Cost of Living
With each generation, the cost of living rises. This
seems peculiar, given the awesome increases in technology
and productivity, the lower costs of many goods which are
made overseas, the lower costs of food relative to other
items, etc. Yes, even poor people own items that didn't
exist 50 years ago, or were available only to the
wealthiest among us.
(Interestingly, Henry George spoke to
this issue near the beginning of Progress &
Poverty, so the same argument has been around
for 125 years! He wrote, in a footnote, "It is true
that the poorest may now in certain ways enjoy what the
richest a century ago could not have commanded, but
this does not show improvement of condition so long as
the ability to obtain the necessaries of life is not
increased. The beggar in a great city may enjoy many
things from which the backwoods farmer is debarred, but
that does not prove the condition of the city beggar
better than that of the independent farmer.")
But young people, particularly in our coastal states
and urban areas, can't afford to live in the towns in
which they grew up. Nurses and retail sales people and
janitors can't afford to buy homes in many parts of the
country, and can't afford to rent in many others. Wages
are not keeping up with the cost of living. And our
official poverty statistics don't begin to measure
this.
At the same time, wealth is becoming
increasingly concentrated into the top few percent of
the population, as is income.
Can this be changed? The thesis of this website is
that, yes, it can, if we come to understand that all of the benefits of our
technological
progress and population growth and
public spending go
to whomever gets to keep the rent
on land, and then recognize that we must collect the rental
value of land from those who own land, particularly our urban land.
Shifting our taxes off work and onto land values will
help bring down
the price of land, making it affordable to those who
need it. This will make housing more affordable, allow
potential entrepreneurs
access to the choice sites, and reduce the profitability
of the FIRE sector. Those
businesses whose primary purpose is to serve as landlord, however, will not favor
this reform. Are they powerful enough to prevent it? They
have a lot to lose: not the rent on the buildings —
that is legitimately theirs, and wouldn't be taxed
— but the locational value, which is rightly our
common asset.
What sort of world would you like your grandchildren to live in? If you
are in the landlord class, do you think you can provide
all of them enough protection from those who are tenants
or whose landholdings are of minimal value? What sort of
world do you want all of our grandchildren to live
in?
Henry George: The
Common Sense of Taxation (1881 article)
As to amount of taxation, there is no principle which
imposes any arbitrary limit. Heavy taxation is better for
any community than light taxation, if the increased
revenue be used in doing by public agencies things which
could not be done, or could not be as well and
economically done, by private agencies. Taxes could be
lightened in the city of New York by dispensing with
street-lamps and disbanding the police force. But would a
reduction in taxation gained in this way be for the
benefit of the people of New York and make New York a
more desirable place to live in? Or if it should be found
that heat and light could be conducted through the
streets at public expense and supplied to each house at
but a small fraction of the cost of supplying them by
individual effort, or that the city railroads could be
run at public expense so as to give every one
transportation at very much less than it now costs the
average resident, the increased taxation necessary for
these purposes would not be increased burden, and in
spite of the larger taxation required, New York would
become a more desirable place to live in. It is a mistake
to condemn taxation as bad merely because it is high; it
is a mistake to impose by constitutional provision, as in
many of our States has been advocated, and in some of our
States has been done, any restriction upon the amount of
taxation. A restriction upon the incurring of public
indebtedness is another matter. In nothing is the
far-reaching statesmanship of Jefferson more clearly
shown than in his proposition that all public obligations
should be deemed void after a certain brief term —
a proposition which he grounds upon the self-evident
truth that the earth belongs in usufruct to the living,
and that the dead have no control over it, and can give
no title to any part of it. But restriction upon public
debts is a very different thing from restriction upon the
power of taxation, and reasons which urge the one do not
apply to the other. Nor is increased taxation necessarily
proof of governmental extravagance. Increase in taxation
is in the order of social development, for the reason
that social development tends to the doing of things
collectively that in a ruder state are done individually,
to the giving to government of new functions and the
imposing of new duties. Our public schools and libraries
and parks, our signal service and fish commissions and
agricultural bureaus and grasshopper investigations, are
evidences of this.
But while no limit can be properly fixed for the
amount of taxation, the method of taxation is of supreme
importance. A horse may be anchored by fastening to his
bridle a weight which he will not feel when carried in a
buggy behind him. The best ship may be made utterly
unseaworthy by the bad stowage of a cargo which properly
placed would make her the stiffer and more weatherly. So
enterprise may be palsied, industry crushed, accumulation
prevented, and a prosperous country turned into a desert,
by taxation which rightly levied would hardly be felt.
...
For, keeping in mind the fact that all wealth is the
result of human exertion, it is clearly seen that, having
in view the promotion of the general prosperity, it is
the height of absurdity to tax wealth for purposes of
revenue while there remains, unexhausted by taxation, any
value attaching to land. We may tax land values as much
as we please, without in the slightest degree lessening
the amount of land, or the capabilities of land, or the
inducement to use land. But we cannot tax wealth without
lessening the inducement to the production of wealth, and
decreasing the amount of wealth. We might take the whole
value of land in taxation, so as to make the ownership of
land worth nothing, and the land would still remain, and
be as useful as before. The effect would be to throw land
open to users free of price, and thus to increase its
capabilities, which are brought out by increased
population. But impose anything like such taxation upon
wealth, and the inducement to the production of wealth
would be gone. Movable wealth would be hidden or carried
off, immovable wealth would be suffered to go to decay,
and where was prosperity would soon be the silence of
desolation. ...
See how unjust and short-sighted is this system. Here
is a man who, gathering what little capital he can, and
taking his family, starts West to find a place where he
can make himself a home. He must travel long distances;
for, though he will pass plenty of land nobody is using,
it is held at prices too high for him. Finally he will go
no further, and selects a place where, since the creation
of the world, the soil, so far as we know, has never felt
a plowshare. But here, too, in nine cases out of ten, he
will find the speculator has been ahead of him, for the
speculator moves quicker, and has superior means of
information to the emigrant. Before he can put this land
to the use for which nature intended it, and to which it
is for the general good that it should be put, he must
make terms with some man who in all probability never saw
the land, and never dreamed of using it, and who, it may
be, resides in some city, thousands of miles away. In
order to get permission to use this land, he must give up
a large part of the little capital which is seed-wheat to
him, and perhaps in addition mortgage his future labor
for years. Still he goes to work: he works himself, and
his wife works, and his children work — work like
horses, and live in the hardest and dreariest manner.
Such a man deserves encouragement, not discouragement;
but on him taxation falls with peculiar severity. Almost
everything that he has to buy — groceries,
clothing, tools — is largely raised in price by a
system of tariff taxation which cannot add to the price
of the grain or hogs or cattle that he has to sell. And
when the assessor comes around he is taxed on the
improvements he has made, although these improvements
have added not only to the value of surrounding land, but
even to the value of land in distant commercial centers.
Not merely this, but, as a general rule, his land,
irrespective of the improvements, will be assessed at a
higher rate than unimproved land around it, on the ground
that "productive property" ought to pay more than
"unproductive property" — a principle just the
reverse of the correct one, for the man who makes land
productive adds to the general prosperity, while the man
who keeps land unproductive stands in the way of the
general prosperity, is but a dog-in-the-manger, who
prevents others from using what he will not use
himself.
Or, take the case of the railroads. That railroads are
a public benefit no one will dispute. We want more
railroads, and want them to reduce their fares and
freight. Why then should we tax them? for taxes upon
railroads deter from railroad building, and compel higher
charges. Instead of taxing the railroads, is it not clear
that we should rather tax the increased value which they
give to land? To tax railroads is to check railroad
building, to reduce profits, and compel higher rates; to
tax the value they give to land is to increase railroad
business and permit lower rates. The elevated
railroads, for instance, have opened to the overcrowded
population of New York the wide, vacant spaces of the
upper part of the island. But this great public benefit
is neutralized by the rise in land values. Because these
vacant lots can be reached more cheaply and quickly,
their owners demand more for them, and so the public gain
in one way is offset in another, while the roads lose the
business they would get were not building checked by the
high prices demanded for lots. The increase of land
values, which the elevated roads have caused, is not
merely no advantage to them — it is an injury; and
it is clearly a public injury. The elevated
railroads ought not to be taxed. The more profit they
make, with the better conscience can they be asked to
still further reduce fares. It is the
increased land values which they have created that ought
to be taxed, for taxing them will give the public the
full benefit of cheap fares. ... read the whole
article
Rev. A. C. Auchmuty: Gems from George, a themed
collection of excerpts from the writings of Henry
George (with links to sources)
THE mode of taxation is quite as important as the
amount. As a small burden badly placed may distress a
horse that could carry with ease a much larger one
properly adjusted, so a people may be impoverished and
their power of producing wealth destroyed by taxation,
which, if levied in another way, could be borne with
ease. —
Progress & Poverty
— Book VIII, Chapter 3, Application of the Remedy:
The Proposition Tried by the Canons of Taxation
IF we impose a tax upon buildings, the users of
buildings must finally pay it, for the erection of
buildings will cease until building rents become high
enough to pay the regular profit and the tax besides. If
we impose a tax upon manufactures or imported goods, the
manufacturer or importer will charge it in a higher price
to the jobber, the jobber to the retailer, and the
retailer to the consumer. Now, the consumer, on whom the
tax thus ultimately falls, must not only pay the amount
of the tax, but also a profit on this amount to everyone
who has thus advanced it — for profit on the
capital he has advanced in paying taxes is as much
required by each dealer as profit on the capital he has
advanced in paying for goods. —
Progress & Poverty
— Book VIII, Chapter 3, Application of the Remedy:
The Proposition Tried by the Canons of Taxation
THE way taxes raise prices is by increasing the cost of
production, and checking supply. But land is not a thing
of human production, and taxes upon rent cannot check
supply. Therefore though a tax on rent compels the
landowners to pay more, it gives them no power to obtain
more for the use of their land, as it in no way tends to
reduce the supply of land. On the contrary, by compelling
those who hold land on speculation to sell or let for
what they can get, a tax on land values tends to increase
the competition between owners, and thus to reduce the
price of land. —
Progress & Poverty
— Book VIII, Chapter 3, Application of the Remedy:
The Proposition Tried by the Canons of Taxation
... go to "Gems from
George"
Louis Post: Outlines
of Louis F. Post's Lectures, with Illustrative Notes and
Charts (1894)
II. THE SINGLE TAX AS A FISCAL
REFORM
1. DIRECT AND INDIRECT
TAXATION
Taxes are either direct or indirect; or, as they have
been aptly described, "straight" or "crooked." Indirect
taxes are those that may be shifted by the first payer
from himself to others; direct taxes are those that
cannot be shifted.5
The shifting of indirect taxes is accomplished
by means of their tendency to increase the prices of
commodities on which they fall. Their magnitude
and incidence 6 are thereby disguised. It was for this
reason that a great French economist of the last century
denounced them as "a scheme for so plucking geese as to
get the most feathers with the least squawking."7 ...
read the book
Charles B. Fillebrown: A Catechism of Natural
Taxation, from Principles of Natural Taxation
(1917)
Q19. Why should buildings and all other
improvements and personal property and capital be exempt
from taxes?
A. Because a tax on them falls upon industry, and so
increases the cost of living, while continuing the
invidious exemption of the present net land value.
Q45. Why tax $1,000 invested in a vacant lot while
exempting $1,000 invested in New York Central
stock?
A. Because: (1) the land is made worth $1,000 and so
maintained at public expense without any contribution
from the owner; (2) the $1,000 New York Central stock
adds nothing to the public expense, but a tax upon it, if
collected at the source, falls directly on the road and
thence upon the public, and so adds to the cost of
living.
... read
the whole article
Mason Gaffney: Land as a Distinctive Factor
of Production
Land normally does not depreciate as a function of
time. Most attributes of land also withstand use
and abuse. Most land is, rather, expected to
appreciate in real value in the long run. Values go
in cycles, but the secular history is upwards as
population, capital, and demands all grow while land
remains fixed. Capital has a period of formation
during which it accretes value by storing up other inputs
and changing physical form, but that is a phase.
Once formed, almost all capital fails with
time.
Perhaps the most durable capital is intellectual,
like the writings of Plato. These, however, do not
endure generations without the continual human effort and
expense of education. As schools starve and
libraries close, it is sadly certain that much will be
lost. Under any conditions much is twisted in
transmission, like classical economics itself.
...
... It follows that the demand for land arises
over time with incomes, but
faster than incomes. Read the whole
article
William F. Buckley, Jr.: Home Dear
Home
So why is the cost of housing so high?
We learn that the average new house nationwide now
sells for nearly $300,000. The writer tells us, "I asked
(a builder) what our children -- my kids are both under
8, I told him -- would be paying when they're ready to
buy.
"'They're going to live with us until they're 40,'
(the builder) said matter-of-factly. 'And when they have
their second kid, then we'll finally kick them out and
make them pay for the house that we paid for. And that
house will cost them 45 to 50 percent of their
income.'"
Such data are dismaying, but perspective helps. "In
Britain," the builder explains, "you pay seven times your
annual income for a home; in the U.S. you pay three and a
half." The Brits get 330 square feet per person in their
homes; Americans, 750 square feet. But choice parts of
the United States face "build-out." Consider New Jersey.
It currently averages 1,165 people per square mile --
denser than India (914) and Japan (835).
And we confront, finally and inevitably, the question:
What is to be done about it?
Almost without exception, housing specialists concur,
high home prices are owing to zoning. Twenty years ago,
in many quarters of the country, one year would go by
before the political authority would permit a developer
to begin housing construction. In New Jersey, that
interval now approaches eight years. Delays of that kind
have the effect of shrinking the amount of land on which
houses can be constructed. We get the inflated costs so
familiar. "(Some authorities) used sample prices from 25
areas to show that the cost of housing in a metropolitan
area appears to be in direct correlation to its degree of
zoning ordinances," Gertner writes.
This is a politically remote source of trouble. People
who have to wait for a zoning agency to change its
conventions, regulations, traditions and idiosyncrasies
will be very old before they acquire a new home.
Henry George, the eminent social philosopher of a
century ago, turned the attention of planners and
economists, however briefly, to the indefeasible factor
of land scarcity. Capital and labor can increase; land
cannot. ... ... read the
whole column
Mason Gaffney: The
Red and the Blue
To understand the politics of New
York City or San Francisco we need to begin by noting
that they have about the highest residential rents and
home prices in the U.S.A., along with the highest tenancy
rates. It takes a high monetary income even to be poor in
such places, unless you own
land. Federal statisticians who publish the
Consumer Price Index (CPI) delicately refrain from
comparing different cities - they just compare different
times, city by city. This helps them finesse tough
questions about rents, and housing prices. Common
observation, however, and various semi-popular
publications, fill the gap. The C.O.L., especially
its rent and home value elements, is a lot higher in the
big glamorous cities, so real incomes there are a lot
lower than they look - unless you own land.
The City of Los Angeles in early December, 2004,
condemned an apartment building in “south
central,” the toughest slum area, to drive out
violent gangs who make it their base and terrorize the
neighborhood. Were the other tenants
grateful? No, they protested. “Where
else can I rent for $600,” bemoaned one with a
mistress and child, clinging to a one-bedroom place with
a “ratty carpet, broken tiles, and
roaches.”
“The People’s Republic of Santa
Monica,” so-called by wags, has about the highest
land values per square foot in the U.S.A. Its
enviable location is hard to beat. It also has a high
rate of tenancy, and a City Council swayed by organized
tenants. Color it blue: the tenants vote. Read the whole
article
Jeff Smith and Kris Nelson: Giving Life to the Property Tax
Shift (PTS)
John Muir is right. "Tug on any one thing and find
it connected to everything else in the universe." Tug on
the property tax and find it connected to urban slums,
farmland loss, political favoritism, and unearned equity
with disrupted neighborhood tenure. Echoing Thoreau, the
more familiar reforms have failed to address this
many-headed hydra at its root. To think that the root
could be chopped by a mere shift in the property tax base
-- from buildings to land -- must seem like the epitome
of unfounded faith. Yet the evidence shows that state and
local tax activists do have a powerful, if subtle, tool
at their disposal. The "stick" spurring efficient use of
land is a higher tax rate upon land, up to even the
site's full annual value. The "carrot" rewarding
efficient use of land is a lower or zero tax rate upon
improvements. ...
The other potentially supportive
businesses -- service providers -- do not consume much in
the way of resources or prime locations. Even service
providers on valuable sites, were they to pay more, could
still come out ahead in the better business climate of
zero taxes on sales, on paid wages, on customers' income,
and of less onerous mortgage. Presently
taxes and mortgages consume about 65% of the average
worker's income, drastically reducing discretionary
spending. ...
A big problem needs a big solution
which in turn needs a matching shift of our prevailing
paradigm. Geonomics -- advocating that we share the
social value of sites and natural resources and untax
earnings -- does just that.
Read the whole
article
Jeff Smith: Planning by
Markets
Taxes -- an aspect of politics, not markets --
motivate misuse of land.
- The tax on buildings
discourages maintenance and breeds slums (Lynn
1973). After the neighborhood really goes down hill and
the owner has milked every last penny out of the
structure, he just walks away. Thus urban cores decay
(Pickard 1966), an entropy that seems inevitable yet is
policy-induced(1).
- In growing areas, custom
design creates more valuable homes, hence more tax
liability. To avoid the penalty, developers can
under-build or sacrifice esthetics. Cookie-cutter
developments all in a row reduce built value and property
taxes(2).
- Taxing sales raises the cost
of living while taxing income lowers the ability to
afford to live. Like a vise, regressive taxes
squeeze out the discretionary income of the poor who
cannot afford the city they may like. Necessity crams
them into the structures that cut corners.
While taxes are creatures of
legislatures, ground rent is a phenomenon of markets.
What's political is what we do with it. Most of us forget
it's there, letting it reward speculation and sprawl.
... Read the whole
article
Herbert J. G. Bab:
Property Tax --
Cause of Unemployment (circa 1964)
When analysing property taxes we shall distinguish
between that part of the tax which is assessed on
improvements and that part which is assessed on
land.
That part of the tax that is assessed on buildings
penalizes everybody who improves his land, his buildings
or intends to construct residential, commercial or
industrial property. The most serious incidence of
property taxes is on new housing. When rental property or
houses are newly constructed these taxes add 15 to 20% to
the annual cost depending on assessment practices and tax
rates.
"In 1962 property taxes on new F.H.A. insured
houses averaged $14.30 per month, or $171.60 per year,
excluding that part of the tax that was assessed on the
land. Assuming that a family spends 20%
of its income on housing, the income of a family
must increase by $858 per year in order to afford the
purchase of a home. In this way many families in the
lower income group are priced, or taxed, out of the
market. And residential construction, a mainstay of our
economy, is discouraged."
"In 1963 HOUSING STARTS reached a level of 1.6
million units, representing a value of about $20
billions. Yet very few houses were built in the central
areas of our cities and a large part of these houses were
built for families in the middle or upper income group.
Of these single-family homes, only 15% were sold for less
than $12,500. Another 15% sold for between $12,500 and
$15,000. Thus 70% of these homes cost $15,000 or more.
This is so because under our income tax laws property
taxes and interest charges are deductible items. A person
in the 75% bracket pays only 25% of these costs and a
person in the 50% bracket pays only half the property
taxes and half the interest charges."
The steep increase in the level of rentals
represents a true and accurate yardstick of our housing
shortage. During the period 1950 to 1961
- the average rental rose from $71.13 per month
to $186.79 or by 160%.
- During the same period median urban family
income rose from $3,497 to $5,924 or by only
69%.
- Construction
costs per square foot rose from $8.68 in 1950 to $11.32
in 1961 or by only 30.4%.
The ever widening gap between the level of rentals
and the urban family income constitutes a rental squeeze,
which has brought untold misery and hardship to families
in the lower income group, especially to those belonging
to minority groups. The rental squeeze has also
aggravated overcrowding and slum
conditions.
In the press, on the radio and on
television we are often warned about the threat of
inflation. Hardly ever are we told, that the increase in
the cost of living is to a large extent due to the
increase in housing costs brought about by the housing
shortage.Read
the whole article
The
inflationary effects of property taxation are reinforced
by the fact that property taxes themselves are included
in the cost of living index and that property tax rates
have the tendency to rise.
The Most Rev. Dr Thomas Nulty, Roman Catholic Bishop of
Meath (Ireland): Back to
the Land (1881)
Higher Money Wages but Lower
Purchasing Power.
Does it therefore follow that the strong,
widespread and permanent feeling of discontent which
prevail among the labourers is the result of fancy or
imagination, having no solid foundation whatever in
fact?
Undoubtedly this feeling proves the
labourers to have substantial grievances, although I think
they have failed to trace them to the causes that have
really produced them. The money wage of
the English operative is now considerably higher than in
any past period of English history. But if his money wage
is now high, the price of the raw products of the soil,
that is to say, of the necessaries and comforts of life, is
vastly higher still.
A given amount of money will not now
procure for him the same quantity of food and of the other
necessaries of life as formerly. In purchasing the raw
products of the soil, he must pay not only for the
necessaries and comforts of life which he enjoys himself,
but also for the comforts and luxuries which go to the
enjoyment of the owners of the soil. The price, therefore,
of the raw products is a payment and a tax; a payment for
what he consumes himself, and a tax for what is consumed by
others.
Then again, a vast margin of the
earnings of the English people is expended in direct and
indirect taxation. The public burdens of every nation fall
mainly on the vast masses of that nation, and the
operatives of England are the vast masses of the English
nation.
If the English operatives could only
retain for their own use and benefit the vast sums which,
under the existing system of Land Tenure, go on the one
hand to the owners of the soil, and the sums that an
economical system of taxation would save for them on the
other, their material comforts and enjoyments would be
multiplied a hundred fold. Under the existing state of
things their condition is utterly incapable of any
improvement in the future. Read the whole
letter
Weld Carter: An
Introduction to Henry George
Another area in which George applied these
inherent differences between land and products was the
field of taxation. To determine the incidence of
taxation, George had to know what was to be taxed,
products or the value of land. In each case he traced out
the effect from the essential nature of the thing to be
taxed: "...all taxes upon things of unfixed quantity
increase prices, and in the course of exchange are
shifted from seller to buyer, increasing as they go.
...If we impose a tax upon buildings, the users of
buildings must finally pay it, for the erection of
buildings will cease until building rents become high
enough to pay the regular profit and the tax besides.
...In this way all taxes which add to prices are shifted
from hand to hand, increasing as they go, until they
ultimately rest upon consumers, who thus pay much more
than is received by the government. Now, the way taxes
raise prices is by increasing the cost of production, and
checking supply. But land is not a thing of human
production, and taxes upon...[land value] cannot check
supply. Therefore, though a tax on...[land value] compels
the land owners to pay more, it gives them no power to
obtain more for the use of their land, as it in no way
tends to reduce the supply of land. On the contrary, by
compelling those who hold land on speculation to sell or
let for what they can get, a tax on land values tends to
increase the competition between owners, and thus to
reduce the price of land."
Here, then is another derivative difference
between land and products, according to George: taxation
on products causes an increase in the price of products;
taxation on the value of land causes a drop in the price
of land. ... read the
whole article
|
To share this page with a friend:
right click, choose "send," and add your
comments.
|
|
Red links have not been
visited; .
Green links are pages you've seen
|
Essential Documents pertinent
to this theme:
|
|