Commuting
Each year, more and more people spend more and more
time in cars and on trains and buses, to get from places
where they can afford a bit of land to live on to jobs in
places that pay wages sufficient to support their
families. Does it have to be this way? Does it have to
get worse year by year? Should we be proud of, or even
satisfied with, a system under which people can't afford
to buy homes in the towns in which they grew up? Who
benefits from this state of affairs, anyway?
Is there a better way? Yup! To understand why and
what, spend some time with the "essential documents
H.G. Brown: Significant Paragraphs
from Henry George's Progress & Poverty, Chapter 4: Land
Speculation Causes Reduced Wages
In communities like the United States, where the user
of land generally prefers, if he can, to own it, and
where there is a great extent of land to overrun, this
cause operated with enormous power.
The immense area over which the population of the
United States is scattered shows this. The man who sets
out from the Eastern Seaboard in search of the margin of
cultivation, where he may obtain land without paying
rent, must, like the man who swam the river to get a
drink, pass for long distances through half-tilled farms,
and traverse vast areas of virgin soil, before he reaches
the point where land can be had free of rent i.e., by
homestead entry or pre-emption. He (and, with him, the
margin of cultivation) is forced so much farther than he
otherwise need have gone, by the speculation which is
holding these unused lands in expectation of increased
value in the future. And when he settles, he will, in his
turn, take up, if he can, more land than he can use, in
the belief that it will soon become valuable; and so
those who follow him are again forced farther on than the
necessities of production require, carrying the margin of
cultivation to still less productive, because still more
remote points. ... read the whole
chapter
Karl Williams: Land Value Taxation: The
Overlooked But Vital Eco-Tax
I. Historical overview
II. The problem of sprawl
III. Affordable and efficient public
transport
IV. Agricultural benefits
V. Financial concerns
VI. Conclusion: A greater
perspective
Appendix: "Natural Capitalism" -- A Case Study in
Blindness to Land Value Taxation
While, at first sight, the
prospect of sprawling cities with lots of open space and
possible greenery might be appealing from an
environmental perspective, a closer examination should
lead to a different conclusion. The inducement to
collect windfall profits (resulting from the failure of
society to apply LVT) encourages some landholders to
withhold vacant land from the market and forces new
development to "leapfrog" this land and move further out.
Hence there is an unnecessary outlay in roads, pipelines,
power supplies and other infrastructure which must
service a greater area. Commuting journeys, similarly,
must now consume greater resources. Financially inducing
land to be put to its optimal use is not "flogging" the
land, but is rather ensuring land is carefully used and
that we only exploit as much as we properly need.
read the
entire article
Bill Batt: Stemming
Sprawl: The Fiscal Approach
We do an awful lot of driving just to do what we need
to do. This is because transportation engineers and land
use planners have confused two fundamental concepts:
access and mobility.
By confusing these two principles, we spend an
inordinate amount of money on transportation services,
most of it on roads and highways. One 1993 study
calculated that the total costs of motor vehicle
transportation to our society equal approximately a
fourth of our gross domestic product (GDP).[3] The study
concluded that "when the full range of costs of
transportation are tallied, passenger ground
transportation costs the American public a total of $1.2
to $1.6 trillion each year. Just the costs of automobile
crashes represents a figure equal to 8 percent of the
American GDP.[4] Japan, by way
of comparison, spends an estimated 10.4 percent to
satisfy all its transportation requirements, although the
figure might be a bit low because not all externalities
are included in the calculation.[5] Road user fees
in 1991 totaled only about $33 billion, whereas the true
costs to society were ten times that;[6] put another
way, drivers pay only 10 percent of the true costs of
their motor vehicle use.[7] The balance is
paid by society, effectively subsidizing highway use by
paying for all but the marginal out-of-pocket operating
costs.
The relationship between transportation costs and land
values can be made even clearer by empirical study of how
land values increase as one moves toward the center of
the city. In an investigation for the Urban Land
Institute, the author concluded that, for Portland,
Oregon, each additional mile [traveled] translated into
slightly more than $5,000 in housing costs; closer-in
locations command a premium, those farther out save
money. A ten-mile difference, all other things being
equal, would amount to about $56,000 in new home
value.
For a household in which one worker drives downtown
(or at least to a more central location) to work, that
ten-mile difference may amount to 4,600 miles annually,
assuming 230 days of commuting and a round-trip of 20
miles each day. Moreover, if non-work trips to the
central area and elsewhere doubled that amount, the
tradeoff would be about 9,000 miles annually, which could
mean a higher/lower driving cost of $3,000 annually, not
counting the time saved/spent.[8] ...
Sooner than Americans are likely to bear the real
burden of global warming's environmental consequences,
they are likely to experience the onset of price rises
for petroleum. Experts are divided, but among those best
insulated from the pressures of bias, there is increasing
consensus that the peak of oil extraction worldwide will
come sometime around 2010 if not sooner.[11] Rising prices
will not induce greater supply; it will not change the
fact that the world will have passed the point of most
easily extracted oil and will enter a long and
increasingly steep period of declining availability. It
is rather a matter of physics: When it costs more in
energy to bring oil from deep in the earth than what can
be extracted, it is not worth the investment. Even the
greater wealth of American society will not insulate it
from world competition over what is a limited and
fungible commodity. How this alters the calculations
Americans make about where to live and work will
increasingly depend on the price they are willing to pay
for transportation service. ...
Stemming Sprawl: Pricing Measures for
Transportation
From the foregoing, it is clear that insofar as the
causes of sprawl development are economic, the solution
needs to be economic as well. The equilibrium of forces
can be restored in two ways:
1) by charging the true marginal costs of motor
vehicle transportation to users and
2) by recovering the economic rent from urban site
owners that is really the socially created value.
It is easy to distinguish five elements of
transportation service cost: capital investment,
maintenance costs, regulation costs, environmental
externalities, and congestion costs. Each of these calls
for a different treatment with respect to revenue design.
Capital costs are best recovered by recapturing the land
rent proximate to the highway corridors. This is socially
created value, which is better used to honor debt service
of infrastructure investment than allowing it to be
retained as windfall gains by titleholders to property
close by. User fees, most aptly linked to the purchase of
motor fuel and tire wear, serve as a proxy for the use of
the roads and can be designed to be commensurate with
use. As the wear and tear of roads as well as police
patrol, snow and ice control, and signaling all involve
operating and maintenance costs, such charges are easily
linked with benefits received. In the future, still more
accurate systems of service charges are likely to appear:
Singapore, Hong Kong, and New Zealand are already reliant
on electronic devices that record road use by time,
place, and vehicle weight.
Ensuring the safety of drivers and vehicles through
licenses, registrations, and inspections is most
appropriately financed by fees commensurate with the
costs of their administration. This way, if a vehicle is
used but seldom, it is charged on the basis of its
identification rather than assuming any projected level
of use. Environmental externalities such as pollution
costs can be linked to the polluting source, such as
diesel fuel and gasoline consumption, to the full extent
necessary to equilibrate air quality and other
environmental ambiences. Congestion costs, the last of
the major components of a pricing design for highway use,
are partially paid for by the time loss of those caught
in traffic. The costs of time lost due to highway
congestion are enormous: In 2000, the average driver
spent 62 hours sitting in traffic at a nationwide cost of
$68 billion in gas and time lost In Los Angeles, the
average driver spent 136 hours stalled in traffic at an
average cost of $2,510.[33] Commuting
times were also 20 percent longer than they were a decade
ago, about 22 minutes one way nationally on average but
as high as 32 minutes on average in New York.[34] But not all
people's time is valued equally, and people themselves
value their time differently at different times, and it
is unfair to require people to impose their congestion on
others. Therefore, congestion pricing, being explored in
several urban regions, provides a rationing of limited
highway space. In a sense, that payment for space usage,
in time or money, is a form of land rent. ... read the whole article
Herbert J. G. Bab: Property Tax -- Cause of
Unemployment (circa 1964)
Property taxes shape the pattern of our
cities.
- If taxes on improvements are low or
non-existing and taxes on land are high, the cities are
bound to grow vertically and at a fast rate.
- If taxes on improvements are high and taxes on
land are low, our cities will spread over larger and
larger areas. They will become metropolitan areas and
they will grow at a much slower rate.
Relatively low taxes on land and high taxes on
improvements will discourage the owners of vacant lots or
underdeveloped land, such as that used for parking lots,
gas stations, hamburger stands, etc., from improving
their land. It will encourage them to keep the land out
of use and to sell later at a profit. This will create an
artificial shortage of land, which in turn will lead to
urban blight and irregular, leapfrog city
growth.
This urban sprawl makes our cities look ugly, but
it has many disadvantages besides:
- It gobbles up a tremendous amount of farm
land;
- the farmers have to give up their land before
it is really needed;
- the building developer has to go far out to
find available land;
- the prospective home-owner has to travel
farther;
- traffic on congested roads will increase
and
- new roads and schools will have to be
built.
It is generally believed that
zoning laws are a very effective tool to control the
growth of our cities. Zoning laws determine the best
possible use of urban land. Yet nobody can be forced to
improve his land and to build unless there is an
incentive. This can be achieved by taxing land at a rate
that will make it unprofitable to hold it without
improving it.
The city planner needs land taxation just as he
needs zoning laws. With both these tools the orderly
growth of our cities will be assured, but -- as
experience has shown -- without land taxation rational
and efficient land usage becomes impossible.
Read the whole
article
|
To share this page with a friend:
right click, choose "send," and add your
comments.
|
|
Red links have not been
visited; .
Green links are pages you've seen
|
Essential Documents pertinent
to this theme:
|
|