadequate warmth and clothing,
and unwholesome surroundings, constantly, in the very
centers of plenty, swell the death-rates. What is this but
famine – just such famine as the Irish famine? It is
not that the needed things are really scarce; but that
those whose need is direst have not the means to get them,
and, when not relieved by charity, want kills them in its
various ways. When, in the hot midsummer, little children
die like flies in the New York tenement wards, what is that
but famine? And those barges crowded with such children
that a noble and tender charity sends down New York Harbor
to catch the fresh salt breath of the Antlantic – are
they not fighting famine as truly as were our food-laden
war-ship and the Royal Prince's gunboats? Alas! to find
famine one has not to cross the sea.
There was bitter satire in the
cartoon that one of our illustrated papers published when
subscriptions to the Irish famine fund were being made
– a cartoon that represented James Gordon Bennett
sailing away for Ireland in a boat loaded down with
provisions, while a sad-eyed, hungry-looking, tattered
group gazed wistfully on them from the pier. The bite and
the bitterness of it, the humiliating sting and satire of
it, were in its truth.
This is "the home of freedom," and
"the asylum of the oppressed;" our population is yet
sparse, our public domain yet wide; we are the greatest of
food producers, yet even here there are beggars, tramps,
paupers, men torn by anxiety for the support of their
families, women who know not which way to turn, little
children growing up in such poverty and squalor that only a
miracle can keep them pure. "Always with you," even here.
What is the week or the day of the week that our
papers do not tell of man or woman who, to escape the
tortures of want, has stepped out of life unbidden? What is
this but famine?...read the
whole article Henry George: The Crime of
Poverty (1885 speech)
Poverty is the mother of ignorance, the breeder of
crime. I walked down one of your streets this morning,
and I saw three men going along with their hands chained
together. I knew for certain that those men were not rich
men; and, although I do not know the offence for which
they were carried in chains through your streets, this I
think I can safely say, that, if you trace it up you will
find it in some way to spring from poverty. Nine tenths
of human misery, I think you will find, if you look, to
be due to poverty. ... And it seems to me clear
that the great majority of those who suffer from poverty
are poor not from their own particular faults, but
because of conditions imposed by society at large.
Therefore I hold that poverty is a crime – not an
individual crime, but a social crime, a crime for which
we all, poor as well as rich, are responsible. ...
read the whole speech
Louis Post: Outlines
of Louis F. Post's Lectures, with Illustrative Notes and
Charts (1894)
Note 14: Land values are lower in all
countries of poor government than in any country of
better government, other things being equal. They are
lower in cities of poor government, other things being
equal, than in cities of better government. Land values
are lower, for example, in Juarez, on the Mexican side of
the Rio Grande, where government is bad, than in El Paso,
the neighboring city on the American side, where
government is better. They are lower in the same city
under bad government than under improved government. When
Seth Low, after a reform campaign, was elected mayor of
Brooklyn, N.Y., rents advanced before he took the oath of
office, upon the bare expectation that he would eradicate
municipal abuses. Let the city authorities anywhere pave
a street, put water through it and sewer it, or do any of
these things, and lots in the neighborhood rise in value.
Everywhere that the "good roads" agitation of wheel men
has borne fruit in better highways, the value of adjacent
land has increased. Instances of this effect as results
of public improvements might be collected in abundance.
Every man must be able to recall some within his own
experience.
And it is perfectly reasonable that it
should be so. Land and not other property must rise in
value with desired improvements in government, because,
while any tendency on the part of other kinds of property
to rise in value is checked by greater production, land
can not be reproduced.
Imagine an utterly lawless place, where
life and property are constantly threatened by
desperadoes. He must be either a very bold man or a very
avaricious one who will build a store in such a community
and stock it with goods; but suppose such a man should
appear. His store costs him more than the same building
would cost in a civilized community; mechanics are not
plentiful in such a place, and materials are hard to get.
The building is finally erected, however, and stocked.
And now what about this merchant's prices for goods?
Competition is weak, because there are few men who will
take the chances he has taken, and he charges all that
his customers will pay. A hundred per cent, five hundred
per cent, perhaps one or two thousand per cent profit
rewards him for his pains and risk. His goods are dear,
enormously dear — dear enough to satisfy the most
contemptuous enemy of cheapness; and if any one should
wish to buy his store that would be dear too, for the
difficulties in the way of building continue. But
land is cheap! This is the type of community in
which may be found that land, so often mentioned and so
seldom seen, which "the owners actually can't give away,
you know!"
But suppose that government improves. An
efficient administration of justice rids the place of
desperadoes, and life and property are safe. What about
prices then? It would no longer require a bold or
desperately avaricious man to engage in selling goods in
that community, and competition would set in. High
profits would soon come down. Goods would be cheap
— as cheap as anywhere in the world, the cost of
transportation considered. Builders and building
materials could be had without difficulty, and stores
would be cheap, too. But land would be dear!
Improvement in government increases the value of that,
and of that alone.
... read the
book
John
Dewey: Steps to
Economic Recovery
I do not claim that George's remedy is a panacea that
will cure by itself all our ailments. But I do claim that
we cannot get rid of our basic troubles without it. I
would make exactly the same concession and same claim
that Henry George himself made:
"I do not say that in the recognition of the equal
and unalienable right of each human being to the
natural elements from which life must be supported and
wants satisfied, lies the solution of all social
problems. I fully recognize that even after we do this,
much will remain to do. We might recognize the equal
right to land, and yet tyranny and spoilation be
continued. But whatever else we do, as along as we fail
to recognize the equal right to the elements of nature,
nothing will avail to remedy that unnatural inequality
in the distribution of wealth which is fraught with so
much evil and danger. Reform as we may, until we make
this fundamental reform, our material progress can but
tend to differentiate our people into the monstrously
rich and frightfully poor. Whatever be the increase of
wealth, the masses will still be ground toward the
point of bare subsistence -- we must still have our
great criminal classes, our paupers and our tramps, men
and women driven to degradation and desperation from
inability to make an honest living." ... read the whole speech
Walter Rybeck: What
Affordable Housing Problem?
Like all creatures — goldfinches, squirrels,
butterflies, cicadas — we humans are squatters on
this planet. We all need a part of earth for shelter,
nourishment, a work site and a place to raise the next
generation. Otherwise we perish. ...
In the 1980s, Washington, D.C., was concerned
about its growing army of homeless. At that time I found
there were 8,000 boarded-up dwelling units in our
Nation's Capital — more than enough to accommodate
some 5,000 street people. I also found there were 11,500
privately owned vacant lots in the District of Columbia,
mostly zoned for and suitable for homes or apartments.
Decent housing on these sites held in cold storage would
have provided an alternative for the many low-income
families squatting in places that were overcrowded,
overpriced, overrun with vermin and overloaded with
safety hazards.
These issues spurred my research described in a
1988 report, "Affordable Housing
— A Missing Link." Evidence from the Census
Bureau, Bureau of Labor Statistics and other sources over
a 30-year period revealed the following average cost
increases of items that go into the building and
maintenance of housing:
- Wages of general building construction workers
rose 14 percent a year.
- Wages of special trade construction workers
rose 11 percent a year.
- Construction material costs rose 11.5 percent
a year.
- Combined wage-materials-managerial costs for
residential building rose 12.5 percent a
year.
- Fuel and utility costs for housing rose 13.8
percent a year. All of these costs closely tracked the
Consumer Price Index which, over these same 30 years,
rose by 12 percent a year. According to those figures,
housing prices and housing rents apparently were held in
check
Why do those statistics not seem to jibe with what
you have been told, seen with your own eyes, and felt in
your own pocketbooks?
- How to explain that, during the last decade of
my research period, U.S. households with serious housing
problems increased from 19 to 24 millions?
- What caused the portion of renters paying more
than 35 percent of their income for housing doubled from
21 to 41 percent during the last two decades of the study
period?
- Why were over 2.4 million renters paying 60
percent or more of their income for rent?
The answers would be obvious except that, so far,
I have not mentioned what happened to the price of the
land that housing sits on. Many of those who talk and
write about housing conveniently overlook the fact that
housing does not exist in mid air but is attached to the
land, and that the price of this land has gone through
the stratosphere.
In contrast to those 11- to
14-percent annual increases in housing-related costs,
residential land values nationwide rose almost 80 percent
a year, or almost 2000 percent over those three
decades. ...
A close friend in Bethesda bought a house and lot
there 40 years ago for $20,000. Two months ago he sold
the property for a cool half million. That 2400 percent
increase was entirely land value. The buyer immediately
demolished the house to put up a larger one, so he
clearly paid half a million for the location value -- the
land value -- alone.
Officials, civic leaders and commentators who
bemoan the lack of affordable housing nevertheless
applaud each rise in real estate values as a sign of
prosperity. Seeing their own assets multiply through no
effort of their own apparently makes them forget the
teachers, firemen, police and low-income people who are
boxed out of a place to squat in their cities and
neighborhoods. ...
Many of our Founding Fathers,
George Washington included, had amassed huge estates. But
the property tax induced them to sell off excess lands
they were not using. ...
One of the many virtues of a tax
on land values is that it can be introduced gradually.
Cities that take this incremental approach report that
homeowners-voters-taxpayers hardly notice the
change. What's important in
modernizing your taxation is not the speed of change but
the direction you choose. If you keep the present
tax system with its disincentives for compact and
wholesome growth, you will experience the treadmill
effect that has been so familiar in so-called urban and
housing "solutions." You will have to keep running faster
and faster with patchwork remedies to keep from sliding
backward.
A caution. Revising taxes as
proposed here will not end the need for housing
subsidies, at least not in the short run, but it will do
three things that should greatly reduce
subsidies.
- One, by deflating land costs it will enable
the private market to offer homes and sites at lower
costs.
- Two, this will shrink the number of families
needing subsidies.
- Three, it will stretch subsidy dollars farther
because sites for publicly assisted housing can be
acquired far more cheaply.
In Conclusion, I have tried to show that
America has a housing land problem, not
an affordable housing problem. This problem can be
substantially alleviated by freeing the market of
anti-enterprise taxes and by turning the
property tax right side up -- that is, by dropping tax
rates on housing and by raising them on publicly-created
land values. Read the whole
article
Henry George:
How to Help the Unemployed
Henry George: Justice
the Object -- Taxation the Means (1890)
Now see, take it in its lowest aspect — take
it as a mere fiscal change, and see how in accord with
every dictate of expediency, with every principle of
justice, is the Single Tax. We have invented and
invented, improved and improved, yet the great fact is,
that today we have not wealth enough. There are in the United States some few men richer
than it is wholesome for men to be. But the great masses
of our people are not so rich as civilised Americans at
the close of the nineteenth century ought to be.
The great mass of our people only manage by hard work to
live. The great mass of our people
don't get the comforts, the refinements, the luxuries
that in the present age of the world everyone ought to
have. All over this country there is a fierce struggle
for existence.
Read the entire article
Henry George:
Progress & Poverty:
Introductory: The Problem
Now, however, we are coming into collision with facts
which there can be no mistaking. From all parts of the
civilized world come complaints;
- of industrial depression;
- of labor condemned to involuntary idleness;
- of capital massed and wasting;
- of pecuniary distress among business men;
- of want and suffering and anxiety among the working
classes.
All the dull, deadening pain, all the keen, maddening
anguish, that to great masses of men are involved in the
words "hard times," afflict the world today. This
state of things, common to communities differing so
widely in situation, in political institutions, in fiscal
and financial systems, in density of population and in
social organization can hardly be accounted for by local
causes.
- There is distress where large standing armies are
maintained, but there is also distress where the
standing armies are nominal;
- there is distress where protective tariffs stupidly
and wastefully hamper trade, but there is also distress
where trade is nearly free;
- there is distress where autocratic government yet
prevails, but there is also distress where political
power is wholly in the hands of the people;
- in countries where paper is money, and
- in countries where gold and silver are the only
currency.
Evidently, beneath all such things as these, we must
infer a common cause.
That there is a common cause, and that it is either
what we call material progress or something closely
connected with material progress, becomes more than an
inference when it is noted that the phenomena we class
together and speak of as industrial depression, are but
intensifications of phenomena which always accompany
material progress, and which show themselves more clearly
and strongly as material progress goes on. Where
the conditions to which material progress everywhere
tends are most fully realized--that is to say, where
population is densest, wealth greatest, and the machinery
of production and exchange most highly developed--we find
the deepest poverty, the sharpest struggle for existence,
and the most enforced idleness.
It is to the newer countries — that is, to the
countries where material progress is yet in its earlier
stages — that laborers emigrate in search of higher
wages, and capital flows in search of higher interest. It
is in the older countries — that is to say, the
countries where material progress has reached later
stages — that widespread destitution is found in
the midst of the greatest abundance. Go into one of the
new communities where Anglo-Saxon vigor is just beginning
the race of progress;
- where the machinery of production and exchange is
yet rude and inefficient;
- where the increment of wealth is not yet great
enough to enable any class to live in ease and
luxury;
- where the best house is but a cabin of logs or a
cloth and paper shanty, and the richest man is forced
to daily work
and though you will find an absence of wealth and all
its concomitants, you will find no beggars. There is no
luxury, but there is no destitution. No one makes an easy
living, nor a very good living; but every one can make a
living, and no one able and willing to work is oppressed
by the fear of want.
But just as such a community realizes the
conditions which all civilized communities are striving
for, and advances in the scale of material progress
— just as closer settlement and a more intimate
connection with the rest of the world, and greater
utilization of labor-saving machinery, make possible
greater economies in production and exchange, and wealth
in consequence increases, not merely in the aggregate,
but in proportion to population— so does poverty
take a darker aspect. Some get an infinitely
better and easier living, but others find it hard to get
a living at. The "tramp" comes
with the locomotive, and alms houses and prisons areas
surely the marks of "material progress" as are costly
dwellings, rich warehouses, and magnificent churches.
Upon streets lighted with gas and controlled by uniformed
policemen, beggars wait for the passer-by, and in the
shadow of college, and library, and museum, are gathering
the more hideous Huns and fiercer Vandals of whom
Macaulay prophesied.
This fact — the great fact that
poverty and all its concomitants show themselves in
communities just as they develop into the conditions
towards which material progress tends — proves that
the social difficulties existing wherever a certain stage
of progress has been reached, do not arise from local
circumstances, but are, in some way or another,
engendered by progress itself.
And, unpleasant as it may be to admit it, it is at
last becoming evident that the enormous increase in
productive power which has marked the present century and
is still going on with accelerating ratio, has no
tendency to extirpate poverty or to lighten the burdens
of those compelled to toil. It simply widens the gulf
between Dives
and Lazarus, and makes the struggle for existence
more intense. The march of invention has clothed mankind
with powers of which a century ago the boldest
imagination could not have dreamed. But
- in factories where labor-saving machinery has
reached its most wonderful development, little children
are at work;
- wherever the new forces are anything like fully
utilized, large classes are maintained by charity or
live on the verge of recourse to it;
- amid the greatest accumulations of wealth, men die
of starvation, and puny infant suckle dry breasts;
- while everywhere the greed of gain, the worship of
wealth, shows the force of the fear of want.
The promised land flies before us like the mirage. The
fruit of the tree of knowledge turn as we grasp them to
apples of Sodom that crumble at the touch.
It is true that wealth has been greatly increased, and
that the average of comfort, leisure, and refinement has
been raised; but these gains are not general. In them the lowest
class do not share.* I do not mean that the condition of
the lowest class has nowhere nor in anything been
improved; but that there is nowhere any improvement which
can be credited to increased productive power. I mean
that the tendency of what we call material progress is in
no wise to improve the condition of the lowest class in
the essentials of healthy, happy human life. Nay,
more, that it is to still further depress the condition
of the lowest class. The new forces, elevating in
their nature though they be, do not act upon the social
fabric from underneath, as was for a long time hoped and
believed, but strike it at a point intermediate between
top and bottom. It is as though an immense wedge were
being forced, not underneath society, but through
society. Those who are above the point of separation are
elevated, but those who are below are crushed down.
[* It is true that the poorest may now
in certain ways enjoy what the richest a century ago
could not have commanded, but this does not show
improvement of condition so long as the ability to
obtain the necessaries of life is not increased. The
beggar in a great city may enjoy many things from
which the backwoods farmer is debarred, but that does
not prove the condition of the city beggar better
than that of the independent farmer.]
This depressing effect is not generally realized, for
it is not apparent where there has long existed a class
just able to live. Where the lowest class barely lives,
as has been the case for a long time in many parts of
Europe, it is impossible for it to get any lower, for the
next lowest step is out of existence, and no tendency to
further depression can readily show itself. But in the
progress of new settlements to the conditions of older
communities it may clearly be seen that material progress
does not merely fail to relieve poverty--it actually
produces it. In the United States it is clear that
squalor and misery, and the vices and crimes that spring
from them, everywhere increase as the village grows to
the city, and the march of development brings the
advantages of the improved methods of production and
exchange. It is in the older and richer sections of
the Union that pauperism and distress among the working
classes are becoming most painfully apparent. If there
is less deep poverty in San Francisco than in New York,
is it not because San Francisco is yet behind New York in
all that both cities are striving for? When San Francisco
reaches the point where New York now is, who can doubt
that there will also be ragged and barefooted children on
her streets? ...
read the entire chapter
Henry George: The Condition of Labor
— An Open Letter to Pope Leo XIII in response to
Rerum Novarum (1891)
That the value attaching to land with social growth is
intended for social needs is shown by the final proof.
God is indeed a jealous God in the sense that nothing but
injury and disaster can attend the effort of men to do
things other than in the way he has intended; in the
sense that where the blessings he proffers to men are
refused or misused they turn to evils that scourge us.
And just as for the mother to withhold the provision that
fills her breast with the birth of the child is to
endanger physical health, so for society to refuse to
take for social uses the provision intended for them is
to breed social disease.
For refusal to take for public purposes the increasing
values that attach to land with social growth is to
necessitate the getting of public revenues by taxes that
lessen production, distort distribution and corrupt
society. It is to leave some to take what justly belongs
to all; it is to forego the only means by which it is
possible in an advanced civilization to combine the
security of possession that is necessary to improvement
with the equality of natural opportunity that is the most
important of all natural rights. It is thus at the basis
of all social life to set up an unjust inequality between
man and man, compelling some to pay others for the
privilege of living, for the chance of working, for the
advantages of civilization, for the gifts of their God.
But it is even more than this. The very robbery that the
masses of men thus suffer gives rise in advancing
communities to a new robbery. For the value that with the
increase of population and social advance attaches to
land being suffered to go to individuals who have secured
ownership of the land, it prompts to a forestalling of
and speculation in land wherever there is any prospect of
advancing population or of coming improvement, thus
producing an artificial scarcity of the natural elements
of life and labor, and a strangulation of production that
shows itself in recurring spasms of industrial depression
as disastrous to the world as destructive wars. It is
this that is driving men from the old countries to the
new countries, only to bring there the same curses.
It is this that causes our material advance not
merely to fail to improve the condition of the mere
worker, but to make the condition of large classes
positively worse. It is this that in our richest
Christian countries is giving us a large population whose
lives are harder, more hopeless, more degraded than those
of the veriest savages. It is this that leads so
many men to think that God is a bungler and is constantly
bringing more people into his world than he has made
provision for; or that there is no God, and that belief
in him is a superstition which the facts of life and the
advance of science are dispelling.
The darkness in light, the weakness in
strength, the poverty amid wealth, the seething
discontent foreboding civil strife, that characterize our
civilization of today, are the natural, the inevitable
results of our rejection of God’s beneficence, of
our ignoring of his intent. Were we on the other
hand to follow his clear, simple rule of right, leaving
scrupulously to the individual all that individual labor
produces, and taking for the community the value that
attaches to land by the growth of the community itself,
not merely could evil modes of raising public revenues be
dispensed with, but all men would be placed on an equal
level of opportunity with regard to the bounty of their
Creator, on an equal level of opportunity to exert their
labor and to enjoy its fruits. And then, without drastic
or restrictive measures the forestalling of land would
cease. For then the possession of land would mean only
security for the permanence of its use, and there would
be no object for any one to get land or to keep land
except for use; nor would his possession of better land
than others had confer any unjust advantage on him, or
unjust deprivation on them, since the equivalent of the
advantage would be taken by the state for the benefit of
all. ...
Your use, in so many passages of your Encyclical, of
the inclusive term “property” or
“private” property, of which in morals
nothing can be either affirmed or denied, makes your
meaning, if we take isolated sentences, in many places
ambiguous. But reading it as a whole, there can be no
doubt of your intention that private property in land
shall be understood when you speak merely of private
property. With this interpretation, I find that the
reasons you urge for private property in land are eight.
Let us consider them in order of presentation. You
urge:
1. That what is bought with rightful property is
rightful property. (RN, paragraph 5) ...
2. That private property in land proceeds from
man’s gift of reason. (RN, paragraphs 6-7.)
...
3. That private property in land deprives no one of the
use of land. (RN, paragraph 8.) ...
4. That Industry expended on land gives ownership in the
land itself. (RN, paragraphs 9-10.) ...
5. That private property in land has the support of the
common opinion of mankind, and has conduced to peace and
tranquillity, and that it is sanctioned by Divine Law.
(RN, paragraph 11.) ...
6. That fathers should provide for their children and
that private property in land is necessary to enable them
to do so. (RN, paragraphs 14-17.) ...
7. That the private ownership of land stimulates
industry, increases wealth, and attaches men to the soil
and to their country. (RN, paragraph 51.) ...
8. That the right to possess private property in land is
from nature, not from man; that the state has no right to
abolish it, and that to take the value of landownership
in taxation would be unjust and cruel to the private
owner. (RN, paragraph 51.) ...
6. That fathers should provide for their
children and that private property in land is necessary
to enable them to do so. (14-17.)
With all that your Holiness has to say of the
sacredness of the family relation we are in full accord.
But how the obligation of the father to the child can
justify private property in land we cannot see. You
reason that private property in land is necessary to the
discharge of the duty of the father, and is therefore
requisite and just, because —
It is a most sacred law of nature that a father must
provide food and all necessaries for those whom he has
begotten; and, similarly, nature dictates that a
man’s children, who carry on, as it were, and
continue his own personality, should be provided by him
with all that is needful to enable them honorably to keep
themselves from want and misery in the uncertainties of
this mortal life. Now, in no other way can a father
effect this except by the ownership of profitable
property, which he can transmit to his children by
inheritance. (14.)
Thanks to Him who has bound the generations of men
together by a provision that brings the tenderest love to
greet our entrance into the world and soothes our exit
with filial piety, it is both the duty and the joy of the
father to care for the child till its powers mature, and
afterwards in the natural order it becomes the duty and
privilege of the child to be the stay of the parent. This
is the natural reason for that relation of marriage, the
groundwork of the sweetest, tenderest and purest of human
joys, which the Catholic Church has guarded with such
unremitting vigilance.
We do, for a few years, need the providence of our
fathers after the flesh. But how small, how transient,
how narrow is this need, as compared with our constant
need for the providence of Him in whom we live, move and
have our being — Our Father who art in Heaven! It
is to him, “the giver of every good and perfect
gift,” and not to our fathers after the flesh, that
Christ taught us to pray, “Give us this day our
daily bread.” And how true it is that it is through
him that the generations of men exist! Let the mean
temperature of the earth rise or fall a few degrees, an
amount as nothing compared with differences produced in
our laboratories, and mankind would disappear as ice
disappears under a tropical sun, would fall as the leaves
fall at the touch of frost. Or, let for two or three
seasons the earth refuse her increase, and how many of
our millions would remain alive?
The duty of fathers to transmit to their children
profitable property that will enable them to keep
themselves from want and misery in the uncertainties of
this mortal life! What is not possible cannot be a duty.
And how is it possible for fathers to do that?
Your Holiness has not considered how mankind
really lives from hand to mouth, getting each day its
daily bread; how little one generation does or can leave
another. It is doubtful if the wealth of the civilized
world all told amounts to anything like as much as one
year’s labor, while it is certain that if labor
were to stop and men had to rely on existing
accumulation, it would be only a few days ere in the
richest countries pestilence and famine would
stalk.
The profitable property your Holiness refers to, is
private property in land. Now profitable land, as all
economists will agree, is land superior to the land that
the ordinary man can get. It is land that will yield an
income to the owner as owner, and therefore that will
permit the owner to appropriate the products of labor
without doing labor, its profitableness to the individual
involving the robbery of other individuals. It is
therefore possible only for some fathers to leave their
children profitable land. What therefore your Holiness
practically declares is, that it is the duty of all
fathers to struggle to leave their children what only the
few peculiarly strong, lucky or unscrupulous can leave;
and that, a something that involves the robbery of others
— their deprivation of the material gifts of
God.
This anti-Christian doctrine has been long in practice
throughout the Christian world. What are its results?
Are they not the very evils set forth in your
Encyclical? Are they not, so far from enabling men to
keep themselves from want and misery in the uncertainties
of this mortal life, to condemn the great masses of men
to want and misery that the natural conditions of our
mortal life do not entail; to want and misery deeper and
more wide-spread than exist among heathen savages? Under
the régime of private property in land and in the
richest countries not five per cent of fathers are able
at their death to leave anything substantial to their
children, and probably a large majority do not leave
enough to bury them! Some few children are left by their
fathers richer than it is good for them to be, but the
vast majority not only are left nothing by their fathers,
but by the system that makes land private property are
deprived of the bounty of their Heavenly Father; are
compelled to sue others for permission to live and to
work, and to toil all their lives for a pittance that
often does not enable them to escape starvation and
pauperism.
What your Holiness is actually, though of course
inadvertently, urging, is that earthly fathers should
assume the functions of the Heavenly Father. It is not
the business of one generation to provide the succeeding
generation “with all that is needful to enable them
honorably to keep themselves from want and misery.”
That is God’s business. We no more create our
children than we create our fathers. It is God who is the
Creator of each succeeding generation as fully as of the
one that preceded it. And, to recall your own words (7),
“Nature [God], therefore, owes to man a storehouse
that shall never fail, the daily supply of his daily
wants. And this he finds only in the inexhaustible
fertility of the earth.” What you are now assuming
is, that it is the duty of men to provide for the wants
of their children by appropriating this storehouse and
depriving other men’s children of the unfailing
supply that God has provided for all.
The duty of the father to the child — the duty
possible to all fathers! Is it not so to conduct himself,
so to nurture and teach it, that it shall come to manhood
with a sound body, well-developed mind, habits of virtue,
piety and industry, and in a state of society that shall
give it and all others free access to the bounty of God,
the providence of the All-Father?
In doing this the father would be doing more to secure
his children from want and misery than is possible now to
the richest of fathers — as much more as the
providence of God surpasses that of man. For the justice
of God laughs at the efforts of men to circumvent it, and
the subtle law that binds humanity together poisons the
rich in the sufferings of the poor. Even the few who are
able in the general struggle to leave their children
wealth that they fondly think will keep them from want
and misery in the uncertainties of this mortal life
— do they succeed? Does experience show that it is
a benefit to a child to place him above his fellows and
enable him to think God’s law of labor is not for
him? Is not such wealth oftener a curse than a blessing,
and does not its expectation often destroy filial love
and bring dissensions and heartburnings into families?
And how far and how long are even the richest and
strongest able to exempt their children from the common
lot? Nothing is more certain than that the blood of the
masters of the world flows today in lazzaroni and that
the descendants of kings and princes tenant slums and
workhouses.
But in the state of society we strive for, where the
monopoly and waste of God’s bounty would be done
away with and the fruits of labor would go to the
laborer, it would be within the ability of all to make
more than a comfortable living with reasonable labor. And
for those who might be crippled or incapacitated, or
deprived of their natural protectors and breadwinners,
the most ample provision could be made out of that great
and increasing fund with which God in his law of rent has
provided society — not as a matter of niggardly and
degrading alms, but as a matter of right, as the
assurance which in a Christian state society owes to all
its members.
Thus it is that the duty of the father, the obligation
to the child, instead of giving any support to private
property in land, utterly condemns it, urging us by the
most powerful considerations to abolish it in the simple
and efficacious way of the single tax.
This duty of the father, this obligation to children,
is not confined to those who have actually children of
their own, but rests on all of us who have come to the
powers and responsibilities of manhood.
For did not Christ set a little child in the midst of
the disciples, saying to them that the angels of such
little ones always behold the face of his Father; saying
to them that it were better for a man to hang a millstone
about his neck and plunge into the uttermost depths of
the sea than to injure such a little one?
And what today is the result of private property in
land in the richest of so-called Christian countries? Is
it not that young people fear to marry; that married
people fear to have children; that children are driven
out of life from sheer want of proper nourishment and
care, or compelled to toil when they ought to be at
school or at play; that great numbers of those who attain
maturity enter it with under-nourished bodies,
overstrained nerves, undeveloped minds — under
conditions that foredoom them, not merely to suffering,
but to crime; that fit them in advance for the prison and
the brothel?
If your Holiness will consider these things we are
confident that instead of defending private property in
land you will condemn it with anathema! ...
Your Holiness will remember the great London dock
strike of two years ago, which, with that of other
influential men, received the moral support of that
Prince of the Church whom we of the English speech hold
higher and dearer than any prelate has been held by us
since the blood of Thomas à Becket stained the
Canterbury altar.
In a volume called “The Story of the
Dockers’ Strike,” written by Messrs. H.
Llewellyn Smith and Vaughan Nash, with an introduction by
Sydney Buxton, M.P., which advocates trades-unionism as
the solution of the labor question, and of which a large
number were sent to Australia as a sort of official
recognition of the generous aid received from there by
the strikers, I find in the summing up, on pages 164-165,
the following:
If the settlement lasts, work at the docks will be
more regular, better paid, and carried on under better
conditions than ever before. All this will be an
unqualified gain to those who get the benefit from it.
But another result will undoubtedly be to contract the
field of employment and lessen the number of those for
whom work can be found. The lower-class
casual will, in the end, find his position more
precarious than ever before, in proportion to the
increased regularity of work which the
“fitter” of the laborers will secure. The
effect of the organization of dock labor, as of all
classes of labor, will be to squeeze out the residuum.
The loafer, the cadger, the failure in the industrial
race — the members of “Class B” of
Mr. Charles Booth’s hierarchy of social classes
— will be no gainers by the change, but will
rather find another door closed against them, and this
in many cases the last door to
employment.
I am far from wishing that your Holiness should join
in that pharisaical denunciation of trades-unions common
among those who, while quick to point out the injustice
of trades-unions in denying to others the equal right to
work, are themselves supporters of that more primary
injustice that denies the equal right to the
standing-place and natural material necessary to work.
What I wish to point out is that trades-unionism, while
it may be a partial palliative, is not a remedy; that it
has not that moral character which could alone justify
one in the position of your Holiness in urging it as good
in itself. Yet, so long as you insist on private property
in land what better can you do?
... read
the whole letter
Weld Carter: A Clarion Call
to Sanity, to Honesty, to Justice
(1982)
George has described this world as a
"well-provisioned ship" and when one considers the
increasingly huge daily withdrawals of such provisions as
coal and petroleum as have occurred say over the past one
hundred years, one must but agree with this writer. But
this is only a static view. Consider the suggestion of
some ten years ago that it would require the conversion
of less than 20% the of the current annual growth of wood
into alcohol to fuel all the motors then being fueled by
the then-conventional means. The dynamic picture of the
future is indeed awesome, and there is every indication
that that characteristic has the potential of endless
expansion. So how is it that on so richly endowed
a Garden of Eden as this world of ours we have only been
able to make of it a hell on earth for vast numbers of
people? ...
read the whole essay
|
To share this page with a friend:
right click, choose "send," and add your
comments.
|
|
Red links have not been
visited; .
Green links are pages you've seen
|
Essential Documents pertinent
to this theme:
|
|