Poverty
Some attempt to define poverty away, by
allowing our official definition of poverty to be
assigned via an income threshold that is far below a
livable income level in all but a few rural counties in
the U.S. (The Census Bureau acknowledges that the
incomes levels they use are statistical, and not
related to adequacy in any way.
But some dare to dream of, and move toward,
abolishing poverty. Henry George dedicated Progress
and Poverty: An inquiry into the cause of industrial
depressions and of increase of want with increase of
wealth ... The Remedy"to those who, seeing the
vice and misery that spring from the unequal
distribution of wealth and privilege, feel the
possibility of a higher social state and would strive
for its attainment." This website is for those who will
strive for that today.
Henry George: Thy Kingdom
Come (1889 speech)
Really, if we could imagine it, it is impossible
to think of heaven treated as we treat this earth,
without seeing that, no matter how salubrious were its
air, no matter how bright the light that filled it, no
matter how magnificent its vegetable growth, there would
be poverty, and suffering, and a division of classes in
heaven itself, if heaven were parcelled out as we have
parceled out the earth. And, conversely, if people were
to act towards each other as we must suppose the
inhabitants of heaven to do, would not this earth be a
very heaven? ... Read the whole
speech
Henry George: The Land Question
(1881)
The owner of city land takes, in the rents he
receives for his land, the earnings of labor just as
clearly as does the owner of farming land. And whether he
be working in a garret ten stories above the street, or
in a mining drift thousands of feet below the earth's
surface, it is the competition for the use of land that
ultimately determines what proportion of the produce of
his labor the laborer will get for himself. This is the reason why modern progress does not tend
to extirpate poverty; this is the reason why, with all
the inventions and improvements and economies which so
enormously increase productive power, wages everywhere
tend to the minimum of a bare living. ...
read the whole article
Henry George: Political
Dangers (Chapter 2 of Social Problems, 1883)
[11] The rise in the United
States of monstrous fortunes, the aggregation of enormous
wealth in the hands of corporations, necessarily implies
the loss by the people of governmental control.
Democratic forms may be maintained, but there can be as
much tyranny and misgovernment under democratic forms as
any other — in fact, they lend themselves most
readily to tyranny and misgovernment. Forms count for
little. The Romans expelled their kings, and continued to
abhor the very name of king. But under the name of
Cæsars and Imperators, that at first meant no more
than our "Boss," they crouched before tyrants more
absolute than kings. We have already, under the popular
name of "bosses," developed political Cæsars in
municipalities and states. If this development continues,
in time there will come a national boss. We are young but
we are growing. The day may arrive when the "Boss of
America" will be to the modern world what Cæsar was
to the Roman world. This, at least, is certain:
Democratic government in more than name can exist only
where wealth is distributed with something like equality
— where the great mass of citizens are personally
free and independent, neither fettered by their poverty
nor made subject by their wealth. There is,
after all, some sense in a property qualification. The
man who is dependent on a master for his living is not a
free man. To give the suffrage to slaves is only to give
votes to their owners. That universal suffrage may add
to, instead of decreasing, the political power of wealth
we see when mill-owners and mine operators vote their
hands. The freedom to earn, without fear or favor, a
comfortable living, ought to go with the freedom to vote.
Thus alone can a sound basis for republican institutions
be secured. How can a man be said to have a country where
he has no right to a square inch of soil; where he has
nothing but his hands, and, urged by starvation, must bid
against his fellows for the privilege of using them? When
it comes to voting tramps, some principle has been
carried to a ridiculous and dangerous extreme. I have
known elections to be decided by the carting of paupers
from the almshouse to the polls. But such decisions can
scarcely be in the interest of good government. ... read the
entire essay
Henry George: The
Crime of Poverty (1885 speech)
I PROPOSE to talk to you tonight of the Crime of
Poverty. I cannot, in a short time, hope to convince you
of much; but the thing of things I should like to show
you is that poverty is a crime. I do not mean that it is
a crime to be poor. Murder is a crime; but it is not a
crime to be murdered; and a man who is in poverty, I look
upon, not as a criminal in himself, so much as the victim
of a crime for which others, as well perhaps as himself,
are responsible. ...
The curse born of poverty is not
confined to the poor alone; it runs through all classes,
even to the very rich. They, too, suffer; they must suffer;
for there cannot be suffering in a community from which any
class can totally escape. The vice, the crime, the
ignorance, the meanness born of poverty, poison, so to
speak, the very air which rich and poor alike must
breathe.
Poverty is the mother of ignorance, the breeder of
crime. I walked down one of your streets this morning,
and I saw three men going along with their hands chained
together. I knew for certain that those men were not rich
men; and, although I do not know the offence for which
they were carried in chains through your streets, this I
think I can safely say, that, if you trace it up you will
find it in some way to spring from poverty. Nine tenths
of human misery, I think you will find, if you look, to
be due to poverty. ... And it seems to me clear
that the great majority of those who suffer from poverty
are poor not from their own particular faults, but
because of conditions imposed by society at large.
Therefore I hold that poverty is a crime – not an
individual crime, but a social crime, a crime for which
we all, poor as well as rich, are responsible.
...
... Whose fault is it that social conditions are
such that men have to make that terrible choice between
what conscience tells them is right, and the necessity of
earning a living? I hold that it is the fault of society;
that it is the fault of us all. Pestilence is a curse.
The man who would bring cholera to this country, or the
man who, having the power to prevent its coming here,
would make no effort to do so, would be guilty of a
crime. Poverty is worse than cholera; poverty kills more
people than pestilence, even in the best of times. Look
at the death statistics of our cities; see where the
deaths come quickest; see where it is that the little
children die like flies – it is in the poorer
quarters. And the man who looks with careless eyes upon
the ravages of this pestilence, the man who does not set
himself to stay and eradicate it, he, I say, is guilty of
a crime.
If poverty is appointed by the power
which is above us all, then it is no crime; but if poverty
is unnecessary, then it is a crime for which society is
responsible and for which society must suffer. I hold, and
I think no one who looks at the facts can fail to see, that
poverty is utterly unnecessary. It is not by the decree of
the Almighty, but it is because of our own injustice, our
own selfishness, our own ignorance, that this scourge,
worse than any pestilence, ravages our civilisation,
bringing want and suffering and degradation, destroying
souls as well as bodies. Look over the world, in this
heyday of nineteenth century civilisation. In every
civilised country under the sun you will find men and women
whose condition is worse than that of the savage: men and
women and little children with whom the veriest savage
could not afford to exchange. Even in this new city of
yours with virgin soil around you, you have had this winter
to institute a relief society. Your roads have been filled
with tramps, fifteen, I am told, at one time taking shelter
in a round-house here. As here, so everywhere; and poverty
is deepest where wealth most abounds.
What more unnatural than this? There
is nothing in nature like this poverty which today curses
us. We see rapine in nature; we see one species destroying
another; but as a general thing animals do not feed on
their own kind; and, wherever we see one kind enjoying
plenty, all creatures of that kind share it. No man, I
think, ever saw a herd of buffalo, of which a few were fat
and the great majority lean. No man ever saw a flock of
birds, of which two or three were swimming in grease and
the others all skin and bone. Nor in savage life is there
anything like the poverty that festers in our
civilisation.
In a rude state of society there are seasons of
want, seasons when people starve; but they are seasons
when the earth has refused to yield her increase, when
the rain has not fallen from the heavens, or when the
land has been swept by some foe – not when there is
plenty. And yet the peculiar
characteristic of this modern poverty of ours is that it
is deepest where wealth most abounds.
Why, today, while over the civilised
world there is so much distress, so much want, what is the
cry that goes up? What is the current explanation of the
hard times? Overproduction! There are so many clothes that
men must go ragged, so much coal that in the bitter winters
people have to shiver, such over-filled granaries that
people actually die by starvation! Want due to
over-production! Was a greater absurdity ever uttered? How
can there be over-production till all have enough? It is
not over-production; it is unjust distribution.
...
Here is a broad general fact that is asserted by
all who have investigated the question, by such men as
Hallam, the historian, and Professor Thorold Rogers, who
has made a study of the history of prices as they were
five centuries ago. When all the productive arts were in
the most primitive state, when the most prolific of our
modern vegetables had not been introduced, when the
breeds of cattle were small and poor, when there were
hardly any roads and transportation was exceedingly
difficult, when all manufacturing was done by hand
— in that rude time the condition
of the labourers of England was far better than it is
today. In those rude times no man need fear want
save when actual famine came, and owing to the
difficulties of transportation the plenty of one district
could not relieve the scarcity of another. Save in such
times, no man need fear want. Pauperism, such as exists
in modern times, was absolutely unknown. Everyone, save the physically disabled, could make a
living, and the poorest lived in rude plenty. But
perhaps the most astonishing fact brought to light by
this investigation is that at that time, under those
conditions in those "dark ages," as we call them,
the working day was only eight
hours. While with all our modern inventions and
improvements, our working classes have been agitating and
struggling in vain to get the working day reduced to
eight hours. ...
Why, in the rudest state of society in the most
primitive state of the arts the labour of the natural
bread-winner will suffice to provide a living for himself
and for those who are dependent upon him. Amid all our
inventions there are large bodies of men who cannot do
this. What is the most astonishing thing in our
civilisation? Why, the most astonishing
thing to those Sioux chiefs who were recently brought
from the Far West and taken through our manufacturing
cities in the East, was not the marvellous
inventions that enabled machinery to act almost as if it
had intellect; it was not the growth of our cities; it
was not the speed with which the railway car whirled
along; it was not the telegraph or the telephone that
most astonished them; but the fact that
amid this marvellous development of productive power they
found little children at work. And astonishing
that ought to be to us; a most astounding
thing!
Talk about improvement in the condition of the
working classes, when the facts are that a larger and
larger proportion of women and children are forced to
toil. ... Such facts are appalling; they mean that
the very foundations of the Republic are being sapped.
The dangerous man is not the man who
tries to excite discontent; the dangerous man is the man
who says that all is as it ought to be. Such a
state of things cannot continue; such tendencies as we
see at work here cannot go on without bringing at last an
overwhelming crash.
I say that all this poverty and the ignorance
that flows from it is unnecessary; I say that there is no
natural reason why we should not all be rich, in the
sense, not of having more than each other, but
in the sense of all having enough to
completely satisfy all physical wants; of all having
enough to get such an easy living that we could develop
the better part of humanity. There is no
reason why wealth should not be so abundant, that no one
should think of such a thing as little children at work,
or a woman compelled to a toil that nature never intended
her to perform; wealth so abundant that there would be no
cause for that harassing fear that sometimes paralyses
even those who are not considered "the poor," the fear
that every man of us has probably felt, that if sickness
should smite him, or if he should be taken away, those
whom he loves better than his life would become charges
upon charity. "Consider the lilies of the field, how they
grow; they toil not, neither do they spin." I believe
that in a really Christian community, in a society that
honoured not with the lips but with the act, the
doctrines of Jesus, no one would have occasion to worry
about physical needs any more than do the lilies of the
field. There is enough and to spare. The trouble is that,
in this mad struggle, we trample in the mire what has
been provided in sufficiency for us all; trample it in
the mire while we tear and rend each other.
There is a cause for this poverty;
and, if you trace it down, you will find its root in a
primary injustice. Look over the world
today—poverty everywhere. The cause must be a
common one. You cannot attribute it to the tariff, or to
the form of government, or to this thing or to that in
which nations differ; because, as deep poverty is common
to them all the cause that produces it must be a common
cause. What is that common cause? There is one sufficient
cause that is common to all nations; and that is the
appropriation as the property of some of that natural
element on which and from which all must live.
...
... Men are compelled to compete with each other
for the wages of an employer, because they have been
robbed of the natural opportunities of employing
themselves; because they cannot find a piece of God's
world on which to work without paying some other human
creature for the privilege.
I do not mean to say that even after
you had set right this fundamental injustice, there would
not be many things to do; but this I do mean to say, that
our treatment of land lies at the bottom of all social
questions. This I do mean to say, that, do what you please,
reform as you may, you never can get rid of wide-spread
poverty so long as the element on which and from which all
men must live is made the private property of some men. It
is utterly impossible. Reform government — get taxes
down to the minimum — build railroads; institute
co-operative stores; divide profits, if you choose, between
employers and employed-and what will be the result? The
result will be that the land will increase in value —
that will be the result — that and nothing else.
Experience shows this. Do not all improvements simply
increase the value of land — the price that some must
pay others for the privilege of living? ...
read the whole
speech Henry George: Thou Shalt Not Steal
(1887 speech)
The comments made on that meeting and on the
institution of this Society are suggestive. We are told, in the first place, by the newspapers,
that you cannot abolish poverty because there is not
wealth enough to go around. We are told that if
all the wealth of the United States were divided up there
would only be some eight hundred dollars apiece. Well, if
that is the case, all the more monstrous is the injustice
which today gives some people millions and tens of
millions, and even hundreds of millions. If there really
is so little, then the more injustice in these great
fortunes.
But we do not propose to abolish
poverty by dividing up wealth. We propose to
abolish poverty by setting at work that vast army of men
— estimated last year to amount in this country
alone to one million — that vast army of men only
anxious to create wealth, but who are now, by a system
which permits dogs-in-the-manger to monopolize
God’s bounty, deprived of the opportunity to
toil.
Then, again, they tell us you cannot abolish
poverty, because poverty always has existed. Well, if
poverty always has existed, all the more need for our
moving for its abolition. It has existed long enough. We
ought to be tired of it; let us get rid of it. But I deny
that poverty, such poverty as we see on earth today,
always has existed. ... read the whole
article
Henry George: The Wages of
Labor
The poverty amid wealth and the seething
discontent foreboding civil strife that characterise our
civilisation of today are the inevitable results of our
rejection of God’s beneficence, of our ignoring of
His intent. Were we to follow His clear, simple rule of
right – leaving scrupulously to the individual all
that individual labor produces, and taking for the
community the value that attaches to land by the growth
of the community – not merely could evil modes of
raising public revenue be dispensed with, but all men
would be placed on an equal level of opportunity with
regard to the bounty of their Creator, on an equal level
of opportunity to exert their labor and to enjoy its
fruits.
Then, without drastic restrictive measures, the
forestalling of land would cease. For then the possession
of land would mean only security for the permanence of
its use, and there would be no object for anyone to get
land or to keep land except for use; nor would his
possession of better land than others had confer any
unjust advantage on him, or unjust deprivation on them,
since the equivalent of the advantage would be taken by
the State for the benefit of all.
...
So long as private property in land
continues – so long as some men are treated as owners
of the earth, and other men live on it only by their
sufferance – human wisdom can devise no means by
which the evils of our present condition may be
avoided.
Could even the wisdom of God do so?
How could He? Should He infuse new vigour into the
sunlight, new virtue into the air; new fertility into the
soil, would not all this new bounty go to the owners of the
land?
Should He open the minds of men to
the possibilities of new substances, new adjustments, new
powers, would this do any more to relieve poverty than
steam, electricity and all the numberless discoveries and
inventions of our time have done?
Or, if He were to send down from the heavens above
or cause to gush up from the subterranean depths, food,
clothing – all the things that satisfy man’s
material desires to whom under our laws would all these
belong? Would not this increase and extension of His
bounty merely enable the privileged class more riotously
to roll in wealth, and bring the disinherited class to
more widespread pauperism?
...
It is assumed that there are in the natural order
two classes, the rich and the poor, and that laborers
naturally belong to the poor. It is true that there are
differences in capacity, in diligence, in health and in
strength, that may produce differences in fortune. These,
however, are not the differences that divide men into
rich and poor. The natural differences in powers and
aptitudes are certainly not greater than are natural
differences in stature. But while it is only by selecting
giants and dwarfs that we can find men twice as tall as
others, yet in the difference between rich and poor that
exists today we find some men richer than others by the
thousand-fold and the million-fold!
Nowhere do these differences
between wealth and poverty coincide with differences in
individual powers and aptitudes. The real difference
between rich and poor is the difference between those who
hold the toll gates and those who pay toll; between
tribute receivers and tribute
yielders.
To assume that laborers, even ordinary manual
laborers, are naturally poor is to ignore the fact that
labor is the producer of wealth, and to attribute to the
Natural Law of the Creator an injustice that comes from
man’s impious violation of His benevolent
intention.
In the rudest stage of the arts
it is possible, where justice prevails, for all well men
to earn a living. With the labor-saving appliances of our
time, it should be possible for all to earn much
more. And so, to say that poverty is no disgrace,
is to convey an unreasonable implication; since, in a
condition of social justice, it would, except where
sought from religious motives or imposed by unavoidable
misfortune, imply recklessness or laziness.
The worst evil of
poverty is not in the want of material things, but in the
stunting and distortion of the higher qualities. So,
in another way, the possession of unearned wealth stunts
and distorts what is noblest in man.
The evil is not in wealth itself
– in its command over material things: it is in the
possession of wealth while others are steeped in poverty;
in being raised above touch with the life of humanity; from
its work and its struggles, its hopes and its fears, and
the kind sympathies and generous acts that strengthen faith
in man and trust in God!
God’s commands cannot be evaded
with impunity. If it be His command that men shall earn
their bread by labor, the idle rich must suffer. And they
do!
See the utter vacancy of the lives of
those who live for pleasure; see the vices bred in a class
who, surrounded by poverty, are sated with wealth; see the
pessimism that grows among them; see that terrible
punishment of ennui, of which the poor know so little that
they cannot understand it! ...
As the unduly rich are the corollary
of the unduly poor, so is the soul-destroying quality of
riches but the reflex of the want that embrutes and
degrades. The real evil lies in the injustice from which
unnatural possession and unnatural deprivation both
spring.
This injustice can hardly be charged
on individuals or classes. The existence of private
property in land is a great social wrong from which society
at large suffers, and of which the very rich and the very
poor are alike victims, though at the opposite extremes.
Seeing this, if seems like a violation of Christian charity
to speak of the rich as though they individually were
responsible for the sufferings of the poor. Yet many do
this while at the same time insisting that land monopoly,
the cause of monstrous wealth and degrading poverty, shall
not be touched....
read the whole
article Henry George: The Land for the
People (1889 speech)
We say that all the social difficulties we see
here, all the social difficulties that exist in England
or Scotland, all the social difficulties that are growing
up in the United States--
- the lowness of wages,
- the scarcity of employment,
- the fact that though labor is the producer of
wealth, yet everywhere the laboring class is the poor
class
--are all due to one great primary wrong, that
wrong which makes the natural element necessary to all,
the natural element that was made by the Creator for the
use of all, the property of some of the people, that
great wrong that in every civilized country disinherited
the mass of men of the bounty of their Creator. What we
aim at is not the increase in the number of a privileged
class, not making some thousands of earth owners into
some more thousands. No, no; what we aim at is to secure
the natural and God-given right to the humblest in the
community--to secure to every child born in Ireland, or
in any other country, his natural right to the equal use
of his native land. Read the whole speech
Henry George: Justice
the Object -- Taxation the Means (1890)
Come into the coalfields of Pennsylvania; there
you will frequently find thousands and thousands of
miners unable to work, either locked out by their
employers, or striking as a last resource against their
pitiful wages being cut down a little more.
Why should there be such a struggle? Why don't
these men go to work and take coal for themselves? Not
because there is not coal land enough in those mining
districts. The parts that are worked are small as
compared to the whole coal deposits. The land is not all
used, but it is all owned, and before the men who would
like to go to work can get the opportunity to work the
raw material, they must pay to its owner thousands of
dollars per acre for land that is only nominally
taxed.
Go West, find people filing along, crowding around
every Indian reservation that is about to be opened;
travelling through unused and half-used land in order to
get an opportunity to settle — like men swimming a
river in order to get a drink. Come to this State, ride
through your great valleys, see those vast expanses, only
dotted here and there by a house, without a tree; those
great ranches, cultivated as they are cultivated by
blanket men, who have a little work in ploughing time,
and some more work in reaping time, and who then, after
being fed almost like animals, and sheltered worse than
valuable animals are sheltered, are forced to tramp
through the State. It is the artificial scarcity of
natural opportunities. Is there any wonder that under
this treatment of the land all over the civilised world
there should he want and destitution? Aye, and suffering
— degradation worse in many cases than anything
known among savages, among the great masses of the
people.
How could it be otherwise in a world like this
world, tenanted by land animals, such as men are? How
could the Creator, so long as our laws are what they are
— how could He, himself, relieve it? Suppose that
in answer to the prayers that ascend for the relief of
poverty, the Almighty were to rain down wealth from
heaven, or cause it to spout tip from the bowels of the
earth. Who, under our present system, would own it? The
landowner. There would be no benefit to labour. Consider,
conceive any kind of a world your imagination will
permit. Conceive of heaven itself, which, from the very
necessities of our minds, we cannot otherwise think of
than as having an expansion of space — what would
be the result in heaven itself, if the people who should
first get to heaven were to parcel it out in big tracts
among themselves?
Oh, the wickedness of it; oh, the blasphemy of it!
Worse than atheists are those so-called Christians who by
implication, if not by direct statement, attribute to the
God they call on us to worship, the God that they say
with their lips is all love and mercy, this bitter
suffering which today exists in the very centres of our
civilisation.
Read the entire article
Henry George:
Concentrations of Wealth Harm
America(excerpt
from Social
Problems)
(1883)
Can Anyone Be Rich?
The comfortable theory that it is in the nature of
things that some should be poor and some should be rich,
and that the gross and constantly increasing inequalities
in the distribution of wealth imply no fault in our
institutions, pervades our literature, and is taught in
the press, in the church, in school and in
college.
This is a free country, we are told
-- every man has a vote and every man has a chance. The
laborer's son may become President; poor boys of to-day
will be millionaires thirty or forty years from now, and
the millionaire's grandchildren will probably be poor. What
more can be asked? If a man has energy, industry, prudence
and foresight, he may win his way to great wealth. If he
has not the ability to do this he must not complain of
those who have. If some enjoy much and do little, it is
because they, or their parents, possessed superior
qualities which enabled, them to "acquire property" or
"make money." If others must work hard and get little, it
is because they have not yet got their start, because they
are ignorant, shiftless, unwilling to practise that economy
necessary for the first accumulation of capital; or because
their fathers were wanting in these respects. The
inequalities in condition result from the inequalities of
human nature, from the difference in the powers and
capacities of different men. If one has to toil ten or
twelve hours a day for a few hundred dollars a year, while
another, doing little or no hard work, gets an income of
many thousands, it is because all that the former
contributes to the augmentation of the common stock of
wealth is little more than the mere force of his muscles.
He can expect little more than the animal, because he
brings into play little more than animal powers. He is but
a private in the ranks of the great army of industry, who
has but to stand still or march, as he is bid. The other is
the organizer, the general, who guides and wields the whole
great machine, who must think, plan and provide; and his
larger income is only commensurate with the far higher and
rarer powers which he exercises, and the far greater
importance of the function he fulfils. Shall not education
have its reward, and skill its payment? What incentive
would there be to the toil needed to learn to do anything
well were great prizes not to be gained by those who learn
to excel? It would not merely be gross injustice to refuse
a Raphael or a Rubens more than a housepainter, but it
would prevent the development of great painters. To destroy
inequalities in condition would be to destroy the incentive
to progress. To quarrel with them is to quarrel with the
laws of nature. We might as well rail against the length of
the days or the phases of the moon; complain that there are
valleys and mountains; zones of tropical heat and regions
of eternal ice. And were we by violent measures to divide
wealth equally, we should accomplish nothing but harm; in a
little while there would be inequalities as great as
before.
This, in substance, is the teaching
which we constantly hear. It is accepted by some because it
is flattering to their vanity, in accordance with their
interests or pleasing to their hope; by others, because it
is dinned into their ears. Like all false theories that
obtain wide acceptance, it contains much truth. But it is
truth isolated from other truth or alloyed with falsehood.
...
I am not denouncing the rich, nor
seeking, by speaking of these things, to excite envy and
hatred; but if we would get a clear understanding of social
problems, we must recognize the fact that it is
due
- to monopolies which we permit and
create,
- to advantages which we give one man over
another,
- to methods of extortion sanctioned by law and
by public opinion,
that some men are enabled to get so enormously
rich while others remain so miserably poor. If we look around us and note the elements of
monopoly, extortion and spoliation which go to the
building up of all, or nearly all, fortunes, we see on
the one hand now disingenuous are those who preach to us
that there is nothing wrong in social relations and that
the inequalities in the distribution of wealth spring
from the inequalities of human nature; and on the other
hand, we see how wild are those who talk as though
capital were a public enemy, and propose plans for
arbitrarily restricting the acquisition of wealth.
Capital is a good; the capitalist is a
helper, if he is not also a monopolist. We can safely let
any one get as rich as he can if he will not despoil
others in doing so. There are deep wrongs
in the present constitution of society, but they are not
wrongs inherent in the constitution of man nor in those
social laws which are as truly the laws of the Creator as
are the laws of the physical universe. They are
wrongs resulting from bad adjustments which it is within
our power to amend. The ideal social
state is not that in which each gets an equal amount of
wealth, but in which each gets in proportion to his
contribution to the general stock. And in such a social state there would not be less
incentive to exertion than now; there would be far more
incentive. Men will be more industrious and more
moral, better workmen and better citizens, if each takes
his earnings and carries them home to his family, than
where they put their earnings in a "pot" and gamble for
them until some have far more than they could have
earned, and others have little or nothing.
...
Read the entire
article
Gems from George, a
themed collection of excerpts from the writings of Henry
George (with links to sources)
FIVE centuries ago the wealth-producing power of
England, man for man, was small indeed compared with what
it is now. Not merely were all the great inventions and
discoveries which since the Introduction of steam have
revolutionized mechanical industry then undreamed of, but
even agriculture was far ruder and less productive.
Artificial grasses had not been discovered. The potato,
the carrot, the turnip, the beet, and many other plants
and vegetables which the farmer now finds most prolific,
had not been introduced. The advantages which ensue from
rotation of crops were unknown. Agricultural implements
consisted of the spade, the sickle, the flail, the rude
plow and the harrow. Cattle had not been bred to more
than one-half the size they average now, and sheep did
not yield half the fleece. Roads, where there were roads,
were extremely bad, wheel vehicles scarce and rude, and
places a hundred miles from each other were, in
difficulties of transportation, practically as far apart
as London and Hong Kong, or San Francisco and New York,
are now.
Yet patient students of those times tell us that the
condition of the English laborer was not only relatively,
but absolutely better in those rude times than it is in
England today, after five centuries of advance in the
productive arts. They tell us that the workingman did not
work so hard as he does now, and lived better; that he
was exempt from the harassing dread of being forced by
loss of employment to want and beggary, or of leaving a
family that must apply to charity to avoid I starvation.
Pauperism as it prevails in the rich England of the
nineteenth century was in the far poorer England of the
fourteenth century absolutely unknown. Medicine was
empirical and superstitious, sanitary regulations and
precautions were all but unknown. There were frequently
plague and occasionally famine, for, owing to the
difficulties of transportation, the scarcity of one
district could not "be relieved by the plenty of another.
But men did not as they do now, starve in the midst of
abundance; and what is perhaps the most significant fact
of all is that not only were women and children not
worked as they are today, but the eight-hour system,
which even the working classes of the United States, with
all the profusion of labor-saving machinery and
appliances have not yet attained, was then the common
system! — Protection or Free Trade —
Chapter 22: The Real Weakness of Free Trade. abridged
•
econlib
The Savage and the Modern
Workman
THE aggregate produce of the labor of a savage tribe is
small, but each member is capable of an independent life.
He can build his own habitation, hew out or stitch
together his own canoe, make his own clothing,
manufacture his own weapons, snares, tools and ornaments.
He has all the knowledge of nature possessed by his tribe
— knows what vegetable productions are fit for
food, and where they maybe found; knows the habits and
resorts of beasts, birds, fishes and insects; can pilot
himself by the sun or the stars, by the turning of
blossoms or the mosses on the trees; is, in short,
capable of supplying all his wants. He may be cut off
from his fellows and still live; and thus possesses an
independent power which makes him a free contracting
party in his relations to the community of which he is a
member.
Compare with this savage the laborer in the lowest ranks
of civilized society, whose life is spent in producing
but one thing, or oftener but the infinitesimal part of
one thing, out of the multiplicity of things that
constitute the wealth of society and go to supply even
the most primitive wants; who not only cannot make even
the tools required for his work, but often works with
tools that he does not own, and can never hope to own.
Compelled to even closer and more continuous labor than
the savage, and gaining by it no more than the savage
gets — the mere necessaries of life — he
loses the independence of the savage. He is not only
unable to apply his own powers to the direct satisfaction
of his own wants, but, without the concurrence of many
others, he is unable to apply them indirectly to the
satisfaction of his wants. He is a mere link in an
enormous chain of producers and consumers, helpless to
separate himself, and helpless to move, except as they
move. The worse his position in society, the more
dependent is he on society; the more utterly unable does
he become to do anything for himself. The very power of
exerting his labor for the satisfaction of his wants
passes from his own control, and may be taken away or
restored by the actions of others, or by general causes
over which he has no more influence than he has over the
motions of the solar system. The primeval curse comes to
be looked upon as a boon, and men think, and talk, and
clamor, and legislate as though monotonous manual labor
in itself were a good and not an evil, an end and not a
means. Under such circumstances, the man loses the
essential quality of manhood — the godlike power of
modifying and controlling conditions. He becomes a slave,
a machine, a commodity — a thing, in some respects,
lower than the animal.
I am no sentimental admirer of the savage state. I do not
get my ideas of the untutored children of nature from
Rousseau, or Chateaubriand, or Cooper. I am conscious of
its material and mental poverty, and its low and narrow
range. I believe that civilization is not only the
natural destiny of man, but the enfranchisement,
elevation, and refinement of all his powers, and think
that it is only in such moods as may lead him to envy the
cud-chewing cattle, that a man who is free to the
advantages of civilization could look with regret upon
the savage state. But, nevertheless, I think no one who
will open his eyes to the facts, can resist the
conclusion that there are in the heart of our
civilization large classes with whom the veriest savage
could not afford to exchange. It is my deliberate opinion
that if, standing on the threshold of being, one were
given the choice of entering life as a Terra del Fuegan,
a black fellow of Australia, an Esquimaux in the Arctic
Circle, or among the lowest classes in such a highly
civilized country as Great Britain, he would make
infinitely the better choice in selecting the lot of the
savage. For those classes who in the midst of wealth are
condemned to want, suffer all the privations of the
savage, without his sense of personal freedom; they are
condemned to more than his narrowness and littleness,
without opportunity for the growth of his rude virtues;
if their horizon is wider, it is but to reveal blessings
that they cannot enjoy. —
Progress & Poverty
— Book V, Chapter 2: The Problem Solved: The
Persistence of Poverty Amid Advancing Wealth
Poverty Unnatural
OR let him go to Edinburgh, the "modern Athens," of which
Scotsmen speak with pride, and in buildings from
whose roofs a bowman might strike the spires of twenty
churches he will find human beings living as he would not
keep his meanest dog. Let him toil up the stairs of one
of those monstrous buildings, let him enter one of those
"dark houses," let him close the door, and in the
blackness think what life must be in such a place. Then
let him try the reduction to iniquity. And if he go to
that good charity (but, alas! how futile is Charity
without Justice!) where little children are kept while
their mothers are at work, and children are fed who would
otherwise go hungry, he may see infants whose limbs are
shrunken from want of nourishment. Perhaps they may tell
him, as they told me, of that little girl, barefooted,
ragged, and hungry, who, when they gave her bread, raised
her eyes and clasped her hands, and thanked our Father in
Heaven for His bounty to her. They who told me that never
dreamed, I think, of its terrible meaning. But I ask the
Duke of Argyll, did that little child, thankful for that
poor dole, get what our Father provided for her? Is He so
niggard? If not, what is it, who is it, that stands,
between such children and our Father's bounty? If it be
an institution, is it not our duty to God and to our
neighbor to rest not till we destroy it? If it be a man,
were it not better for him that a millstone were hanged
about his neck and he were cast into the depths of the
sea? — The Reduction to Iniquity (a reply to
the Duke of Argyll), The Nineteenth Century, July,
1884
WE are so accustomed to poverty that even in the most
advanced countries we regard it as the natural lot of the
great masses of the people; that we take it as a matter
of course that even in our highest civilization large
classes should want the necessaries of healthful life,
and the vast majority should only get a poor and pinched
living by the hardest toil. There are professors of
political economy who teach that this condition of things
is the result of social laws of which it is idle to
complain! There are ministers of religion who
preach that this is the condition which an all-wise,
all-powerful Creator intended for His children! If an
architect were to build a theater so that not more than
one-tenth of the audience could see and hear, we should
call him a bungler and a botcher. If a man were to give a
feast and provide so little food that nine-tenths of his
guests must go away hungry, we should call him a fool, or
worse. Yet so accustomed are we to poverty, that even the
preachers of what passes for Christianity tell us that
the great Architect of the Universe, to whose infinite
skill all nature testifies, has made such a botch job of
this world that the vast majority of the human creatures
whom He has called into it are condemned by the
conditions he has imposed to want, suffering, and
brutalizing toil that gives no opportunity for the
development of mental powers — must pass their
lives in a hard struggle to merely live! —
Social Problems — Chapter 8: That We All Might Be
Rich
THE general subjection of the many to the few, which
we meet with wherever society has reached a certain
development, has resulted from the appropriation of land
as individual property. It is the ownership of the soil
that everywhere gives the ownership of the men that live
upon it. It is slavery of this kind to which the enduring
pyramids and the colossal monuments of Egypt yet bear
witness, and of the institution of which we have,
perhaps, a vague tradition in the biblical story of the
famine during which the Pharaoh purchased up the lands of
the people. It was slavery of this kind to which, in the
twilight of history, the conquerors of Greece reduced the
original inhabitants of that peninsula, transforming them
into helots by making them pay rent for their lands. It
was the growth of the latifundia, or great landed estates, which
transmuted the population of ancient Italy from a race of
hardy husbandmen, whose robust virtues conquered the
world, into a race of cringing bondsmen; it was the
appropriation of the land as the absolute property of
their chieftains which gradually turned the descendants
of free and equal Gallic, Teutonic and Hunnish warriors
into colonii and villains, and which changed the
independent burghers of Sclavonic village communities
into the boors of Russia and the serfs of Poland; which
instituted the feudalism of China and Japan, as well as
that of Europe, and which made the High Chiefs of
Polynesia the all but absolute masters of their fellows.
How it came to pass that the Aryan shepherds and warriors
who, as comparative philology tells us, descended from
the common birth-place of the Indo-Germanic race into the
lowlands of India, were turned into the suppliant and
cringing Hindoo, the Sanscrit verse which I have before
quoted gives us a hint. The white parasols and the
elephants mad with pride of the Indian Rajah are the
flowers of grants of land. —
Progress & Poverty
— Book VII, Chapter 1, Justice of the Remedy:
Injustice of private property in land
TRACE to their root the causes that are thus producing
want in the midst of plenty, ignorance in the midst of
intelligence, aristocracy in democracy, weakness in
strength — that are giving to our civilization a
one-sided and unstable development, and you will find it
something which this Hebrew statesman three thousand
years ago perceived and guarded against. Moses saw that
the real cause of the enslavement of the masses of Egypt
was, what has everywhere produced enslavement, the
possession by a class of the land upon which, and from
which, the whole people must live. He saw that to permit
in land the same unqualified private ownership that by
natural right attaches to the things produced by labor,
would be inevitably to separate the people into the very
rich and the very poor, inevitably to enslave labor
— to make the few the masters of. the many, no
matter what the political forms, to bring vice and
degradation, no matter what the religion.
And with the foresight of the philosophic statesman who
legislates not for the need of a day, but for all the
future, he sought, in ways suited to his times and
conditions, to guard against this error. — Moses
THE women who by the thousands are bending over their
needles or sewing machines, thirteen, fourteen, sixteen
hours a day; these widows straining and striving to bring
up the little ones deprived of their natural
bread-winner; the children that are growing up in squalor
and wretchedness, under-clothed, under-fed,
under-educated, even in this city without any place to
play — growing up under conditions in which only a
miracle can keep them pure — under conditions which
condemn them in advance to the penitentiary or the
brothel — they suffer, they die, because we
permit them to be robbed, robbed of their birthright,
robbed by a system which disinherits the vast majority of
the children that come into the world. There is enough
and to spare for them. Had they the equal rights in the
estate which their Creator has given them, there would be
no young girls forced to unwomanly toil to eke out a mere
existence, no widows finding it such a bitter, bitter
struggle to put bread in the mouths of their little
children; no such misery and squalor as we may see here
in the greatest of American cities; misery and squalor
that are deepest in the largest and richest centers of
our civilization today. — Thou
Shalt Not Steal
Land-Ownership the Cause of Poverty and
Degradation
THE poverty to which in advancing
civilization great masses of men are condemned, is not
the freedom from distraction and temptation which sages
have sought and philosophers have praised: it is a
degrading and embruting slavery, that cramps the higher
nature, dulls the finer feelings, and drives men by its
pain to acts which the brutes would refuse. It is into
this helpless, hopeless poverty, that crushes manhood and
destroys womanhood, that robs even childhood of its
innocence and joy, that the working classes are being
driven by a force which acts upon them like a resistless
and unpitying machine. The Boston collar manufacturer who
pays his girls two cents an hour may commiserate their
condition, but he, as they, is governed by the law of
competition, and cannot pay more and carry on his
business, for exchange is not governed by sentiment. And
so, through all intermediate gradations, up to those who
receive the earnings of labor without return, in the rent
of land, it is the inexorable laws of supply and demand,
a power with which the individual can no more quarrel or
dispute than with the winds and the tides, that seem to
press down the lower classes into the slavery of
want.
But, in reality, the cause is that which always has, and
always must result in slavery — the monopolization
by some of what nature has designed for all. . . .
Private ownership of land is the nether millstone.
Material progress is the upper millstone. Between them;
with an increasing pressure, the working classes are
being ground. —
Progress & Poverty —
Book VII, Chapter 2, Justice of the Remedy: Enslavement
of laborers the ultimate result of private property in
land
IT is not in the relations of capital and labor; it is
not in the pressure of population against subsistence
that an explanation of the unequal development of our
civilization is to be found. The great cause of
inequality in the distribution of wealth is inequality in
the ownership of land. The ownership of land is the great
fundamental fact which ultimately determines the social,
the political and, consequently, the intellectual and
moral condition of a people. And it must be so. For land
is the habitation of man, the storehouse upon which he
must draw for all his needs, the material to which his
labor must be applied for the supply of all his desires;
for even the products of the sea cannot be taken, the
light of the sun enjoyed, or any of the forces of nature
utilized, without the use of land or its products. On the
land we are born, from it we live, to it we return again
— children of the soil as truly as is the blade of
grass or the flower of the field. —
Progress & Poverty
— Book V, Chapter 2: The Problem Solved: The
persistence of poverty amid advancing wealth
THERE is nothing strange or inexplicable in the phenomena
that are now perplexing the world. It is not that
material progress is not in itself a good, it is not that
nature has called into being children for whom she has
failed to provide; it is not that the Creator has left on
natural laws a taint of injustice at which even the human
mind revolts, that material progress brings such bitter
fruits. That amid our highest civilization men faint and
die with want is not due to the niggardliness of nature,
but to the injustice of man. Vice and misery, poverty and
pauperism, are not the legitimate results of increase of
population and industrial development; they only follow
increase of population and industrial development because
land is treated as private property — they are the
direct and necessary results of the violation of the
supreme law of justice, involved in giving to some men
the exclusive possession of that which nature provides
for all men. —
Progress & Poverty
— Book VII, Chapter 1, Justice of the Remedy:
Injustice of private property in land
LABOR may be likened to a man who as he carries home
his earnings is waylaid by a series of robbers. One
demands this much, and another that much, but last of all
stands one who demands all that is left, save just enough
to enable the victim to maintain life and come forth next
day to work. So long as this last robber remains, what
will it benefit such a man to drive off any or all of the
other robbers?
Such is the situation of labor today throughout the
civilized world. And the robber that takes all that is
left, is private property in land. Improvement, no matter
how great, and reform, no matter how beneficial in
itself, cannot help that class who, deprived of all right
to the use of the material elements, have only the power
to labor — a power as useless in itself as a sail
without wind, a pump without water, or a saddle without a
horse. — Protection or Free Trade —
Chapter 25: The Robber That Takes All That Is Left -
econlib | abridged
THERE is but one way to remove an evil — and that
is, to remove its cause. Poverty deepens as wealth
increases, and wages are forced down while
productive power grows, because land, which is the source
of all wealth and the field of all labor, is monopolized.
To extirpate poverty, to make wages what justice commands
they should be, the full earnings of the laborer, we must
therefore substitute for the individual ownership of land
a common ownership. Nothing else will go to the cause of
the evil — in nothing else is there the slightest
hope. —
Progress & Poverty
— Book VI, Chapter 2, The Remedy: The True
Remedy
AND while in the nature of things any change from
wrong-doing to right-doing must entail loss upon those
who profit by the wrong-doing, and this can no more be
prevented than can parallel lines be made to meet; yet it
must also be remembered that in the nature of things the
loss is merely relative, the gain absolute. Whoever will
examine the subject will see that in the abandonment of
the present unnatural and unjust method of raising public
revenues and the adoption of the natural and just method
even those who relatively lose will be enormous gainers.
— A Perplexed
Philosopher
(Compensation)
MANY landholders are laborers of one sort or another. And
it would be hard to find a landowner not a laborer, who
is not also a capitalist — while the general rule
is, that the larger the landowner the greater the
capitalist. So true is this that in common thought the
characters are confounded. Thus, to put all taxes on the
value of land, while it would be to largely reduce all
great fortunes, would in no case leave the rich man
penniless. The Duke of Westminster, who owns a
considerable part of the site of London, is probably the
richest landowner in the world. To take all his ground
rents by taxation would largely reduce his enormous
income, but would still leave him his buildings and all
the income from them, and doubtless much personal
property in various other shapes. He would still have all
he could by any possibility enjoy, and a much better
state of society in which to enjoy it. —
Progress & Poverty
— Book IX, Chapter 3, Effects of the Remedy: Of the
Effect Upon Individuals and Classes
THE existence of private property in land is a great
social wrong from which society at large suffers and of
which the very rich and the very poor are alike victims,
though at the opposite extremes.
Seeing this, it seems to us like a violation of Christian
charity to speak of the rich as though they individually
were responsible for the sufferings of the poor. Yet,
while you do this, you insist that the cause of monstrous
wealth and degrading poverty shall not be touched. Here
is a man with a disfiguring and dangerous excrescence.
One physician would kindly, gently, but firmly remove it.
Another insists that it shall not be removed, but at the
same time holds up the poor victim to hatred and
ridicule. Which is right- ? —
The Condition of Labor, an Open Letter to Pope Leo
XIII
Rich and Poor Alike Gainers
THE evil is not in wealth in itself —
in its command over material things; it is in the
possession of wealth while others are steeped in poverty;
in being raised above touch with the life of humanity,
from its work and its struggles, its hopes and its fears,
and above all, from the love that sweetens life, and the
kindly sympathies and generous acts that strengthen faith
in man and trust in God. Consider how the rich see the
meaner side of human nature; how they are surrounded by
flatterers and sycophants; how they find ready
instruments not only to gratify vicious impulses, but to
prompt and stimulate them; how they must constantly be on
guard lest they be swindled; how often they must suspect
an ulterior motive behind kindly deed or friendly word;
how, if they try to be generous, they are beset by
shameless beggars and scheming impostors; how often the
family affections are chilled for them, and their deaths
anticipated with the ill-concealed joy of expectant
possession. The worst evil of poverty is not in the want
of material things, but in the stunting and distortion of
the higher qualities. So, though in another way, the
possession of unearned wealth likewise stunts and
distorts what is noblest in man.
God's commands cannot be evaded with impunity. If it be
God's command that men shall earn their bread by labor,
the idle rich must suffer. And they do. —
The Condition of Labor, an Open Letter to Pope Leo
XIII
IT seems to me that in a condition of society in which
no one need fear poverty, no one would desire great
wealth — at least no one would take the trouble to
strive and to strain for it as men do now. For,
certainly, the spectacle of men who have only a few years
to live, slaving away their time for the sake of dying
rich, is in itself so unnatural and absurd, that in a
state of society where the abolition of the fear of want
had dissipated the envious admiration with which the
masses of men now regard the possession of great riches,
whoever would toil to acquire more than he cared to use
would be looked upon as we would now look on a man who
would thatch his head with half a dozen hats, or walk
around in the hot sun with an overcoat on. When everyone
is sure of being able to get enough, no one will care to
make a packhorse of himself. —
Progress & Poverty
— Book IX, Chapter 2: Effects of the Remedy, upon
distribution and thence on production
MEN instinctively admire virtue and truth, but the sting
of want and the fear of want make them even more strongly
admire the rich and sympathize with the fortunate. It is
well to be honest and just, and men will commend it; but
he who by fraud and injustice gets him a million dollars
will have more respect and admiration and influence, more
eye service and lip service, if not heart service, than
he who refuses it. The one may have his reward in the
future; he may know that his name is writ in the Book of
Life, and that for him is the white robe and the palm
branch of the victor against temptation; but the other
has his reward in the present. His name is writ in the
list of "our substantial citizens;" he has the courtship
of men and the flattery of women; the best pew in the
church and the personal regard of the eloquent clergyman,
who in the name of Christ preaches the Gospel of Dives,
and tones down into a meaningless flower of. eastern
speech the stern metaphor of the camel and the needle's
eye. He may be a patron of arts, a Maecenas to men of
letters; may profit by the converse of the intelligent,
and be polished by the attrition of the refined. His alms
may feed the poor, and help the struggling, and bring
sunshine into desolate places; and noble public
institutions commemorate, after he is gone, his name and
his fame. It is not in the guise of a hideous monster,
with horns and tail, that Satan tempts the children of
men, but as an angel of light. His promises are not alone
of the kingdoms of the world, but of mental and moral
principalities and powers. He appeals not only to the
animal appetites, but to the cravings that stir in man
because he is more than an animal. —
Progress & Poverty —
Book IX, Chapter 4, Effects of the Remedy: Of the Changes
that would be Wrought in Social Organization and Social
Life
"THE poor ye have always with you." If ever a scripture
has been wrested to the devil's service, this is that
scripture. How often have these words been distorted from
their obvious meaning to soothe conscience into
acquiescence in human misery and degradation — to
bolster that blasphemy, the very negation and denial of
Christ's teachings, that the All Wise and Most Merciful,
the Infinite Father, has decreed that so many of His
creatures must be poor in order that others of His
creatures to whom He wills the good things of life should
enjoy the please and virtue of doling out alms!
"The poor ye have always with you," said Christ; but all
His teachings supply the limitation, "until the coming of
the Kingdom." In that kingdom of God on earth, that kingdom of justice and love
for which He taught His followers to strive and pray,
there will be no poor. —
Social Problems — Chapter 8: That We All Might Be
Rich.
WE naturally despise poverty; and it is reasonable that
we should. I do not say — I distinctly repudiate it
— that the people who are poor are poor always from
their own fault, or even in most cases; but it ought to
be so. If any good man or woman had the power to create a
world, it would be a sort of a world in which no one
would be poor unless he was lazy or vicious. But that is
just precisely the kind of a world that this is; that is
just precisely, the kind of a world that the Creator has
made. Nature gives to labor, and to labor alone; there
must be human work before any article of wealth can be
produced; and, in a natural state of things, the man who
toiled honestly and well would be the rich man, and he
who did not work would be poor. We have so reversed the
order of nature, that we are accustomed to think of a
working-man as a poor man. —
The Crime of Poverty
... go to "Gems from
George"
Louis Post: Outlines
of Louis F. Post's Lectures, with Illustrative Notes and
Charts (1894)
III. THE SINGLE TAX AS A
SOCIAL REFORM.
But the single tax is more than a revenue system.
Great as are its merits in this respect, they are but
incidental to its character as a social reform.31 And
that some social reform, which shall be simple in method
but fundamental in character, is most urgently needed we
have only to look about us to see.
31. There are two classes of single tax
advocates. Those who advocate it as a reform in
taxation alone, regardless of its effects upon social
adjustments, are called "single tax men limited"; those
who advocate it both as a reform in taxation and as the
mode of securing equal rights to land, are called
"single tax men unlimited."
Poverty is widespread and pitiable. This we know. Its
general manifestations are so common that even good men
look upon it as a providential provision for enabling the
rich to drive camels through needles' eyes by exercising
the modern virtue of organized giving.32 Its occasional
manifestations in recurring periods of "hard times"33 are
like epidemics of a virulent disease, which excite even
the most contented to ask if they may not be the next
victims. Its spasms of violence threaten society with
anarchy on the one hand, and, through panic-stricken
efforts at restraint, with loss of liberty on the other.
And it persists and deepens despite the continuous
increase of wealth producing power.34
32. Not all charity is contemptible.
Those charitable people, who, knowing that individuals
suffer, hasten to their relief, deserve the respect and
affection they receive. That kind of charity is
neighborliness; it is love. And perhaps in modern
circumstances organization is necessary to make it
effective. But organized charity as a cherished social
institution is a different thing. It is not love, nor
is it inspired by love; it is simply sanctified
selfishness, at the bottom of which will be found the
blasphemous notion that in the economy of God the poor
are to be forever with us that the rich may gain heaven
by alms-giving.
Suppose a hole in the sidewalk into
which passers-by continually fall, breaking their arms,
their legs, and sometimes their necks. We should
respect charitable people who, without thought of
themselves, went to the relief of the sufferers,
binding the broken limbs of the living, and decently
burying the dead. But what should we say of those who,
when some one proposed to fill up the hole to prevent
further suffering, should say, "Oh, you mustn't fill up
that hole! Whatever in the world should we charitable
people do to be saved if we had no broken legs and arms
to bind, and no broken-necked people to bury?"
Of some kinds of charity it has been
well said that they are "that form of
self-righteousness which makes us give to others the
things that already belong to them." They suggest the
old nursery rhyme:
"There was once a considerate
crocodile,
Which lay on a bank of the river Nile.
And he swallowed a fish, with a face of woe,
While his tears flowed fast to the stream
below.
'I am mourning,' said he, 'the untimely fate
Of the dear little fish which I just now ate.'"
Read Chapter viii of "Social Problems,"
by Henry George, entitled, "That We All Might Be
Rich."
33. Differences between "hard times" and
"good times" are but differences in degrees of poverty
and in the people who suffer from it. Times are always
hard with the multitude. But the voice of the multitude
is too weak to be heard at ordinary times through the
ordinary trumpets of public opinion. They are not
regarded nor do they regard themselves as people of any
importance in the industrial world, so long as the
general wheels of business revolve. It is only when
poverty has eaten its way up through the various strata
of struggling and pinching and squeezing and squirming
humanity, and with its cancerous tentacles touched the
superincumbent layers of manufacturing nabobs, merchant
princes, railroad kinds, great bankers and great
landowners that we hear any general complain of "hard
times."
34. "Could a man of the last century
— a Franklin or a Priestley — have seen, in
a vision of the future, the steamship taking the place
of the sailing vessel, the railroad train of the wagon,
the reaping machine of the scythe, the threshing
machine of the flail; could he have heard the throb of
the engines that in obedience to human will, and for
the satisfaction of human desire, exert a power greater
than that of all the men and all the beasts of burden
of the earth combined; could he have seen the forest
tree transformed into finished lumber — into
doors, sashes, blinds, boxes or barrels, with hardly
the touch of a human hand; the great workshops where
boots and shoes are turned out by the case with less
labor than the old-fashioned cobbler could have put on
a sole; the factories where, under the eye of a girl,
cotton becomes cloth faster than hundreds of stalwart
weavers could have turned it out with their hand-looms;
could he have seen steam hammers shaping mammoth shafts
and mighty anchors, and delicate machinery making tiny
watches; the diamond drill cutting through the heart of
the rocks, and coal oil sparing the whale; could he
have realized the enormous saving of labor resulting
from improved facilities of exchange and communication
— sheep killed in Australia eaten fresh in
England and the order given by the London banker in the
afternoon executed in San Francisco in the morning of
the same day; could he have conceived of the hundred
thousand improvements which these only suggest, what
would he have inferred as to the social condition of
mankind?
"It would not have seemed like an
inference; further than the vision went, it would have
seemed as though he saw; and his heart would have
leaped and his nerves would have thrilled, as one who
from a height beholds just ahead of the thirst-stricken
caravan the living gleam of rustling woods and the
glint of laughing waters. Plainly, in the sight of the
imagination, he would have beheld these new forces
elevating society from its very foundations, lifting
the very poorest above the possibility of want,
exempting the very lowest from anxiety for the material
needs of life ... And out of these bounteous material
conditions he would have seen arising, as necessary
sequences, moral conditions realizing the golden age of
which mankind have always dreamed. ... More or less
vague or clear, these have been the hopes, these the
dreams born of the improvements which give this
wonderful century its preeminence. ... It is true that
disappointment has followed disappointment, and that
discovery upon discovery, and invention after
invention, have neither lessened the toil of those who
most need respite, nor brought plenty to the poor. But
there have been so many things to which it seemed this
failure could be laid, that up to our time the new
faith has hardly weakened. ... Now, however, we are
coming into collision with facts which there can be no
mistaking. ... And, unpleasant as it may be to admit
it, it is at last becoming evident that the enormous
increase in productive power which has marked the
present century and is still going on with accelerating
ratio, has no tendency to extirpate poverty or to
lighten the burdens of those compelled to toil. It
simply widens the gulf between Dives
and Lazarus, and makes the struggle for existence
more intense. The march of invention has clothed
mankind with powers of which a century ago the boldest
imagination could not have dreamed. But in factories
where labor-saving machinery has reached its most
wonderful development, little children are at work;
wherever the new forces are anything like fully
utilized, large classes are maintained by charity or
live on the verge of recourse to it; amid the greatest
accumulations of wealth, men die of starvation, and
puny infant suckle dry breasts; while everywhere the
greed of gain, the worship of wealth, shows the force
of the fear of want. — Progress and Poverty,
Introduction.
That much of our poverty is involuntary may be proved,
if proof be necessary, by the magnitude of charitable
work that aims to help only the "deserving poor"; and as
to undeserving cases — the cases of voluntary
poverty — who can say but that they, if not due to
birth and training in the environs of degraded poverty,
35 are the despairing culminations of long-continued
struggles for respectable independence? 36 How can we
know that they are not essentially like the rest —
involuntary and deserving? It is a profound distinction
that a clever writer of fiction 37 makes when he speaks
of "the hopeful and the hopeless poor." There is, indeed,
little difference between voluntary and involuntary
poverty, between the "deserving" and the "undeserving"
poor, except that the "deserving" still have hope, while
from the "undeserving" all hope, if they ever knew any,
has gone.
35. The leader of one of the labor
strikes of the early eighties, a hard-working,
respectable, and self-respecting man, told me that the
deprivations which he himself suffered as a workingman
were as nothing compared with the fear for the future
of his children that he felt whenever he thought of the
repulsive surroundings, physical and moral, in which,
owing to his poverty, he was compelled to bring them
up.
Professor Francis Wayland, Dean of the
Yale law school, wrote in the Charities Review
for March, 1893: "Under our eyes and within our reach,
children are being reared from infancy amid
surroundings containing every conceivable element of
degradation, depravity and vice. Why, then, should we
be surprised that we are surrounded by a horde of
juvenile delinquents, that the police reports in our
cities teem with the exploits of precocious little
villains, that reform schools are crowded with
hopelessly abandoned young offenders? How could it be
otherwise? What else could be expected from such
antecedents, from such ever-present examples of
flagrant vice? Short of a miracle, how could any child
escape the moral contagion of such an environment? How
could he retain a single vestige of virtue, a single
honest impulse, a single shred of respect for the
rights of others, after passing through such an ordeal
of iniquity? What is there left on which to build up a
better character?
In the Arena of July, 1893,
Helen Campbell says, "It would seem at times as if the
workshop meant only a form of preparation for the
hospital, the workhouse and the prison, since the
workers therein become inoculated with trade diseases,
mutilated by trade appliances, and corrupted by trade
associates till no healthy fiber, mental, moral or
physical, remains."
Such testimony is abundant. But no
further citation is necessary to arouse the conscience
of the merciful and the just, and any amount of proof
would not affect those self-satisfied mortals whom
Kipling describes when he says that "there are men who,
when their own front doors are closed, will swear that
the whole world's warm."
36. Some years ago a gentleman, now well
and favorably known in New York public life, told me of
a ragged tramp whom he had brought, more to gratify a
whim perhaps than in any spirit of philanthropy, from a
neighboring camp of tramps to his house for breakfast.
After breakfast the host asked his guest, in the course
of conversation, why he lived the life of a tramp. This
in substance was the tramp's reply:
"I am a mechanic and used to be a good
one, though not so exceptionally good as to be safe
from the competition of the great class of average
workers. I had a family — a wife and two
children. In the hard times of the seventies I lost my
job. For a while we lived upon our little savings; but
sickness came and our savings were used up. My wife and
children died. Everything was gone but self-respect.
Then I traveled, looking for work which could not be
had at home. I traveled afoot; I could afford no other
way. For days I hunted for work, begging food and
sleeping in barns or under trees; but no work could I
get. Once or twice I was arrested as a vagrant. Then I
fell in with a party of tramps and with them drifted
into the city. Winter came on. I still had a desire to
regain my old place as a self-respecting man, but work
was scarce and nothing that I could do could I find to
do, except some little job now and then which was given
to me as pennies are given to beggars. I slept mostly
in station houses. Part of the time I was undergoing
sentence for vagrancy. In the spring I tramped again.
But now I did not hunt for work. My self-respect was
gone so completely that I had no ambition to regain it.
I was a loafer and a jail-bird. I had no family to
support, and I had found that, barring the question of
self-respect, I was about as well off as were average
workmen. After years of tramping this opinion is
unchanged. I am always sure of enough to eat and a
place to sleep in — not very good often, but good
enough. I should not be sure of that if I were a
workingman. I might lose my job and go hungry rather
than beg. I might be unable to pay my rent and so be
turned upon the street. I might marry again and have a
family which would be condemned to the hard life of the
average workingman's family. And as for society, why, I
have society. Tramps are good fellows — sociable
fellows, bright fellows many of them. Life as a tramp
is not half bad when you compare it with the
workingman's life, leaving out the question of
self-respect, of course. You must leave that out. No
man can be a tramp for good until he loses that. But a
period of hard times makes many a chap lose it. And as
I have lost it I would rather be a tramp than a
workingman. I have tried both. By the way, Mr.
——, this is a very good cigar — this
brand of yours. I seldom smoke much better cigars."
The facts in detail of this man's story
may have been false; they probably were. But so were
the facts in detail of Bunyan's "Pilgrim's Progress."
There is, however, a distinction between fact
and truth, and no matter how false the man's
facts may have been, his story, like Bunyan's, was
essentially true. Much of the poverty that upon the
surface seems to be voluntary and undeserving comes
from a growing feeling among those who work hardest
that, as Cowper describes it, they are
"Letting down buckets into empty
wells,
And growing old with drawing nothing up."
At Victoria, B.C., in the spring of
1894, I witnessed a canoe race in which there were two
contestants and but one prize. Long before the winner
had reached the goal his adversary, who found himself
far behind, turned his canoe toward the shore and
dropped out of the race. Was it because he was too lazy
to paddle? Not at all. It was because he realized the
hopelessness of the effort.
37. H. C. Bunner, editor of
Puck.
But it is not alone to objects of charity that the
question of poverty calls our attention. There is a
keener poverty, which pinches and goes hungry, but is
beyond the reach of charity because it never complains.
And back of all and over all is fear of poverty, which
chills the best instincts of men of every social grade,
from recipients of out-door relief who dread the
poorhouse, to millionaires who dread the possibility of
poverty for their children if not for themselves.38
38. A well known millionaire is quoted
as saying: "I would rather leave my children penniless
in a world in which they could at all times obtain
employment for wages equal to the value of their work
as measured by the work of others, than to leave them
millions of dollars in a world like this, where if thy
lose their inheritance, they may have no chance of
earning am decent living."
It is poverty and fear of poverty that prompt men of
honest instincts to steal, to bribe, to take bribes, to
oppress, either under color of law or against law, and
— what is worst than all, because it is not merely
a depraved act, but a course of conduct that implies a
state of depravity — to enlist their talents in
crusades against their convictions. 39 Our civilization
cannot long resist such enemies as poverty and fear of
poverty breed; to intelligent observers it already seems
to yield. 40
39. "From whence springs this lust for
gain, to gratify which men tread everything pure and
noble under their feet; to which they sacrifice all the
higher possibilities of life; which converts civility
into a hollow pretense, patriotism into a sham, and
religion into hypocrisy; which makes so much of
civilized existence an Ishmaelitish warfare, of which
the weapons are cunning and fraud? Does it not spring
from the existence of want? Carlyle somewhere says that
poverty is the hell of which the modern Englishman is
most afraid. And he is right. Poverty is the
openmouthed, relentless hell which yawns beneath
civilized society. And it is hell enough. The Vedas
declare no truer thing than when the wise crow Bushanda
tells the eagle-bearer of Vishnu that the keenest pain
is in poverty. For poverty is not merely deprivation;
it means shame, degradation; the searing of the most
sensitive parts of our moral and mental nature as with
hot irons; the denial of the strongest impulses and the
sweetest affections; the wrenching of the most vital
nerves. You love your wife, you love your children; but
would it not be easier to see them die than to see them
reduced to the pinch of want in which large classes in
every highly civilized community live? ... From this
hell of poverty, it is but natural that men should make
every effort to escape. With the impulse to
self-preservation and self-gratification combine nobler
feelings, and love as well as fear urges in the
struggle. Many a man does a mean thing, a dishonest
thing, a greedy and grasping and unjust thing, in the
effort to place above want, or the fear of want, mother
or wife or children." — Progress and Poverty,
book ix, ch iv.
40. "There is just now a disposition to
scoff at any implication that we are not in all
respects progressing ... Yet it is evident that there
have been times of decline, just as there have been
times of advance; and it is further evident that these
epochs of decline could not at first have been
generally recognized.
"He would have been a rash man who, when
Augustus was changing the Rome of brick to the Rome of
marble, when wealth was augmenting and magnificence
increasing, when victorious legions were extending the
frontier, when manners were becoming more refined,
language more polished, and literature rising to higher
splendors — he would have been a rash man who
then would have said that Rome was entering her
decline. Yet such was the case.
"And whoever will look may see that
though our civilization is apparently advancing with
greater rapidity than ever, the same cause which turned
Roman progress into retrogression is operating now.
"What has destroyed every previous
civilization has been the tendency to the unequal
distribution of wealth and power. This same tendency,
operating with increasing force, is observable in our
civilization today, showing itself in every progressive
community, and with greater intensity the more
progressive the community. ... The conditions of social
progress, as we have traced the law, are association
and equality. The general tendency of modern
development, since the time when we can first discern
the gleams of civilization in the darkness which
followed the fall of the Western Empire, has been
toward political and legal equality ... This tendency
has reached its full expression in the American
Republic, where political and legal rights are
absolutely equal ... it is the prevailing tendency, and
how soon Europe will be completely republican is only a
matter of time, or rather of accident. The United
States are therefore in this respect, the most advanced
of all the great nations, in a direction in which all
are advancing, and in the United States we see just how
much this tendency to personal and political freedom
can of itself accomplish. ... It is now ... evident
that political equality, coexisting with an increasing
tendency to the unequal distribution of wealth, must
ultimately beget either the despotism of organized
tyranny or the worse despotism of anarchy.
"To turn a republican government into a
despotism the basest and most brutal, it is not
necessary formally to change its constitution or
abandon popular elections. It was centuries after
Cæsar before the absolute master of the Roman
world pretended to rule other than by authority of a
Senate that trembled before him.
"But forms are nothing when substance
has gone, and the forms of popular government are those
from which the substance of freedom may most easily go.
Extremes meet, and a government of universal suffrage
and theoretical equality may, under conditions which
impel the change, most readily become a despotism. For
there despotism advances in the name and with the might
of the people. ... And when the disparity of condition
increases, so does universal suffrage make it easy to
seize the source of power, for the greater is the
proportion of power in the hands of those who feel no
direct interest in the conduct of government; who,
tortured by want and embruted by poverty, are ready to
sell their votes to the highest bidder or follow the
lead of the most blatant demagogue; or who, made bitter
by hardships, may even look upon profligate and
tyrannous government with the satisfaction we may
imagine the proletarians and slaves of Rome to have
felt, as they saw a Caligula or Nero raging among the
rich patricians. ... Now this transformation of popular
government into despotism of the vilest and most
degrading kind, which must inevitably result from the
unequal distribution of wealth, is not a thing of the
far future. It has already begun in the United States,
and is rapidly going on under our eyes. ... The type of
modern growth is the great city. Here are to be found
the greatest wealth and the deepest poverty. And it is
here that popular government has most clearly broken
down. ... In theory we are intense democrats. ... But
is there not growing up among us a class who have all
the power without any of the virtues of aristocracy?
... Industry everywhere tends to assume a form in which
one is master and many serve. And when one is master
and the others serve, the one will control the others,
even in such matters as votes. ... There is no
mistaking it — the very foundations of society
are being sapped before our eyes ... It is shown in
greatest force where the inequalities in the
distribution of wealth are greatest, and it shows
itself as they increase. ... Though we may not speak it
openly, the general faith in republican institutions
is, where they have reached their fullest development,
narrowing and weakening. It is no longer that confident
belief in republicanism as the source of national
blessings that it once was. Thoughtful men are
beginning to see its dangers, without seeing how to
escape them; are beginning to accept the view of
Macaulay and distrust that of Jefferson. And the people
at large are becoming used to the growing corruption.
The most ominous political sign in the United States
today is the growth of a sentiment which either doubts
the existence of an honest man in public office or
looks on him as a fool for not seizing his
opportunities. That is to say, the people themselves
are becoming corrupted. Thus in the United States
to-day is republican government running the course it
must inevitably follow under conditions which cause the
unequal distribution of wealth." — Progress
and Poverty, book x, ch. iv.
But how is the development of these social enemies to
be arrested? Only by tracing poverty to its cause, and,
having found the cause, deliberately removing it. Poverty
cannot be traced to its cause, however, without serious
thought; not mere reading and school study and other
tutoring, but thought. 41 To jump at a
conclusion is very likely to jump over the cause, at
which no class is more apt than the tutored class.42 We
must proceed step by step from familiar and indisputable
premises.
41. "The power to reason correctly on
general subjects is not to be learned in schools, nor
does it come with special knowledge. It results from
care in separating, from caution in combining, from the
habit of asking ourselves the meaning of the words we
use, and making sure of one step before building
another upon it — and above all, from loyalty to
truth." — Henry George's Perplexed
Philosopher, p. 9
42. "Harold Frederic, the London
correspondent of the New York Times, reports
Mr. Gladstone as having said, in substance, in one of
his campaign speeches, that the older he grew the more
he began to conclude that the highly educated classes
were in public affairs rather more conspicuously
foolish than anybody else. Mr. Frederic thinks that the
Tories have since done much to 'breed a suspicion that
therein Gladstone touched the outskirts of a great and
solemn truth.' But it needed not the action of the
Tories to breed that suspicion. In this country as well
as in England it is patent to any close observer that
the highly educated classes, or to speak with more
exactness, the highly tutored classes, when
compared with the common people, are in public affairs
but little better than fools. The explanation is
simple. The common people are philosophers unencumbered
with useless knowledge, who look upon public affairs
broadly, and moralists who pry beneath the surface of
custom and precedent into the heart of public
questions. The minds of the tutored classes, on the
contrary, are dwarfed by close attention to particulars
to the exclusion of generals, and distorted by such
false morality as is involved in tutorial notions
regarding vested rights. — The Standard,
July 27, 1892.
The tendency of tutoring to elevate mere
authority above observation and thought is well
illustrated by the story of two classes in a famous
school. The primary class, being asked if fishes have
eyelids, went to the aquarium and observed; the senior
class being asked the same question, went to the
library and consulted authorities.
"One may stand on a box and look over
the heads of his fellows, but he no better sees the
stars. The telescope and the microscope reveal depths
which to the unassisted vision are closed. Yet not
merely do they bring us no nearer to the cause of suns
and animalcula, but in looking through them the
observer must shut his eyes to what lies about him ...
A man of special learning may be a fool as to common
relations." — Perplexed
Philosopher, Introduction.
1. THE SOURCE OF WEALTH
The first demand upon us is to make sure that we know
the source of the things that satisfy want.43 But it is
quite unnecessary to tediously specify these and trace
them to their origin in detail. In searching for the
source of one we shall discover the source of all.
...
71. Farmers, millers, bakers, ranchers,
butchers, fishermen, hunters, makers of food-producing
implements, food merchants, railroad men, sailors,
draymen, coal miners, metal miners, builders, bankers who
by exchanging commercial paper facilitate trade. together
with clerks, bookkeepers, foremen, journeymen, common
laborers, seeking for them instead of their seeking for
work. To specify the labor that would be profitably
affected by this demand would involve the cataloguing of
all workmen, all business men, and all professional men
who either directly or indirectly are connected with food
industries, and the naming of every grade of such labor,
from the newest apprentice to the largest supervising
employer.
Would not this be putting an end to "hard
times"? For what is the most striking manifestation of
"hard times"? Is it not "scarcity of work"? Is it not
that there are more men seeking work than there are jobs
to do? Certainly it is. And to say that, is not to limit
"hard times" to hired men. The real trouble with the
business man when he complains of "hard times" is that
people do not employ him as much as he expects to be
employed. Work is scarce with him, just as with those he
employs, or as he would phrase it, "business is
slack."
Let there be ten men and but nine jobs,
and you have "hard times." The tenth man will be out of
work. He may be a good union man who abhors a "scab" and
will not take work away from his brother workman. So he
hunts for a job which does not exist, until all his
savings are gone. Still he will not be a "scab," and he
suffers deprivation. But after a while hunger gets the
better of him, and he takes one of the nine jobs away
from another man by underbidding. He becomes a "scab."
And who can blame him? any one would rather be a "scab"
than a corpse. Then the man who has lost his place
becomes a "scab" too, and turns out some one else by
underbidding. And so it goes again and again until wages
fall so low that they but just support life. Then the
poorhouse or a charitable institution takes care of the
tenth man, who thereafter serves the purpose of
preventing arise in wages. Meanwhile, diminished
purchasing power, due to low wages, bears down upon
business generally.
But let there be ten jobs and but nine
men. Conditions would instantly reverse, Instead of a man
all the time seeking for a job, a job would be all the
time seeking for a man; and wages would rise until they
equaled the value of the work for which they were paid.
And as wages rose purchasing power would rise, and
business in general would flourish.
If demand freely directed production,
there would always be ten jobs for nine men, and no
longer only nine jobs for ten men. It could not be
otherwise while any wants were unsatisfied.
... read the
book
Henry George:
Progress & Poverty:
The Current Doctrine of Wages — Its
Insufficiency
...
read the entire chapter
H.G. Brown:
Significant Paragraphs from Henry George's
Progress & Poverty: 13 Effect
of Remedy Upon Social Ideals (in the unabridged
P&P:
Part IX: Effects of the Remedy — 4. Of the changes
that would be wrought in social organization and social
life)
From whence springs this lust for gain, to gratify
which men tread everything pure and noble under their
feet; to which they sacrifice all the higher
possibilities of life; which converts civility into a
hollow pretense, patriotism into a sham, and religion
into hypocrisy; which makes so much of civilized
existence an Ishmaelitish warfare, of which the weapons
are cunning and fraud?
Does it not spring from the existence of want? Carlyle
somewhere says that poverty is the hell of which the
modern Englishman is most afraid. And he is right.
Poverty is the openmouthed, relentless hell which yawns
beneath civilized society. And it is hell enough. The
Vedas declare no truer thing than when the wise crow
Bushanda tells the eagle-bearer of Vishnu that the
keenest pain is in poverty. For poverty is not merely
deprivation; it means shame, degradation; the searing of
the most sensitive parts of our moral and mental nature
as with hot irons; the denial of the strongest impulses
and the sweetest affections; the wrenching of the most
vital nerves. You love your wife, you love your children;
but would it not be easier to see them die than to see
them reduced to the pinch of want in which large classes
in every highly civilized community live? The strongest
of animal passions is that with which we cling to life,
but it is an everyday occurrence in civilized societies
for men to put poison to their mouths or pistols to their
heads from fear of poverty, and for one who does this
there are probably a hundred who have the desire, but are
restrained by instinctive shrinking, by religious
considerations, or by family ties.
From this hell of poverty, it is but natural that men
should make every effort to escape. With the impulse to
self-preservation and self-gratification combine nobler
feelings, and love as well as fear urges in the struggle.
Many a man does a mean thing, a dishonest thing, a greedy
and grasping and unjust thing, in the effort to place
above want, or the fear of want, mother or wife or
children.
And out of this condition of things arises a public
opinion which enlists, as an impelling power in the
struggle to grasp and to keep, one of the strongest
perhaps with many men the very strongest springs of human
action. The desire for approbation, the feeling that
urges us to win the respect, admiration, or sympathy of
our fellows, is instinctive and universal. Distorted
sometimes into the most abnormal manifestations, it may
yet be everywhere perceived. It is potent with the
veriest savage, as with the most highly cultivated member
of the most polished society; it shows itself with the
first gleam of intelligence, and persists to the last
breath. It triumphs over the love of ease, over the sense
of pain, over the dread of death. It dictates the most
trivial and the most important actions. ...
read the whole chapter
H.G. Brown:
Significant Paragraphs from Henry George's
Progress & Poverty: 14
Liberty, and Equality of Opportunity (in the unabridged
P&P:
Part X: The Law of Human Progress — Chapter 5: The
Central Truth)
The truth to which we were led in the
politico-economic branch of our inquiry is as clearly
apparent in the rise and fall of nations and the growth
and decay of civilizations, and it accords with those
deep-seated recognitions of relation and sequence that we
denominate moral perceptions. Thus are given to our
conclusions the greatest certitude and highest
sanction.
This truth involves both a menace and a promise.
It shows that the evils arising from the unjust
and unequal distribution of wealth, which are becoming
more and more apparent as modern civilization goes on,
are not incidents of progress, but tendencies which must
bring progress to a halt; that they will not
cure themselves, but, on the contrary, must, unless their
cause is removed, grow greater and greater, until they
sweep us back into barbarism by the road every previous
civilization has trod. But it also shows that
these evils are not imposed by natural laws; that they
spring solely from social maladjustments which ignore
natural laws, and that in removing their cause we shall
be giving an enormous impetus to progress.
The poverty which in the midst of abundance
pinches and embrutes men, and all the manifold evils
which flow from it, spring from a denial of justice. In
permitting the monopolization of the opportunities which
nature freely offers to all, we have ignored the
fundamental law of justice — for, so far
as we can see, when we view things upon a large scale,
justice seems to be the supreme law of the universe. But
by sweeping away this injustice and asserting the rights
of all men to natural opportunities, we shall conform
ourselves to the law —
- we shall remove the great cause of unnatural
inequality in the distribution of wealth and
power;
- we shall abolish poverty;
- tame the ruthless passions of greed;
- dry up the springs of vice and misery;
- light in dark places the lamp of knowledge;
- give new vigor to invention and a fresh impulse to
discovery;
- substitute political strength for political
weakness; and
- make tyranny and anarchy impossible.
The reform I have proposed accords with all that is
politically, socially, or morally desirable. It has the
qualities of a true reform, for it will make all other
reforms easier. What is it but the carrying out in letter
and spirit of the truth enunciated in the Declaration of
Independence — the "self-evident" truth that is the
heart and soul of the Declaration —"That all men
are created equal; that they are endowed by their Creator
with certain inalienable rights; that among these are
life, liberty, and the pursuit of happiness!"
These rights are denied when the equal right
to land — on which and by which men alone can live
— is denied. Equality of political rights will not
compensate for the denial of the equal right to the
bounty of nature. Political liberty, when the equal right
to land is denied, becomes, as population increases and
invention goes on, merely the liberty to compete for
employment at starvation wages. This is the
truth that we have ignored. And so
- there come beggars in our streets and tramps on our
roads; and
- poverty enslaves men who we boast are
political sovereigns; and
- want breeds ignorance that our schools
cannot enlighten; and
- citizens vote as their masters dictate; and
- the demagogue usurps the part of the statesman;
and
- gold weighs in the scales of justice; and
- in high places sit those who do not pay to civic
virtue even the compliment of hypocrisy; and
- the pillars of the republic that we thought so
strong already bend under an increasing strain.
...
We honor Liberty in name and in form. We set up her
statues and sound her praises. But we have not fully
trusted her. And with our growth so grow her demands. She
will have no half service!
Liberty! it is a word to conjure with, not to vex the
ear in empty boastings. For Liberty means Justice, and
Justice is the natural law — the law of health and
symmetry and strength, of fraternity and
co-operation.
They who look upon Liberty as having accomplished her
mission when she has abolished hereditary privileges and
given men the ballot, who think of her as having no
further relations to the everyday affairs of life, have
not seen her real grandeur — to them the poets who
have sung of her must seem rhapsodists, and her martyrs
fools! As the sun is the lord of life, as well as of
light; as his beams not merely pierce the clouds, but
support all growth, supply all motion, and call forth
from what would otherwise be a cold and inert mass all
the infinite diversities of being and beauty, so is
liberty to mankind. It is not for an abstraction that men
have toiled and died; that in every age the witnesses of
Liberty have stood forth, and the martyrs of Liberty have
suffered.
We speak of Liberty as one thing, and of virtue,
wealth, knowledge, invention, national strength, and
national independence as other things. But, of all these,
Liberty is the source, the mother, the necessary
condition. ...
Only in broken gleams and partial light has the sun of
Liberty yet beamed among men, but all progress hath she
called forth. ...
Shall we not trust her?
In our time, as in times before, creep on the
insidious forces that, producing inequality, destroy
Liberty. On the horizon the clouds begin to lower.
Liberty calls to us again. We must follow her further; we
must trust her fully. Either we must wholly accept her or
she will not stay. It is not enough that men
should vote; it is not enough that they should be
theoretically equal before the law. They must have
liberty to avail themselves of the opportunities and
means of life; they must stand on equal terms with
reference to the bounty of nature. Either this, or
Liberty withdraws her light! Either this, or
darkness comes on, and the very forces that progress has
evolved turn to powers that work destruction. This is the
universal law. This is the lesson of the centuries.
Unless its foundations be laid in justice the social
structure cannot stand.
Our primary social adjustment is a denial of
justice. In allowing one man to own the land on which and
from which other men must live, we have made them his
bondsmen in a degree which increases as material progress
goes on. This is the subtile alchemy that in
ways they do not realize is extracting from the masses in
every civilized country the fruits of their weary toil;
that is instituting a harder and more hopeless slavery in
place of that which has been destroyed; that is bringing
political despotism out of political freedom, and must
soon transmute democratic institutions into anarchy.
It is this that turns the blessings of
material progress into a curse. It is this that
crowds human beings into noisome cellars and squalid
tenement houses; that fills prisons and brothels; that
goads men with want and consumes them with greed; that
robs women of the grace and beauty of perfect womanhood;
that takes from little children the joy and innocence of
life's morning.
Civilization so based cannot continue. The
eternal laws of the universe forbid it. Ruins of
dead empires testify, and the witness that is in every
soul answers, that it cannot be. It is something grander
than Benevolence, something more august than Charity
— it is Justice herself that demands of us to right
this wrong. Justice that will not be denied; that cannot
be put off — Justice that with the scales carries
the sword. Shall we ward the stroke with liturgies and
prayers? Shall we avert the decrees of immutable law by
raising churches when hungry infants moan and weary
mothers weep?
Though it may take the language of prayer, it
is blasphemy that attributes to the inscrutable decrees
of Providence the suffering and brutishness that come of
poverty; that turns with folded hands to the All-Father
and lays on Him the responsibility for the want and crime
of our great cities. We degrade the Everlasting.
We slander the Just One. A merciful man would have better
ordered the world; a just man would crush with his foot
such an ulcerous ant-hill! It is not the Almighty, but we
who are responsible for the vice and misery that fester
amid our civilization. The Creator showers upon us his
gifts — more than enough for all. But like swine
scrambling for food, we tread them in the mire —
tread them in the mire, while we tear and rend each
other!
In the very centers of our civilization today
are want and suffering enough to make sick at heart
whoever does not close his eyes and steel his nerves.
Dare we turn to the Creator and ask Him to relieve
it? Supposing the prayer were heard, and at the
behest with which the universe sprang into being there
should glow in the sun a greater power; new virtue fill
the air; fresh vigor the soil; that for every blade of
grass that now grows two should spring up, and the seed
that now increases fiftyfold should increase a
hundredfold! Would poverty be abated or want relieved?
Manifestly no! Whatever benefit would accrue would be but
temporary. The new powers streaming through the material
universe could be utilized only through land.
This is not merely a deduction of political economy;
it is a fact of experience. We know it because we
have seen it. Within our own times, under our
very eyes, that Power which is above all, and in all, and
through all; that Power of which the whole universe is
but the manifestation; that Power which maketh all
things, and without which is not anything made that is
made, has increased the bounty which men may enjoy, as
truly as though the fertility of nature had been
increased.
- Into the mind of one came the thought that
harnessed steam for the service of mankind.
- To the inner ear of another was whispered the
secret that compels the lightning to bear a message
round the globe.
- In every direction have the laws of matter been
revealed;
- in every department of industry have arisen arms of
iron and fingers of steel, whose effect upon the
production of wealth has been precisely the same as an
increase in the fertility of nature.
What has been the result? Simply that
landowners get all the gain.
Can it be that the gifts of the Creator may be
thus misappropriated with impunity? Is it a light thing
that labor should be robbed of its earnings while greed
rolls in wealth — that the many should want while
the few are surfeited? Turn to history, and on
every page may be read the lesson that such wrong never
goes unpunished; that the Nemesis that follows injustice
never falters nor sleeps! Look around today. Can this
state of things continue? May we even say, "After us the
deluge!" Nay; the pillars of the State are trembling even
now, and the very foundations of society begin to quiver
with pent-up forces that glow underneath. The struggle
that must either revivify, or convulse in ruin, is near
at hand, if it be not already begun.
The fiat has gone forth! With steam and electricity,
and the new powers born of progress, forces have entered
the world that will either compel us to a higher plane or
overwhelm us, as nation after nation, as civilization
after civilization, have been overwhelmed before. ...
- We cannot go on permitting men to vote and forcing
them to tramp.
- We cannot go on educating boys and girls in our
public schools and then refusing them the right to earn
an honest living.
- We cannot go on prating of the inalienable rights
of man and then denying the inalienable right to the
bounty of the Creator.
Even now, in old bottles the new wine begins to
ferment, and elemental forces gather for the strife!
But if, while there is yet time, we turn to
Justice and obey her, if we trust Liberty and follow her,
the dangers that now threaten must disappear, the
forces that now menace will turn to agencies of
elevation. Think of the powers now wasted;
of the infinite fields of knowledge yet to be explored;
of the possibilities of which the wondrous inventions of
this century give us but a hint.
- With want destroyed;
- with greed changed to noble passions;
- with the fraternity that is born of equality taking
the place of the jealousy and fear that now array men
against each other;
- with mental power loosed by conditions that give to
the humblest comfort and leisure; and
- who shall measure the heights to which our
civilization may soar?
Words fail the thought! It is the Golden Age
of which poets have sung and high-raised seers have told
in metaphor! It is the glorious vision which has always
haunted man with gleams of fitful splendor. It is what he
saw whose eyes at Patmos were closed in a trance. It is
the culmination of Christianity — the City of God
on earth, with its walls of jasper and its gates of
pearl! It is the reign of the Prince of Peace!
...
read the whole chapter
Winston Churchill: Land Price as a Cause of
Poverty (1909 speech in Parliament)
What is the position disclosed by the argument? On
the one hand, we have one hundred and twenty thousand
persons in Glasgow occupying one-room tenements; on the
other, the land of Scotland. Between the two stands the
market-gardener, and we are solemnly invited, for the
sake of the market-gardener, to keep that great
population congested within limits that are unnatural and
restricted to an annual supply of land which can bear no
relation whatever to their physical, social, and economic
needs -- and all for the sake of the market-gardener, who
can perfectly well move farther out as the city spreads
and who would not really be in the least
injured.... Read the
whole piece
Henry George:
Progress & Poverty:
Introductory: The Problem
The present century has been marked by a prodigious
increase in wealth-producing power. The utilization of
steam and electricity, the introduction of improved
processes and labor-saving machinery, the greater
subdivision and grander scale of production, the
wonderful facilitation of exchanges, have multiplied
enormously the effectiveness of labor.
At the beginning of this marvelous era it was natural
to expect, and it was expected, that labor-saving
inventions would lighten the toil and improve the
condition of the laborer; that the enormous increase in
the power of producing wealth would make real poverty a
thing of the past.
- Could a man of the last century--a Franklin or a
Priestley--have seen, in a vision of the future, the
steamship taking the place of the sailing vessel, the
railroad train of the wagon, the reaping machine of the
scythe, the threshing machine of the flail;
- could he have heard the throb of the engines that
in obedience to human will, and for the satisfaction of
human desire, exert a power greater than that of all
the men and all the beasts of burden of the earth
combined;
- could he have seen the forest tree transformed into
finished lumber--into doors, sashes, blinds, boxes or
barrels, with hardly the touch of a human hand; the
great workshops where boots and shoes are turned out by
the case with less labor than the old-fashioned cobbler
could have put on a sole; the factories where, under
the eye of a girl, cotton becomes cloth faster than
hundreds of stalwart weavers could have turned it out
with their hand-looms;
- could he have seen steam hammers shaping mammoth
shafts and mighty anchors, and delicate machinery
making tiny watches; the diamond drill cutting through
the heart of the rocks, and coal oil sparing the
whale;
- could he have realized the enormous saving of labor
resulting from improved facilities of exchange and
communication--sheep killed in Australia eaten fresh in
England and the order given by the London banker in the
afternoon executed in San Francisco in the morning of
the same day;
- could he have conceived of the
hundred thousand improvements which these only suggest,
what would he have inferred as to the social condition
of mankind?
It would not have seemed like an inference; further
than the vision went, it would have seemed as though he
saw; and his heart would have leaped and his nerves would
have thrilled, as one who from a height beholds just
ahead of the thirst-stricken caravan the living gleam of
rustling woods and the glint of laughing waters. Plainly,
in the sight of the imagination, he would have beheld
these new forces elevating society from its very
foundations, lifting the very poorest above the
possibility of want, exempting the very lowest from
anxiety for the material needs of life; he would have
seen these slaves of the lamp of knowledge taking on
themselves the traditional curse, these muscles of iron
and sinews of steel making the poorest laborer's life a
holiday, in which every high quality and noble impulse
could have scope to grow.
And out of these bounteous material conditions he
would have seen arising, as necessary sequences, moral
conditions realizing the golden age of which mankind have
always dreamed.
- Youth no longer stunted and starved;
- age no longer harried by avarice;
- the child at play with the tiger;
- the man with the muck-rake drinking in the glory of
the stars!
- Foul things fled, fierce things tame;
- discord turned to harmony!
For how could there be greed where all had enough? How
could the vice, the crime, the ignorance, the brutality,
that spring from poverty and the fear of poverty, exist
where poverty had vanished? Who should crouch where all
were freemen; who oppress where all were peers?
More or less vague or clear, these have been the
hopes, these the dreams born of the improvements which
give this wonderful century its preeminence. They have
sunk so deeply into the popular mind as to radically
change the currents of thought, to recast creeds and
displace the most fundamental conceptions. The haunting
visions of higher possibilities have not merely gathered
splendor and vividness, but their direction has
changed--instead of seeing behind the faint tinges of an
expiring sunset, all the glory of the daybreak has decked
the skies before.
It is true that disappointment has followed
disappointment, and that discovery upon discovery, and
invention after invention, have neither lessened the toil
of those who most need respite, nor brought plenty to the
poor. But there have been so many things to which it
seemed this failure could be laid, that up to our time
the new faith has hardly weakened. We have better
appreciated the difficulties to be overcome; but not the
less trusted that the tendency of the times was to
overcome them.
Now, however, we are coming into collision with facts
which there can be no mistaking. From all parts of the
civilized world come complaints;
- of industrial depression;
- of labor condemned to involuntary idleness;
- of capital massed and wasting;
- of pecuniary distress among business men;
- of want and suffering and anxiety among the working
classes.
All the dull, deadening pain, all the keen, maddening
anguish, that to great masses of men are involved in the
words "hard times," afflict the world today. This
state of things, common to communities differing so
widely in situation, in political institutions, in fiscal
and financial systems, in density of population and in
social organization can hardly be accounted for by local
causes.
- There is distress where large standing armies are
maintained, but there is also distress where the
standing armies are nominal;
- there is distress where protective tariffs stupidly
and wastefully hamper trade, but there is also distress
where trade is nearly free;
- there is distress where autocratic government yet
prevails, but there is also distress where political
power is wholly in the hands of the people;
- in countries where paper is money, and
- in countries where gold and silver are the only
currency.
Evidently, beneath all such things as these, we must
infer a common cause.
That there is a common cause, and that it is either
what we call material progress or something closely
connected with material progress, becomes more than an
inference when it is noted that the phenomena we class
together and speak of as industrial depression, are but
intensifications of phenomena which always accompany
material progress, and which show themselves more clearly
and strongly as material progress goes on. Where
the conditions to which material progress everywhere
tends are most fully realized--that is to say, where
population is densest, wealth greatest, and the machinery
of production and exchange most highly developed--we find
the deepest poverty, the sharpest struggle for existence,
and the most enforced idleness.
It is to the newer countries--that is, to the
countries where material progress is yet in its earlier
stages--that laborers emigrate in search of higher wages,
and capital flows in search of higher interest. It is in
the older countries--that is to say, the countries where
material progress has reached later stages--that
widespread destitution is found in the midst of the
greatest abundance. Go into one of the new communities
where Anglo-Saxon vigor is just beginning the race of
progress;
- where the machinery of production and exchange is
yet rude and inefficient;
- where the increment of wealth is not yet great
enough to enable any class to live in ease and
luxury;
- where the best house is but a cabin of logs or a
cloth and paper shanty, and the richest man is forced
to daily work
and though you will find an absence of wealth and all
its concomitants, you will find no beggars. There is no
luxury, but there is no destitution. No one makes an easy
living, nor a very good living; but every one can make a
living, and no one able and willing to work is oppressed
by the fear of want.
But just as such a community realizes the
conditions which all civilized communities are striving
for, and advances in the scale of material progress--just
as closer settlement and a more intimate connection with
the rest of the world, and greater utilization of
labor-saving machinery, make possible greater economies
in production and exchange, and wealth in consequence
increases, not merely in the aggregate, but in proportion
to population--so does poverty take a darker
aspect. Some get an infinitely better and easier
living, but others find it hard to get a living at.
The "tramp"
comes with the locomotive, and alms houses and prisons
areas surely the marks of "material progress" as are
costly dwellings, rich warehouses, and magnificent
churches. Upon streets lighted with gas and controlled by
uniformed policemen, beggars wait for the passer-by, and
in the shadow of college, and library, and museum, are
gathering the more hideous Huns and fiercer Vandals of
whom Macaulay prophesied.
This fact--the great fact that poverty and
all its concomitants show themselves in communities just
as they develop into the conditions towards which
material progress tends--proves that the social
difficulties existing wherever a certain stage of
progress has been reached, do not arise from local
circumstances, but are, in some way or another,
engendered by progress itself.
And, unpleasant as it may be to admit it, it is at
last becoming evident that the enormous increase in
productive power which has marked the present century and
is still going on with accelerating ratio, has no
tendency to extirpate poverty or to lighten the burdens
of those compelled to toil. It simply widens the gulf
between Dives
and Lazarus, and makes the struggle for existence
more intense. The march of invention has clothed mankind
with powers of which a century ago the boldest
imagination could not have dreamed. But
- in factories where labor-saving machinery has
reached its most wonderful development, little children
are at work;
- wherever the new forces are anything like fully
utilized, large classes are maintained by charity or
live on the verge of recourse to it;
- amid the greatest accumulations of wealth, men die
of starvation, and puny infant suckle dry breasts;
- while everywhere the greed of gain, the worship of
wealth, shows the force of the fear of want.
The promised land flies before us like the mirage. The
fruit of the tree of knowledge turn as we grasp them to
apples of Sodom that crumble at the touch.
It is true that wealth has been greatly increased, and
that the average of comfort, leisure, and refinement has
been raised; but these gains are not general. In them the lowest
class do not share.* I do not mean that the condition of
the lowest class has nowhere nor in anything been
improved; but that there is nowhere any improvement which
can be credited to increased productive power. I mean
that the tendency of what we call material progress is in
no wise to improve the condition of the lowest class in
the essentials of healthy, happy human life. Nay,
more, that it is to still further depress the condition
of the lowest class. The new forces, elevating in
their nature though they be, do not act upon the social
fabric from underneath, as was for a long time hoped and
believed, but strike it at a point intermediate between
top and bottom. It is as though an immense wedge were
being forced, not underneath society, but through
society. Those who are above the point of separation are
elevated, but those who are below are crushed down.
[* It is true that the poorest may now
in certain ways enjoy what the richest a century ago
could not have commanded, but this does not show
improvement of condition so long as the ability to
obtain the necessaries of life is not increased. The
beggar in a great city may enjoy many things from
which the backwoods farmer is debarred, but that does
not prove the condition of the city beggar better
than that of the independent farmer.]
This depressing effect is not generally realized, for
it is not apparent where there has long existed a class
just able to live. Where the lowest class barely lives,
as has been the case for a long time in many parts of
Europe, it is impossible for it to get any lower, for the
next lowest step is out of existence, and no tendency to
further depression can readily show itself. But in the
progress of new settlements to the conditions of older
communities it may clearly be seen that material progress
does not merely fail to relieve poverty--it actually
produces it. In the United States it is clear that
squalor and misery, and the vices and crimes that spring
from them, everywhere increase as the village grows to
the city, and the march of development brings the
advantages of the improved methods of production and
exchange. It is in the older and richer sections of
the Union that pauperism and distress among the working
classes are becoming most painfully apparent. If there
is less deep poverty in San Francisco than in New York,
is it not because San Francisco is yet behind New York in
all that both cities are striving for? When San Francisco
reaches the point where New York now is, who can doubt
that there will also be ragged and barefooted children on
her streets?
This association of poverty with progress is the
great enigma of our times.
- It is the central fact from which spring
industrial, social, and political difficulties that
perplex the world, and with which statesmanship and
philanthropy and education grapple in vain.
- From it come the clouds that overhang the future of
the most progressive and self-reliant nations.
- It is the riddle which the Sphinx of Fate puts to
our civilization, and which not to answer is to be
destroyed.
So long as all the increased wealth which modern
progress brings goes but to build up great fortunes, to
increase luxury and make sharper the contrast between the
House of Have and the House of Want, progress is not real
and cannot be permanent. The reaction must come. The
tower leans from its foundations, and every new story but
hastens the final catastrophe. To educate men who must be
condemned to poverty, is but to make them restive; to
base on a state of most glaring social inequality
political institutions under which men are not fully
equal, is to stand a pyramid on its apex.
All-important as this question is, pressing itself
from every quarter painfully upon attention, it has not
yet received a solution which accounts for all the facts
and points to any clear and simple remedy. This is shown
by the widely varying attempts to account for the
prevailing depression. They exhibit not merely a
divergence between vulgar notions and scientific
theories, but also show that the concurrence which should
exist between those who avow the same general theories
breaks up upon practical questions into an anarchy of
opinion.
- Upon high economic authority we have been told that
the prevailing depression is due to
over-consumption;
- upon equally high authority, that it is due to
over-production; while
- the wastes of war,
- the extension of railroads,
- the attempts of workmen to keep up wages,
- the demonetization of silver,
- the issues of paper money,
- the increase of labor-saving machinery,
- the opening of shorter avenues to trade, etc.,
etc.,
are separately pointed out as the cause, by writers of
reputation.
And while professors thus disagree, the ideas
- that there is a necessary conflict between capital
and labor,
- that machinery is an evil,
- that competition must be restrained and interest
abolished,
- that wealth may be created by the issue of
money,
- that it is the duty of government to furnish
capital or to furnish work,
are rapidly making way among the great body of the
people, who keenly feel a hurt and are sharply conscious
of a wrong. Such ideas, which bring great masses of men,
the repositories of ultimate political power, under the
leadership of charlatans and demagogues, are fraught with
danger; but they cannot be successfully combated until
political economy shall give some answer to the great
question which shall be consistent with all her
teachings, and which shall commend itself to the
perceptions of the great masses of men.
It must be within the province of political economy
to give such an answer. For political economy is not
a set of dogmas. It is the explanation of a certain set
of facts. It is the science which, in the sequence of
certain phenomena, seeks to trace mutual relations and to
identify cause and effect, just as the physical sciences
seek to do in other sets of phenomena. It lays its
foundations upon firm ground. The premises from which
it makes its deductions are truths which have the highest
sanction; axioms which we all recognize; upon which we
safely base the reasoning and actions of every-day life,
and which may be reduced to the metaphysical expression
of the physical law that motion seeks the line of least
resistance--viz., that men
seek to gratify their desires with the least
exertion. Proceeding from a basis thus
assured, its processes, which consist simply in
identification and separation, have the same certainty.
In this sense it is as exact a science as geometry,
which, from similar truths relative to space, obtains its
conclusions by similar means, and its conclusions when
valid should be as self-apparent. And although in the
domain of political economy we cannot test our theories
by artificially produced combinations or conditions, as
may be done in some of the other sciences, yet we can
apply tests no less conclusive, by comparing societies in
which different conditions exist, or by, in imagination,
separating, combining, adding or eliminating forces or
factors of known direction.
I propose in the following pages to attempt to solve
by the methods of political economy the great problem I
have outlined. I propose to seek the law which
associates poverty with progress, and increases want with
advancing wealth; and I believe that in the explanation
of this paradox we shall find the explanation of those
recurring seasons of industrial and commercial paralysis
which, viewed independent of their relations to more
general phenomena, seem so inexplicable. Properly
commenced and carefully pursued, such an investigation
must yield a conclusion that will stand every test, and
as truth will correlate with all other truth. For in the
sequence of phenomena there is no accident. Every effect
has a cause, and every fact implies a preceding fact.
That political economy, as at present taught, does not
explain the persistence of poverty amid advancing wealth
in a manner which accords with the deep-seated
perceptions of men;
- that the unquestionable truths which it does teach
are unrelated and disjointed;
- that it has failed to make the progress in popular
thought that truth, even when unpleasant, must
make;
- that, on the contrary, after a century of
cultivation, during which it has engrossed the
attention some of the most subtle and powerful
intellects, it should be spurned by the statesman,
scouted by the masses, relegated in the opinion of many
educated and thinking men to the rank of a
pseudo-science in which nothing fixed or can be
fixed--must, it seems to me, be due not to any
inability of the science when properly pursued, but
some false step in its premises, or overlooked factor
in its estimates. And as such mistakes are generally
concealed the respect paid to authority, I propose in
this inquiry take nothing for granted, but to bring
even accepted theories to the test of first principles,
and should they not stand the test, to freshly
interrogate facts in the endeavor to discover their
law.
I propose to beg no question, to shrink from no
conclusion, but to follow truth wherever it may lead.
Upon us the responsibility of seeking the law, for in the
very heart of our civilization to-day women faint and
little children moan. But what that law may prove to be
is not our affair. If the conclusions that we reach
run counter to our prejudices, let us not flinch; if they
challenge institutions that have long been deemed wise
and natural, let us not turn back. ...
read the entire chapter
Henry George:
Progress & Poverty:
The Current Doctrine of Wages — Its
Insufficiency
Reducing to its most compact form the problem we have
set out to investigate, let us examine, step by step, the
explanation which political economy, as now accepted by
the best authority, gives of it.
The cause which produces poverty in the midst of
advancing wealth is evidently the cause which exhibits
itself in the tendency, everywhere recognized, of wages
to a minimum. Let us, therefore, put our inquiry into
this compact form:
Why, in spite of increase in productive power,
do wages tend to a minimum which will give but a bare
living? ...
read the entire chapter
Upton Sinclair: The
Consequences of Land Speculation are Tenantry and Debt on
the Farms, and Slums and Luxury in the Cities
I know of a woman — I have never had the
pleasure of making her acquaintance, because she lives in
a lunatic asylum, which does not happen to be on my
visiting list. This woman has been mentally incompetent
from birth. She is well taken care of, because her father
left her when he died the income of a large farm on the
outskirts of a city. The city has since grown and the
land is now worth, at conservative estimate, about twenty
million dollars. It is covered with office buildings, and
the greater part of the income, which cannot be spent by
the woman, is piling up at compound interest. The woman
enjoys good health, so she may be worth a hundred million
dollars before she dies.
I choose this case because it is one about which there
can be no disputing; this woman has never been able to do
anything to earn that twenty million dollars. And if a
visitor from Mars should come down to study the
situation, which would he think was most insane, the
unfortunate woman, or the society which compels thousands
of people to wear themselves to death in order to pay her
the income of twenty million dollars?
The fact that this woman is insane makes it easy to
see that she is not entitled to the "unearned increment"
of the land she owns. But how about all the other people
who have bought up and are holding for speculation the
most desirable land? The value of this land increases,
not because of anything these owners do — not
because of any useful service they render to the
community — but purely because the community as a
whole is crowding into that neighborhood and must have
use of the land.
The speculator who bought this land thinks that he
deserves the increase, because he guessed the fact that
the city was going to grow that way. But it seems clear
enough that his skill in guessing which way the community
was going to grow, however useful that skill may be to
himself, is not in any way useful to the community. The
man may have planted trees, or built roads, and put in
sidewalks and sewers; all that is useful work, and for
that he should be paid. But should he be paid for
guessing what the rest of us were going to need?
Before you answer, consider the consequences of this
guessing game. The consequences of land speculation are
tenantry and debt on the farms, and slums and luxury in
the cities. A great part of the necessary land is held
out of use, and so the value of all land continually
increases, until the poor man can no longer own a home.
The value of farm land also increases; so year by year
more independent farmers are dispossessed, because they
cannot pay interest on their mortgages. So the land
becomes a place of serfdom, that land described by the
poet, "where wealth accumulates and men decay." The great
cities fill up with festering slums, and a small class of
idle parasites are provided with enormous fortunes, which
they do not have to earn, and which they cannot
intelligently spend.
This condition wrecked every empire in the history of
mankind, and it is wrecking modern civilization. One of
the first to perceive this was Henry George, and he
worked out the program known as the Single Tax. Let
society as a whole take the full rental value of land, so
that no one would any longer be able to hold land out of
use. So the value of land would decrease, and everyone
could have land, and the community would have a great
income to be spent for social ends. ...
In Philadelphia, as in all our great cities, are
enormously wealthy families, living on hereditary incomes
derived from crowded slums. Here and there among these
rich men is one who realizes that he has not earned what
he is consuming, and that it has not brought him
happiness, and is bringing still less to his children.
Such men are casting about for ways to invest their money
without breeding idleness and parasitism. Some of them
might be grateful to learn about this enclave plan, and
to visit the lovely village of Arden, and see what its
people are doing to make possible a peaceful and joyous
life, even in this land of bootleggers and jazz
orchestras. ... read
the whole article
Martin Luther King, Jr: Where Do We
Go From Here? (1967)
[book excerpt]: Up to recently we have proceeded from
a premise that poverty is a consequence of multiple
evils:
- lack of education restricting job
opportunities;
- poor housing which stultified home life and
suppressed initiative;
- fragile family relationships which distorted
personality development.
The logic of this approach suggested that each of
these causes be attacked one by one. ...
In addition to the absence of coordination and
sufficiency, the programs of the past all have another
common failing -- they are indirect. Each seeks to solve
poverty by first solving something else. ...
The problem indicates that our emphasis must be
two-fold. We must create full employment or we must
create incomes. ...
We are likely to find that the problems of housing and
education, instead of preceding the elimination of
poverty, will themselves be affected if poverty is first
abolished. The poor transformed into purchasers will do a
great deal on their own to alter housing decay. Negroes,
who have a double disability, will have a greater effect
on discrimination when they have the additional weapon of
cash to use in their struggle. ...
Two conditions are indispensable if we are to ensure
that the guaranteed income operates as a consistently
progressive measure.
- First, it must be pegged to the median income of
society, not the lowest levels of income. To guarantee
an income at the floor would simply perpetuate welfare
standards and freeze into the society poverty
conditions.
- Second, the guaranteed income must be dynamic; it
must automatically increase as the total social income
grows. Were it permitted to remain static under growth
conditions, the recipients would suffer a relative
decline. If periodic reviews disclose that the whole
national income has risen, then the guaranteed income
would have to be adjusted upward by the same
percentage. Without these safeguards a creeping
retrogression would occur, nullifying the gains of
security and stability.
This proposal is not a "civil rights" program, in the
sense that that term is currently used. The program would
benefit all the poor, including the two-thirds of them
who are white. I hope that both Negro and white will act
in coalition to effect this change, because their
combined strength will be necessary to overcome the
fierce opposition we must realistically anticipate.
Our nation's adjustment to a new mode of thinking will
be facilitated if we realize that for nearly forty years
two groups in our society have already been enjoying a
guaranteed income. Indeed, it is a symptom of our
confused social values that these two groups turn out to
be the richest and the poorest. The wealthy who own
securities have always had an assured income; and their
polar opposite, the relief client, has been guaranteed an
income, however miniscule, through welfare benefits.
John Kenneth Galbraith has estimated that $20 billion
a year would effect a guaranteed income, which he
describes as "not much more than we will spend the next
fiscal year to rescue freedom and democracy and religious
liberty as these are defined by 'experts' in Vietnam."
...
The curse of poverty has no justification in our age.
It is socially as cruel and blind as the practice of
cannibalism at the dawn of civilization, when men ate
each other because they had not yet learned to take food
from the soil or to consume the abundant animal life
around them. The time has come for us to civilize
ourselves by the total, direct and immediate abolition of
poverty. ...
[speech excerpt]
Beyond these advantages, a host of positive
psychological changes inevitably will result from
widespread economic security. The dignity of the
individual will flourish when the decisions concerning
his life are in his own hands, when he has the means to
seek self-improvement. Personal conflicts among husbands,
wives and children will diminish when the unjust
measurement of human worth on the scale of dollars is
eliminated .
Now our country can do this. John Kenneth Galbraith
said that a guaranteed annual income could be done for
about twenty billion dollars a year. And I say to you
today, that if our nation can spend thirty-five billion
dollars a year to fight an unjust, evil war in Vietnam,
and twenty billion dollars to put a man on the moon, it
can spend billions of dollars to put God's children on
their own two feet right here on earth. ...
I want to say to you as I move to my conclusion, as we
talk about "Where do we go from here," that we honestly
face the fact that the Movement must address itself to
the question of restructuring the whole of American
society. There are forty million poor people here. And
one day we must ask the question, "Why are there forty
million poor people in America?" And when you begin to
ask that question, you are raising questions about the
economic system, about a broader distribution of wealth.
When you ask that question, you begin to question the
capitalistic economy. And I'm simply saying that more and
more, we've got to begin to ask questions about the whole
society. We are called upon to help the discouraged
beggars in life's market place. But one day we must come
to see that an edifice which produces beggars needs
restructuring. It means that questions must be raised.
You see, my friends, when you deal with this,
- you begin to ask the question, "Who owns the
oil?"
- You begin to ask the question, "Who owns the iron
ore?"
- You begin to ask the question, "Why is it that
people have to pay water bills in a world that is two
thirds water?"
These are questions that must be asked.
Now, don't think that you have me in a "bind" today.
I'm not talking about Communism.
What I'm saying to you this morning is that Communism
forgets that life is individual. Capitalism forgets that
life is social, and the Kingdom of Brotherhood is found
neither in the thesis of Communism nor the antithesis of
capitalism but in a higher synthesis. It is found in a
higher synthesis that combines the truths of both. Now,
when I say question the whole society, it means
ultimately coming to see that the problem of racism, the
problem of economic exploitation, and the problem of war
are all tied together. These are the triple evils that
are interrelated. ... read the
book excerpt and whole speech
winstonchurchill.org:
THE PEOPLE'S RIGHTS: OPPORTUNITY
LOST?
Publisher's pamphlet, circa 1970:
Apart from Free Trade, the great economic and
social issues were taxation and the alleviation of
poverty. The Liberals were concerned to remove the basic
cause of the problem -- not just to mitigate its
undesirable effects.
It was the American economist
Henry
George who, towards the end of the 19th
century, had examined the paradox of the age in his
Progress and Poverty. His principles had
a major impact, first upon the radicals of Scotland and
Ireland, including Campbell Bannerman himself; and later
upon the policy of the Liberal Party.
Henry George
propounded that whilst people have the right to possess
what they produce, or receive in exchange for their work,
there is no such right to private ownership of the
elements upon which all depend -- air, water, sunshine
and land. Indeed, George held the right of access to
these basic elements as strong and equal as the right to
life itself, and that if private ownership of basic
elements is permitted, suppression and exploitation of
one class by another is inevitable. The
consequent injustice must become more acute as the
community develops.
Thus it became a major point of
Liberal policy to shift taxation from production, and to
raise taxation upon the value of land, on the basis that
this value, as witnessed by the
tremendously high prices even then demanded for
commercial land, is created not by any individual but by
the existence and work of the whole community. A
natural source thus arises from which the community may
meet its growing needs without discouraging production or
inhibiting the growth of earnings.
The justice
and practicality of this proposition can rarely if ever
have enjoyed a more brilliant advocate than Winston
Churchill, and today's reader is left to wonder how
different might be the present state of Britain had the
forces of social change pursued these principles to their
enactment. ...
The People's Rights tells a
very different story and comes now not as a document of
historic interest but as a challenge to politicians,
indeed to the entire electorate, to consider again the
causes of poverty and the basic issues of social and
economic justice. Perhaps current disillusionment with
politics springs from a sense that if justice in the
community can only be achieved at the expense of
individual liberty, the price -- especially in terms of
ever-increasing taxation and bureaucracy -- is too high
to pay.
As a proposition that justice
in the community and the freedom of the individual are
complementary and that taxes may be raised without
undermining either, The People's Rights comes as a major
contribution to current political and economic thought.
Indeed it deserves a place in the annals of Man's
struggle for freedom and yearning for a society in which
the genius of every person would be nurtured and the
liberty of every person respected. ...
Read the whole piece
Ted Gwartney: Estimating Land
Values
When considering world-wide economics, most people
think that land rent contributes only a small
insignificant portion of value. But as
societies progress, land has become the predominant force
in determining the progress or poverty of all people
within a community. Land in major or cities is so
costly that people are forced to move further away and
travel great distances in order to get to work and social
attractions. In the more developed countries of the
world, land rent represents more than 40% of gross annual
production. ... Read the whole
article
Robert G.
Ingersoll: A
Lay Sermon (1886)
Recollect what I said in the first place -- that
every man is as he must be. Every crime is a necessary
product. The seeds were all sown, the land thoroughly
plowed, the crop well attended to, and carefully
harvested. Every crime is born of necessity. If you want less crime, you must change the
conditions. Poverty makes crime. Want, rags, crusts,
failure, misfortune -- all these awake the wild beast in
man, and finally he takes, and takes contrary to law, and
becomes a criminal. And what do you do with him?
You punish him. Why not punish a man for having the
consumption? The time will come when you will see that
that is just as logical. What do you do with the
criminal? You send him to the penitentiary. Is he made
better? Worse. The first thing you do is to try to
trample out his manhood, by putting an indignity upon
him. You mark him. You put him in stripes. At night you
put him in darkness. His feeling for revenge grows. you
make a wild beast of him, and he comes out of that place
branded in body and soul, and then you won't let him
reform if he wants to. You put on airs above him, because
he has been in the penitentiary. The next time you look
with scorn upon a convict, let me beg of you to do one
thing. Maybe you are not as bad as I am, but do one
thing. think of all the crimes you have wanted to commit;
think of all the crimes you would have committed if you
had had the opportunity; think of all the temptations to
which you would have yielded had nobody been looking; and
then put your hand on your heart and say whether you can
justly look with contempt even upon a
convict.
None but the noblest should infect punishment,
even on the bassist.
Society has no right to punish any man in revenge
-- no right to punish any man except for two objects --
one, the prevention of crime; the other, the reformation
of the criminal. How can you reform him? Kindness is the
sunshine in which virtue grows. Let it be understood by
these men that there is no revenge; let it be understood,
too, that they can reform. ... And yet we call our
society civilized. There is a mistake. ... read
the whole article
Kris Feder: Progress and Poverty
Today
As this book was written, the Industrial
Revolution was transforming America and Europe at a
breathless pace. In just a century, an economy that
worked on wind, water, and muscular effort had become
supercharged by steam, coal, and electricity. Canals,
railroads, steamships and the telegraph were linking
regional economies into a national and global network of
exchange. The United States had stretched from coast to
coast; the western frontier was evaporating.
American journalist and editor Henry
George marveled at the stunning advance of technology, yet
was alarmed by ominous trends. Why had not
this unprecedented increase in productivity banished want
and starvation from civilized countries, and lifted the
working classes from poverty to prosperity? Instead,
George saw that the division of labor, the widening of
markets, and rapid urbanization had increased the
dependence of the working poor upon forces beyond
their control. The working poor were always, of course, the
most vulnerable in depressions, and last to recover from
them. Unemployment and pauperism had appeared in America,
and indeed, were more prevalent in the developed East than
in the aspiring West. It was "as though a
great wedge were being forced, not underneath society, but
through society. Those who are above the point of
separation are elevated, but those who are below are
crushed down." This, the "great enigma of our times," was
the problem George set out to solve in Progress and
Poverty. ...
In a competitive economy, the
earnings of the factors of production measure their
separate contributions to the value of the product.
Payments for the use of labor are called wages; payments
for land are called rent; the income of capital is
interest. In George's terms, the distress of the working
classes had to do with a persistently low level of real
wages. "Why," he asked, "in spite of
increase in productive power, do wages tend to a minimum
which will give but a bare living?" ...
To George, the Malthusian analysis
was abhorrent: It asserted that no institutional reform
could fundamentally alter the pattern of income
distribution, and that charitable support for the needy
only compounded the problem - by lowering death rates and
raising birth rates. ...
Public debate about economic policy
revolves today, as it always has, around a tension between
two fundamental social goals. Economists and policymakers
lament a perennial "trade-off between efficiency and
equity." ...
Most economists deem it their
business to evaluate the efficiency of policy choices, but,
claiming no special knowledge of ethics, they leave it to
philosophers and the political process to evaluate
questions of justice. Can it be true that society's
arrangements to provide for common needs must always
confront a divisive choice between equity and efficiency -
between what is fair and what is feasible?
Henry George not only denied it; he
asserted the reverse: Full recognition of economic
rights and responsibilities would reveal the goals of
equity and efficiency to be mutually reinforcing. Neither
social justice nor a well-functioning free market system
can long be enjoyed without the other. "The laws of the
universe are harmonious," George proclaimed. His analysis
showed that the root cause of widening inequality lies not
in the laws of nature, but in social maladjustments which
ignore them. Moreover, the breach of justice which
underlies the problem of poverty is not merely incidental
to economic development; it impedes development, leading to
wider and wider inequality.
George emphasized that unequal
distribution is itself wasteful of wealth.
Unemployment and underemployment of
labor mean that energy and intelligence go untapped. For
those who find work, he said, high wages stimulate
creativity, invention, and improvement, while low wages
encourage carelessness. Inadequate education of the poor
multiplies the loss. There are the damages done by
poverty-related vice and crime, and the substantial costs
of protecting society against them. There is the burden
upon the wealthy of providing welfare support for the very
poor - or risking social upheaval if they do not. Moreover,
said George, social institutions by which some prosper at
others' expense cause talent and resources to be diverted
from productive enterprise to unproductive conflict, as
individuals find that competing for political advantage can
be more lucrative than competing for market
success.
In short, an unjust system of
privileges and entitlements tends to cause misallocation of
resources, macroeconomic instability and stagnation,
political corruption, and social conflict that ultimately
may threaten whole civilizations.
George's central contribution was to show that
the distinction between individual property and common
property forms a rational basis for distinguishing the
domain of public activity from that of the
private. ... Read the
whole article
Alanna Hartzok:Ethical Land
Tenure
I want to tell you the story of Charles Avilla. A
while back I came across a book called Ownership, Early Christian Teachings. Avilla
was a divinity student in the Phillipines. One of his
professors had a great concern about poverty conditions
in the Phillipines, and was taking students out to
prisons where the cooks were the land rights
revolutionaries in the Phillipines. Because they kept
pushing for land reform for the people, they had ended up
in jail. So they were political prisoners who were
reading the Bible and were asking the question,
who did God give this earth to? Who does
it belong to? It isn't in the
Bible that so few should have so much and so many have so
little. In the theological world in this upscale
seminary he was trying to put this together about poverty
and what the biblical teachings were. He had a thesis to
write and he was thinking he would do something about
economic justice. One of his professors thought there
would be a wealth of information from the church's early
history, the first 300 years after Jesus. So he actually
went back to read the Latin and Greek about land
ownership and found a wealth of information about the
prophetic railings of the people in that early time on
the rights of the land.
The Talmudic rabinical discussion is of interest
to Georgists because they tried to allocate the land
according to the richness of the soil for agriculture.
For better soil, richer for agriculture, maybe an acre of
that would be allocated. On the poorer soil, these tribes
could get five acres.
The other thing was some lands were closer to the
market. Some land was closer to Jerusalem. That is an
advantage over those who would have to travel a longer
distance to get to the market. How do you have an equal
rights distribution of land allocation with reference to
the market problem? For those more advantageously
situated, the adjustment was to be made by money. Those
holding land nearer the city should pay in to the common
treasury the estimated excess of value attaining to it by
reason of superior situation. While those holding land of
less value by reason of distance from the city would
receive from the treasury a money compensation. On the
more valuable holdings would be imposed a tax or a lease
fee, the measure of which was the excess of their
respective values over a given standard, and the fund
thus created was to be paid out in due proportion to
those whose holdings were in less favorable
locations.
In this, then, we see affirmed the doctrine that
natural advantages are common property and may not be
diverted to private gain. Throughout the ages when wisdom
is applied to land problems, we see this emerge.
...
Read
the whole article
Alanna Hartzok: Earth Rights Democracy:
Public Finance based on Early Christian Teachings
The wealth gap is increasing in
the US. According to the latest Federal Reserve data, the
top 1% of the population has $2 trillion more wealth than
the bottom 90 percent.
Perceptions of the causal factors of these
statistics and the suffering of so many who lack basic
necessities in this wealthy country are most often
simplistic explanations - these people lack money and
they lack money because they lack jobs or their wages are
too low, or housing costs are too high. For those
concerned about the growing wealth gap in America and
worldwide, and the resultant poverty, homelessness,
hunger and food insecurity, the dilemma usually bogs down
into supply or demand side efforts to find solutions.
But the root cause is a deeper
injustice.
The primary cause of the enormous
and growing wealth gap is that the land and natural
resources of the earth are treated as if they are mere
market commodities from which a few are allowed to reap
massive private profits or hold land and resources out of
use in anticipation of future profits. Henry
George, the great 19th century American political
economist and social philosopher, proposed a solution to
a problem that too few understood at the time and too few
understand today. Early Christian teachings drew upon
deep wisdom teachings of the Jubilee justice tradition
when they addressed this problem. The
problem is the Land Problem.
The Land Problem takes two
primary forms: land price escalation and concentrated
land ownership.
- As our system of economic
development proceeds, land values rise faster than wages
increase, until inevitably the price paid for access to
land consumes increasing amounts of a worker's wages. In
classical economics, this dilemma is called the "law of
rent" and has been mostly ignored by mainstream
economists. The predictability of the "law of rent" -
that land values will continually rise - fuels frenzies
of land speculation and the inevitable bust that follows
the boom. A recent Fortune cover story informs us that there
are big gains and huge risks in housing speculation in
about 30 predominantly coastal markets that encompass 100
million people. Since 2000, home prices in New York,
Washington, and Boston have surged 56% to 61%. Prices
jumped 58% in Miami and Los Angeles and 76% in San Diego
where the median home price county-wide is $582,000. The
gap between home prices and fundamentals like job growth
and incomes is greater than ever.[7]
- The second form of
the Land Problem is the fact that in most countries,
including the United States, a small minority of people
own and control a disproportionately large amount of land
and natural resources. Data suggests that
about 3% of the population owns 95% of the privately held
land in the US. Less than 600 companies control 22% of
our private land, a land mass the size of Spain. Those
same companies land interests worldwide comprise a total
area larger than that of Europe - almost 2 billion
acres.[8]
In order to show that there was NO NEED for land
reform in Central America because our land in the US is
even more concentrated in ownership than Central America,
Senator Jesse Helms read these facts into the
Congressional Record in 1981:
- In Florida, 1% owns 77% of the
land.
- Other states where the top 1% own over
two-thirds of the land are Maine, Arizona, California,
Nevada, New Mexico, and Oregon.
A United Nations study of 83 countries showed that
less than 5% of rural landowners control three-quarters
of the land. Other studies on land ownership report these
facts:
- In Brazil, 2% of
landowners hold 60% of the arable land while close to 70%
of rural households have little or none. Just 342 farm
properties in Brazil cover 183,397 square miles - an area
larger than California.
- In Venezuela, 77% of
the farmland is owned by 3% of the people. In Spain, 70
per cent of the land is owned by 0.2 per cent of the
people.
- In Britain, 69 per
cent of the land is owned by 0.6 per cent of the
population. Just 158,000 families own 41 million acres of
land while 24 million families live on four million
acres.[9]
The basic human need for food and shelter requires
access of labor to land. With access to land people can
produce the basic requirements of life. Access to land
provides an enabling environment for life itself and thus
meets the minimum requirement of love, meaning fairness
in human relations based on the fundamental equal right
to exist. The Land Problem in its two
forms - the inequitable ownership and control of land and
natural resources and the treatment of land as a market
commodity - is the root cause of the great amount of
human deprivation and suffering from lack of the basic
necessities of life. And yet the
human right to the earth is missing from the Bill of
Rights, the Universal Declaration of Human Rights, and
the Covenant on Economic, Social and Cultural Human
Rights.
Democratic governance has not yet concerned itself
with a "first principle" question. This question concerns
property rights in land - property rights in the earth
itself. The question is, "Who Should Own
the Earth?" The question of "Who Should Own the
Earth?" is a fundamental question. In venues when this
question is asked, the answer is always the same.
The answer is, "everyone should own the
earth and on an equal basis as a
birthright."
The right to the earth has yet to be pronounced in
human rights covenants. Democracy is unclear, ethically
weak, and on shaky ground when it comes to the question
of the right to the land and resources of the earth.
Democracy as presently constituted lacks this most
fundamental and basic human right - the equal right to
earth. The right to the earth is the great undiscovered
revolution in both American and global
politics. ... read the whole
article
Mason Gaffney: Full Employment,
Growth And Progress On A Small Planet: Relieving Poverty
While Healing The Earth
1. Adequacy of land base. There is enough
land, if only we use it well. Poverty and unemployment
result from owners’ withholding better lands from
full or any use, creating an artificial and specious
scarcity of land relative to population.
...
George’s core ideas include a
formula for achieving full employment and relieving the
poverty of the landless without any need to extend the
bounds of settlement nearly as far as has already
occurred. It is a matter of substituting labor for land,
in many respects and dimensions, as sketched above. It is
not a matter of going against the market, primarily, for
well-oiled markets contain their own price incentives to
foster approprate technology. It is a matter, rather, of
removing tax biases that presently warp the market the
wrong ways.
There are some crudities, errors
and omissions in George’s writings, but none of
them is central or powerful enough to annul the relevant
core of truth. Read the whole
article
Mason Gaffney: The Taxable Surplus of
Land: Measuring, Guarding and Gathering It
1. Common Property in Land is Compatible with the
Market Economy.
2. The Net Product of Land is the Taxable
Surplus
A. To
socialize the taxable surplus, land rent,
effectively, you must define and identify it carefully,
and structure your taxes to home in on it.
B. Taxable surplus is also what you can tax without
driving land into the wrong use.
C. To tax rent we must be sure there is rent to tax, and
we must adopt public policies to husband and maximize it,
and avoid policies that lower and dissipate it.
i. Avoid "perverse subsidies."
ii. Avoid letting lessees of public land conceal their
revenues.
iii. Avoid letting lessees or taxpayers pad their costs
to understate their net revenues.
iv. Avoid dissipating rent by allowing open access to
resources like fisheries,
v. Avoid trying to distribute rents to consumers by
capping prices below the market.
D. Raising output by removing tax bias
E. Maximizing public revenue.
F. Sustaining the tax base
3. Taxing the Net Product of Land Permits Untaxing
Labor
4. Taxing the Net Product of Land
Permits Untaxing Capital
5. Taxing the Net Product of Land Provides Ample
Public Revenues: a Master Solution to Many
Problems
A. Public revenues will support the ruble.
B. Your public credit will, of course, recover to AAA
rating when lenders see that there is a strong flow of
revenue to pay public debts.
C. Never again need you bend to any "advice" or commands
from alien lenders, nor endure patronizing, humiliating
homilies from alien bankers, nor beg any foreign power
for aid.
D. If you again feel the need (as I hope you will not) to
rebuild your military, you will of course require strong
revenues.
E. Strong national revenues are required to unite Russia,
and keep it one nation.
Summary
Avoid trying to distribute rents to
consumers by capping prices below the market. This,
of course, is the history of energy prices in Russia; it
has also been used, in milder forms, in Canada and the U.S.
What is wrong with it? In a word, it fosters wasteful use,
and aborts a lot of economical production. In addition, it
leaves a lot of rent in private hands, untaxed.
It is easy to understand the dire need for guaranteed fuel
in a northern continental winter climate. You mustn't let
people freeze, and they will bless and support you for
keeping them warm. As society gets better
organized, though, you can gain by guaranteeing the poor a
minimum cash income with which to buy fuel and other needs
at market prices, rather than lavishing them with free fuel
that you might be exporting to meet other urgent needs. You
can provide the cash income from the rents created when
fuel prices rise, and have a lot more to spare from the
resulting net gains, which I next explain.
A key to national unity is the fair treatment of
intergovernmental relations and subventions, as between
rich and poor regions, and cities and subregions within
regions. By "rich" I mean rich not in total, but per
capita. It makes sense to adjust tax rates
so they are higher in the regions with higher resource
values per capita, and then distribute a national dividend
on a simple per capita basis, in the manner that
Alaska has made famous on the state
level. The dividend should be "portable," so it does not
bind the recipient, like a serf, to a particular place, nor
induce people to move to the wrong places.
It is not wise to distribute central revenues to local
units of government as such, for at least two
reasons.
- One is that some local units, in bleak, poor
and remote regions, or mined-out regions, might better be
allowed to expire peacefully as their residents leave
with their portable dividends. Many nations have wasted
great wealth subsidizing people to remain in obsolete
locations and industries that they would better abandon,
both for their own and the nation's welfare.
- The other reason is that some poor regions,
like the American State of New Mexico, or Canada's Prince
Edward Island, are ruled by small oligarchies of wealthy
people who create their own region's poverty by the
extreme inequality of resource ownership. It is folly to "tax poor people in rich regions to
subsidize a few rich people in poor regions," as often
occurs. Read the whole
article
Nic Tideman: The Morality of
Taxation: The Local Case
From a moral perspective, taxation is
dubious or worse. We tell our fellow citizens that if they
do not pay taxes that we say they owe, their property will
be seized or they will be sent to prison. Why do we treat
people this way? Is there a justification?
The dubiousness of taxation increases
when we consider its origins. Government seems to have
originated as roving bandits who learned that total
destruction was less profitable than protecting their
victims from other bandits and allowing them to keep a
fraction of what they produced (Olson, 1993). In time,
scheduled partial plunder evolved into taxation. Over the
centuries, regimes that started as tyrannies evolved into
democracies. The public sector evolved from an apparatus
for implementing the will of despots into a mechanism for
carrying out democratic decisions. But public finance
continues to rely on the power of tax collectors, developed
under early tyrants, to coerce citizen to pay taxes. The
wrath that citizens feel toward tax collectors is probably
the strongest antagonistic feeling that citizens have
toward a governmental institution. Why do we allow
ourselves to do this to one another?
There is a gentler side of taxation
that provides some explanation of our tolerance of this
coercion. Taxation can be the way that people achieve their
common purposes. People may agree to be taxed so that there
will be money to pay for public services that they want.
From this perspective, taxation may be considered no more
than the dues for belonging to a club that provides people
with things that they would rather pay their share of than
do without. However, to make this "voluntary exchange"
theory of taxation relevant, people must be able to choose
freely whether or not to "join the club," to be a citizen
of the taxing jurisdiction. With all land claimed by some
taxing jurisdiction, the choice isn't exactly
free.
The problem of morality in taxation
is the following:
- How do we retain the possibility of people
pooling their contributions to the cost of services that
they agree are worthwhile, while eliminating the
possibility of citizens treating their fellow citizens as
targets of plunder?
- What are the limits of obligations that we can
justly impose on our fellow citizens?
- And how do we set up a structure of government
that will ensure that these limits are observed?
...
we would probably have a much more efficient
public sector if every public expenditure required
two-thirds approval in legislative bodies.
But to make taxation truly voluntary,
the option to leave must be viable. If people could move
costlessly from one jurisdiction to another, taking all of
their belongings with them, then competition among
jurisdictions would tend to eliminate oppressive taxation.
This would leave only the fees that people were prepared to
pay to have public services (Tiebout, 1956).
Of course, moving will always have
some costs, so the ideal will not be attainable. But what
can be imagined is a system in which all taxes were local
taxes. Then people would not have to move nearly as far to
escape from taxes that they regarded as oppressive. Higher
levels of government would not need to disappear; if the
services that they provide are desired, they could be
financed by levies on lower levels of government.
...
...Thus communities would not be able to raise
much revenue from income tax or taxes on capital before
they would drive residents and investment away. It might
seem that there would be no way that localities could
finance themselves.
Such a conclusion would be
unwarranted, because there is a very
significant source of public revenue that can survive when
localities compete for mobile residents. This source is
land. When people are taxed in proportion to the land they
possess, no land moves to another locality where
taxes are lower. Thus two questions arise:
- Would taxes on land be sufficient to finance
the public activities that ought to be undertaken,
and
- would such a system be fair?
...
If people cannot be expected to
pay for educating the children that they ought to be able
to have, doesn't that mean that there is some fundamental
unfairness in the starting conditions? Is it not the
combination of past injustice and current unequal access
to natural opportunities that makes us reluctant to
require people to pay the full costs of having
children? In my conception of justice, we have not
adequately compensated for past injustice until we have
put people in a position where we are content to oblige
them to pay the full costs of their choices. ...
Read the whole article
Nic Tideman: The
Shape of a World Inspired by Henry George
How would the world look if its political
institutions were shaped by the conception of social
justice advanced by Henry George?
Fred Foldvary: Underprivileged or
Rights-Deprived?
Poor folk are often labeled "underprivileged" and
richer folk are called "privileged." For example, there
is a book titled "One Nation,
Underprivileged: Why American Poverty Affects Us
All." But "privileged" and "underprivileged" are
confused and misleading expressions. If you think the
poor are "underprivileged," then you don't really
understand poverty.
What is a "privilege?" The term originally meant
"private law." A privilege is a special advantage or
prerogative or immunity or benefit given only to some
people only because they have power or are favored by
those with power. If everyone is entitled to something,
like freedom of expression, or if everyone may obtain an
item such as a passport with the same rules applying to
all, then it is not a privilege but a
right.
Whether a rich person is "privileged" depends on
how he got the money. ...
So if a person is poor, it is not because he is
lacking in special protections, subsidies, and other
privileges. A person is usually poor because he has been
deprived of the natural right to work. Governments
world-wide impose barriers between labor and productive
resources, keeping some workers deprived of labor and
others who do work deprived of their earnings from
labor.
Taxes on wages create a wedge between the cost of
labor to employers and the take-home pay of the worker.
More costly labor results in less employment. Taxes on
the income from capital goods and on the sale of goods
has the same effect. There are unemployment taxes,
disability taxes, and payroll taxes that increase the tax
wedge. On top of that, there are minimum-wage laws that
prevent the least productive workers from getting hired.
There are permits, zoning, and other rules and costs that
also prevent some workers from becoming
self-employed.
Deprived of the full natural right to peaceful
enterprise and labor, and the natural right to fully keep
one's earnings, the poor have little or no income, and
depend on charity and governmental assistance. To call
them "underprivileged" is a lie. The rights-deprived poor
do not need privileges. They just need government to stop
interfering with their right to work and
save!
There has been confusion about what is a right and
what is a privilege. ...
Real privileges are favors arbitrarily given to
some groups and not others. ...
The really underprivileged folks are all
consumers, taxpayers and those who are restricted from
peaceful and honest practices or have to pay extra to the
government while others are unrestricted and non-taxed.
These people lack privileges which others have.
The proper remedy is not to expand
privileges, but to eliminate all governmental privileges.
That is why libertarians and geoists alike have the
motto: "Equal rights for all; privileges for
none!"
Read the whole
article
Dave Wetzel: Justice
or Injustice: The Locational Benefit Levy
We all have our own personal interpretation of how
“justice” can be achieved.
Often “justice” is interpreted in a
very narrow legal sense and only in reference to the
judicial system, which has been designed to protect the
status quo. ...
Of course, all citizens (and subjects in the UK)
-- need to know exactly what are the legal boundaries
within which society operates.
But, supposing those original rules are unfair and
unjust. Then the legal framework, being used to
perpetuate an injustice -- does not make that injustice
moral and proper even if within the rules of
jurisprudence it is “legal.”
Obvious examples of this dislocation between
immoral laws and natural justice is
- South Africa's former policy of
apartheid;
- the USA's former segregated schools and
buses;
- discrimination based on race, religion,
disability or sex;
- slavery;
- the oppression of women;
- Victorian Britain's use of child labour and
colonialism.
All these policies were
“lawful” according to the legal framework of
their day but that veneer of legality did not make these
policies righteous and just.
Any society built on a basis of injustice will be
burdened down with its own predisposition towards
self-destruction. Even the most suppressed people will
one-day, demand justice, rise up and overthrow their
oppressors.
Human survival demands justice. Wherever slavery
or dictatorship has been installed -- eventually, justice
has triumphed and a more democratic and fairer system has
replaced it. It is safe to predict that wherever slavery
or dictatorship exists today -- it will be superseded by
a fairer and more just system.
Similarly, let's consider our
distribution of natural resources.
By definition, natural resources are not made by
human effort. Our planet offers every inhabitant a bounty
-- an amazing treasure chest of wealth that can supply
our needs for food, shelter and every aspect for our
survival.
Surely, “justice”
demands that this natural wealth should be equally
available to all and that nobody should starve, be
homeless or suffer poverty simply because they are
excluded from tapping in to this enormous wealth that
nature has provided. ...
If our whole economy, with the
private possession of land and other natural resources,
is built upon an injustice -- then can any of us really
be surprised that we continue to live on a planet where
wars predominate, intolerance is common, crime is rife
and where poverty and starvation is the norm for a huge
percentage of earth's population.
Is this inherited system really the best we can
do?
There must be a method for fairly utilising the
earth's natural resources.
Referring to the rebuilding of
Iraq in his recent speech to the American Congress, Tony
Blair stated “We promised Iraq democratic
Government. We will deliver it. We promised them the
chance to use their oil wealth to build prosperity for
all their citizens, not a corrupt elite. We will do
so”.
Thus, Tony Blair recognises the difference between
political justice in the form of a democratic Government
and economic justice in the form of sharing natural
resources.
We have not heard any dissenting voice from this
promise to share Iraq's natural oil wealth for all the
people of Iraq to enjoy the benefits. But if it is so obviously right and proper for the
Iraqi people to share their natural wealth – why is
it not the practice to do the same in all
nations?
No landowner can create land values. If this were
the case, then an entrepreurial landowner in the Scottish
Highlands would be able to create more value than an
indolent landowner in the City of London.
No, land values arise because of natural
advantages (eg fertility for agricultural land or
approximity to ports or harbours for commercial sites) or
because of the efforts of the whole community -- past and
present investment by both the public and private
sectors, and the activities of individuals all give rise
to land values. Why do we not advocate
the sharing of these land values, which are as much a
gift of nature and probably in most western economies are
worth much more than Iraqi oil?
One solution would be to introduce a Location Benefit Levy, where each site is
valued, based on its optimum permitted use and a levy is
applied – a similar method to Britain's commercial
rates on buildings but based soley on the land value and
ignoring the condition of the building.
The outcome of this policy would be to give all
citizens a share in the natural wealth of the nation.
...
It is an injustice that landowners can speculate
on empty sites, denying their use for jobs or
homes.
It is an injustice that a factory owner can sack
all their workers, smash the roof of their building to
let in the rain and be rewarded with elimination of their
rates bill.
It is an injustice that the poorest residents pay
the highest share of their incomes in Council
Tax.
It is an injustice that people are denied their
share of the earth's resources.
The Location Benefit Levy is a simple way to start
addressing the world's last great
injustice. Read the whole
article
a synopsis of Robert V. Andelson and James M. Dawsey:
From Wasteland to
Promised land: Liberation Theology for a Post-Marxist
World
Here is the root cause of poverty. When laborers
are faced with the choice of either bare subsistence
wages or land that can barely maintain life, labor itself
is marginalized and cannot effectively bargain on its own
behalf. Wages, generally, on all land, are driven down
toward the point of bare subsistence. Returns to capital
are also depressed for the same reason, deterring
investment. When this is carried to an extreme -- when
people can no longer afford the goods being produced and
when there is little profit in applying capital -- the
economy collapses. The inflated land market, on which the
speculative frenzy has fed, collapses too. Read
the whole synopsis
"A. J. O." (probably Mark Twain) Slavery
But I gain in other ways besides pecuniary
benefit. I have lost the stigma of being a slave driver,
and have, acquired instead the character of a man of
energy and enterprise, of justice and benevolence. I am a
"large employer of labour," to whom the whole country,
and the labourer especially, is greatly indebted, and
people say, "See the power of capital! These poor
labourers, having no capital, could not use the land if
they had it, so this great and far-seeing man wisely
refuses to let them have it, and keeps it all for
himself, but by providing them with employment his
capital saves them from pauperism, and enables him to
build up the wealth of the country, and his own fortune
together."
Whereas it is not my capital that does any of
these things. It is not my capital but the
labourer’s toil that builds up my fortune and the
wealth of the country. It is not my
employment that keeps him from pauperism, but my monopoly
of the land forcing him into my employment that keeps him
on the brink of it. It is not want of capital that keeps
the labourer from using the land, but my refusing him the
use of the land that prevents him from acquiring
capital. All the capital he wants to begin with is
an axe and a spade, which a week’s earnings would
buy him, and for his maintenance during the first year,
and at any subsequent time, he could work for me or for
others, turnabout, with his work on his own land.
Henceforth with every year his capital would grow of
itself, and his independence with it, and that this is no
fancy sketch, anyone can see for himself by taking a trip
into the country, where he will find well-to-do farmers
who began with nothing but a spade and an axe (so to
speak) and worked their way up in the manner described.
... Read the whole piece
Mason Gaffney: George's Economics of
Abundance: Replacing dismal choices with practical
resolutions and synergies
Summary
Dismal trade-offs, deadlocks, and standoffs are
just mental blocks and smokescreens. Henry George began with a quest for justice in
sharing the rent surplus. He found that justice and
efficiency are not at odds, we can have both. This
trade-off that many economists expound is a stall, a
put-off to enervate and unman us so we won't do anything.
It may ease the conscience to think justice must be
sacrificed for efficiency, and schools starved and
libraries closed to free up incentives, so nothing,
really, can ever be done. We all feel compassion by
nature but, to survive and stay whole in this world of
beggars and bandits, learn to harden our hearts and cork
it in. We learn to screen out evidence of suffering and
injustice, and rationalize what we cannot deny. This
mindset, while understandable, is unaffordable in a
period of dangerous national decline, and growing
division between haves and have-nots.
What we have shown here is not just
that we can have both justice and efficiency, but more, we
cannot have either one without the other. If we don't share
rents efficiently, in the Georgist manner, social and
political pressures will continue to cause inefficient
sharing and eventual dissipation.
Economic discourse is afflicted with
pessimists who firmly cling to mutually inconsistent
positions at the same time, each posing an insoluble
problem. Some, for example, believe the world is racing to
starvation, and favor limiting demand through birth
control, while in another context they deplore
"overproduction," or "underconsumption," and favor choking
off farm production to keep farmers from losing money.
George, of course, would see demand as the answer to
supply, and land as the field on which the twain may meet
and satisfy each other, leveling them upwards.
Again, some favor cheap power and
good roads for rural areas, regardless of cost, and then
favor low-density zoning to keep people out. George, of
course, would favor infilling to make full use of short
interior lines at high capacity, and lower cost per
customer.... read the whole
article Walter Rybeck and
Ronald Pasquariello: Combating Modern-day
Feudalism: Land as God’s
Gift
The ethical foundations of land value taxation.
The biblical Jubilee prescription -- redividing the land
every half century -- may have been feasible for a people
practicing crude agriculture. However, a modern
civilization cannot reshuffle the land without confiscating
unmovable property or discouraging economic progress.
The land value plan suggested here --
increasing land taxes, while decreasing taxes on labor,
production and buildings -- achieves the same Jubilee goal
without negative effects. It lets everyone share the
economic value of the land rather than the land itself,
just as a corporation, instead of carving up physical
portions of itself each year, lets shareholders enjoy
portions of the profit.
The proposed
change in the property tax would enable the community to
recapture community-created land values. Those who hold
land retain undisturbed possession of it so long as they
pay back their fair share of land tax to the community each
year. Those with prized sites pay most; holders of poor
locations pay least.
Society
suffers a loss when speculators hold highly productive
sites out of use. A land value tax usually persuades owners
to use land or to sell it to others who wish to do so. If
not, the higher tax compensates society for the land
privileges it grants. This approach permits the elimination
or major reduction of other taxes that weigh too heavily on
wages, while it contributes to increases in local
productivity.
Seven
Pennsylvania cities have independently increased tax rates
on land while imposing much lower tax rates on buildings.
Scranton, with a population of 87,000, has had a modest
two-rate tax for 70 years. When federal funding was cut in
1980, it raised the tax rate on land to four times that on
buildings. In the next two years, the value of private
construction in Scranton rose 22 per cent. In contrast,
Wilkes-Barre, 18 miles away, kept its old tax system, and
construction dropped 44 per cent during the same
period.
Strapped for
funds in 1974, Harrisburg twice dropped tax rates on
buildings and twice increased rates on land. Almost every
homeowner got a tax break. McKeesport adopted the two-rate
tax in 1980, raising revenues 50 per cent and getting the
town out of debt. More remarkably, building investment rose
36 per cent, while falling 14 per cent in neighboring
Duquesne and more than twice that in nearby Clairton. Since
then, Duquesne, along with New Castle and Washington, has
adopted a two-rate tax.
The largest
American city using the two-rate tax is Pittsburgh. After
the city raised its land-tax rate to four times its
building-tax rate in 1979, new construction rose a healthy
14 per cent. In 1980, the land-tax rate rose to five times
the building rate, and the value of construction shot up
212 per cent. When in 1982 the city widened the gap to six
times the building rate, the value of new building permits
rose 600 per cent.
In all these
cities, despite a national recession and a severe steel
crisis in their region, changes in the property tax
structure produced results that were nothing short of
startling. As detailed in a Fortune article ("Higher
Taxes That Promote Development," August 8, 1983), housing
and downtown buildings increased in numbers and dollar
value. Homeowners enjoyed tax reductions, and housing costs
were kept low. New construction jobs eased losses in the
industrial sector.
Poverty, joblessness and
homelessness have been central concerns of religious
social-action groups. There is a growing awareness that
neither private nor public charity is sufficient in
dealing with these problems. Shifting property taxes
offers an effective way to encourage public policy to be
responsive to blighted cities, farm dislocation,
declining industries, chronic unemployment and growing
poverty. The need to infuse biblical principles into
solutions for these problems seems imperative.
Acknowledgment of this necessity is already evident in
the Catholic bishops’ pastoral letter on the
economy and parallel works by the Presbyterians, United
Methodists and the United Church of Christ. The need to address poverty’s basic causes,
including the unhealthy concentration of America’s
land and resources in the hands of so few owners -- who
have tended to misappropriate land values -- ought to be
high on our religious and public policy
agendas. Read
the whole
article
Walt Rybeck: The
Uncertain Future of the Metropolis
If the institution of private
property has a sound foundation, and I believe it does,
then it rests on the principle that people have a right
to reap what they sow, to retain for themselves what they
themselves produce or earn. Land values, produced by all
of society, and by nature, do not conform to this
prescription.
In the case of Washington, B.C.,
most landowners are petty holders. The biggest
portion of their property value is in their homes or
small shops, only 15 or 20% in land. Only five percent of
the city's properties, land and buildings together, are
valued over $100,000. Because the high peaks of land
values are concentrated mainly in the central business
district, those who walk away with the lion's share of
the community's land values are a mere handful of
owners.
Decade after decade, billions of
dollars in urban land values are being siphoned off by a
narrowing class that has no ethical or economic claim to
them. To be outraged when a few ghetto
dwellers, in an occasional frenzy of despair, engage in
looting on a relatively miniscule scale, but to remain
indifferent to this massive, wholesale looting, is worse
than hypocritical. It is to ignore a catastrophic
social maladjustment, more severe, I believe, than
anything the U.S. has experienced since
slavery.
Henry Reuss, Chairman of the House Committee on
Banking, Finances and Urban Affairs, recently pointed
out, that over the past thirty years, the Consumer Price
Index rose 300%, the price of the average new home went
up 500%, and the price of the land under that average new
house went up 1,275%. "Ways must be
found" he said, "to curb the tendency to invest more and
more in land, a passive activity that adds not a single
acre to the nation's wealth. Instead we must encourage
investments in job-creating plant and
equipment."...
Read
the whole
article
Henry Ford
Talks About War and Your Future - 1942 interview
Peter Barnes:
Capitalism 3.0 — Chapter 6: Trusteeship of Creation
(pages 79-100)
By contrast, if pollution rights are assigned to
trusts representing pollutees and future generations,
and if these trusts then sell these rights to
polluters, the trusts rather than the polluters will
capture the commons rent. If the trusts split this
money between per capita dividends and expenditures on
public goods, everyone benefits.
At this moment, based on pollution rights allocated
so far, polluting corporations are getting most of the
commons rent. But the case for trusts getting the rent
in the future is compelling. If this is done, consumers
will pay commons rent not to corporations or
government, but to themselves as beneficiaries of
commons trusts. Each citizen’s dividend will be
the same, but his payments will depend on his purchases
of pollution-laden products. The more he pollutes, the
more rent he’ll pay. High polluters will get back
less than they put in, while low polluters will get
back more. The microeconomic incentives, in other
words, will be perfect. (See figure 6.1.)
What’s equally significant, though less
obvious, is that the macroeconomic incentives will be
perfect too. That is, it will be in everyone’s
interest to reduce the total level of pollution.
Remember how rent for scarce things works: the lower
the supply, the higher the rent. Now, imagine
you’re a trustee of an ecosystem, and leaving
aside (for the sake of argument) your responsibility to
preserve the asset for future generations, you want to
increase dividends. Do you raise the number of
pollution permits you sell, or lower it? The correct,
if counterintuitive answer is: you lower the number of
permits.
This macroeconomic phenomenon — that less
pollution yields more income for citizens — is
the ultimate knockout punch for commons trusts. It
aligns the interests of future generations with, rather
than against, those of living citizens. By so doing, it
lets us chart a transition to sustainability in which
the political pressure is for faster pollution
reduction rather than slower.
There’s one further argument for recycling
commons rent through trusts. As rent is recycled from
overusers of the commons to underusers, income is
shifted from rich to poor. That’s because rich
households, on average, use the commons more than poor
households. They drive SUVs, fly in jets, and have
large homes to heat and cool — thus they dump
more waste into the biosphere. Studies by Congress and
independent economists have shown that only a rent
recycling system like the one just described can
protect the poor. Absent such a system, the poor will
pay commons rent and get nothing back. In other words,
they’ll get poorer.
As always, there are a few caveats.
- First, to the extent commons rent is used for
public goods rather than per capita dividends, the
income recycling effects are diminished. This is
offset, however, by the fact that public goods
benefit everyone.
- Second, the
less-pollution-equals-more-dividends formula
doesn’t work indefinitely. At some point
after less polluting technologies have been widely
deployed, the demand for pollution absorption will
become elastic. Then, lowering the number of
pollution permits sold will decrease income to
citizens. But that time is far in the future, and
when it comes, the world will be a healthier place.
And even then, trustees won’t be able to
increase the number of pollution permits without
violating their responsibility to future
generations.
The Effect on Poverty
I’m now ready to make a bold assertion:
sharing commons rent through per capita dividends
isn’t just the best way to bring our economy into
harmony with nature, it’s also the best way to
reduce poverty. That’s because there’s no
other pool of money of comparable size to which poor
people have a legitimate claim.
The free market notion that those at the bottom of
the ladder will somehow lift themselves out of poverty,
without any capital or property, just isn’t
credible any longer. Our economic operating system has
long been stacked against the poor, and globalization
hasn’t made it any less so. The prospects for
taxing and spending the poor out of poverty
aren’t much brighter. Arguably, such policies
reached their zenith in the Johnson era of the 1960s,
and didn’t get the job done.
The reason commons rent-sharing can work is that
it’s driven not only — or even primarily
— by compassion for the poor. Rather, it’s
driven primarily by the need to preserve threatened
ecosystems. When this problem is tackled, the question
of who gets commons rent will necessarily arise; we
can’t solve the first problem without addressing
the latter. We’ll then have to decide whether to
take, once again, the commons from the poor, or let
them share in our joint inheritance.
The poor’s claim on commons rent is, of
course, no different from the claim of middle-income
households or the rich: commons rent rightfully belongs
to everyone. But commons rent, if fully paid, would
boost living standards for the poor much more than for
anyone else. And unlike other forms of help for the
poor, commons rent can’t be derided as welfare.
It is, technically, unearned income, but no more so
than dividends received by inheritors of private
wealth. It’s property income, and should be a
universal property right. That, I believe, is a
winnable political strategy, as well as sound economic
policy. ...
read the whole chapter
Weld Carter: A Clarion Call
to Sanity, to Honesty, to Justice
(1982)
Our problem today, as yesterday, and
the days before, back to the earliest recorded times, is
POVERTY. ...
... Let us begin this study of
the likely causes of our troubles by asking two
questions:
- Are we over-populated?
- Are the earth's resources inadequate for this
population?
Our stage, of course, for making this study will
be this world of ours, for it is upon this world that the
drama of human living is played out, with all its joys
and all its sorrows, with all its great achievements and
all its failures, with all its nobilities and all its
wickedness.
Regardless of its size relative to
other planets, with its circumference of about twenty-five
thousand miles, to any mere mortal who must walk to the
station and back each day, it is huge. Roughly ninety-six
million miles separate the sun from the earth on the
latter's eliptical journey around the sun. At this
distance, the earth makes its annual journey in its
elliptical curve and it spins on its own canted axis.
Because of this cant, the sun's rays are distributed far
more evenly, thus minimizing their damage and maximizing
their benefits.
Consider the complementarity of
nature in the case of the two forms of life we call
vegetable and animal, in their respective uses of the two
gases, oxygen and carbon dioxide, the waste product of each
serving as the life-giving force of the other. Any increase
in the one will encourage a like response in the
other.
Marvel at the manner in which nature,
with no help from man or beast, delivers pure water to the
highest lands, increasing it as to their elevation, thus
affording us a free ride downstream and free power as we
desire it. Look with awe at the variety and quantity of
minerals with which this world is blessed, and finally at
the fecundity nature has bestowed so lavishly throughout
both animal and vegetable life: Take note of the number of
corn kernels from a single stalk that can be grown next
year from a single kernel of this year's crop; then think
of the vastly greater yields from a single cherry pit or
the seeds of a single apple, or grape or watermelon; or,
turning to the animal world, consider the hen who averages
almost an egg a day and the spawning fish as examples of
the prolificacy that is evident throughout the whole of the
animal world, including mankind.
If this marvelous earth is as rich in
resources as portrayed in the foregoing paragraph, then the
problem must be one of distribution:
- how is the land distributed among the earth's
inhabitants, and
- how are its products in turn
distributed?
Land is universally treated as either public
property or private property. Wars are fought over land.
Nowhere is it treated as common property.
George has described this world as a
"well-provisioned ship" and when one considers the
increasingly huge daily withdrawals of such provisions as
coal and petroleum as have occurred say over the past one
hundred years, one must but agree with this writer. But
this is only a static view. Consider the suggestion of some
ten years ago that it would require the conversion of less
than 20% the of the current annual growth of wood into
alcohol to fuel all the motors then being fueled by the
then-conventional means. The dynamic picture of the future
is indeed awesome, and there is every indication that that
characteristic has the potential of endless expansion.
So how is it that on so richly endowed a Garden of Eden
as this world of ours we have only been able to make of it
a hell on earth for vast numbers of people?
The answers are simple: we have permitted, nay we
have even more than that, encouraged, the gross
misallocation of resources and a viciously wicked
distribution of wealth, and we choose to be governed by
those whom we, in our ignorance, have elected. ...
read the whole essay
|
To share this page with a friend:
right click, choose "send," and add your
comments.
|
|
Red links have not been
visited; .
Green links are pages you've seen
|
Essential Documents pertinent
to this theme:
|
|