Effects of Not Collecting Site
Rent
What happens when we fail to tax that which
should be taxed? And a related question: what
happens when we finally begin to tax that which
should be taxed?
Today, we leave land rent to accumulate in private
pockets and portfolios, and in the hands of
corporations, whose ownership is quite concentrated in
the wealthiest 10% of our society.
Land, particularly urban land, becomes unaffordable
for potential entrepreneurs, preventing the creation of
jobs and creating unsurmountable barriers of entry for
entrepreneurs whose business plans depend on having
affordable access to the choice sites. Existing
businesses tend to have a monopoly, and can maintain
higher prices than would otherwise be the case.
Everyone's cost of living is high, and the rich keep
getting richer. And, as Walt Rybeck puts it, most of us
don't know what's eating us.
Low carrying costs allow speculators to hold choice
land out of use, forcing those who need a place to live
(who doesn't??) to drive further and further from
high-paying work to places they can afford to live. Low
carrying costs all speculators to wait, and wait, for
land to "ripen," while the rest of us pay for the
infrastructure and services that protect and serve that
downtown site, and the neighboring property owners have
less foot traffic than they could have were the land
well developed.
California, post-Proposition 13, can show us, if we
care to look, what happens when carrying costs on
choice properties are low: prices rise, to the point
where 18% of Californians have sufficient income to
support a mortgage on 80% of the median value. (No one
thinks to ask how many of that 18% also have
the money for a 20% down payment on that median
home.)
A lot of our most serious problems will begin to
straighten out when we begin to implement Henry
George's remedy. But, as Clarence Darrow pointed
out,
“The “single tax” is so simple, so
fundamental, and so easy to carry into effect that I
have no doubt that it will be about the last reform
the world will ever get. People in this world are not
often logical.”
Are you willing to be
one who challenges the status quo in this
way?
H.G. Brown: Significant
Paragraphs from Henry George's Progress &
Poverty: 10. Effect of Remedy Upon Wealth
Production (in the unabridged P&P:
Part IX — Effects of the Remedy: Chapter 1 — Of
the effect upon the production of wealth)
And to shift the burden of taxation from production
and exchange to the value or rent of land would not
merely be to give new stimulus to the production of
wealth; it would be to open new opportunities. For under
this system no one would care to hold land unless to use
it, and land now withheld from use would everywhere be
thrown open to improvement.
The selling price of land would fall; land speculation
would receive its death blow; land monopolization would
no longer pay.* Millions and millions of acres from which
settlers are now shut out by high prices would be
abandoned by their present owners or sold to settlers
upon nominal terms. And this not merely on the frontiers,
but within what are now considered well settled
districts.
* The fact that a tax on the rental value
of land cannot be shifted by landowners to tenants,
though recognized by all competent economists, is
sometimes a stumbling block to persons untrained in
economics. The reason such a tax cannot be shifted is
that it cannot limit the supply of land. Landowners are
presumably, before the tax is laid, charging all the
rent they can get. There is nothing in a tax on the
rental value of land to make tenants willing to pay
more or to make land more difficult to hire. On the
contrary, more land will be on the market, because of
such a tax, rather than less, since the tax puts a
heavy penalty on holding land out of use and unimproved
for mere speculation. The competition of former vacant
land speculators to get their land used will make land
cheaper to rent rather than more expensive. And since
only the net rent remaining after the tax is subtracted
is capitalized into salable value, land will be very
much cheaper to buy. H.G.B.
And it must be remembered that this would apply, not
merely to agricultural land, but to all land. Mineral
land would be thrown open to use, just as agricultural
land; and in the heart of a city no one could afford to
keep land from its most profitable use, or on the
outskirts to demand more for it than the use to which it
could at the time be put would warrant. Everywhere that
land had attained a value, taxation, instead of
operating, as now, as a fine upon improvement, would
operate to force improvement. Whoever planted an orchard,
or sowed a field, or built a house, or erected a
manufactory, no matter how costly, would have no more to
pay in taxes than if he kept so much land idle.
- The monopolist of agricultural land would be taxed
as much as though his land were covered with houses and
barns, with crops and with stock.
- The owner of a vacant city lot would have to pay as
much for the privilege of keeping other people off of
it until he wanted to use it, as his neighbor who has a
fine house upon his lot.
- It would cost as much to keep a row of tumble-down
shanties upon valuable land as though it were covered
with a grand hotel or a pile of great warehouses filled
with costly goods.
Thus, the bonus that wherever labor is most productive
must now be paid before labor can be exerted would
disappear.
- The farmer would not have to pay out half his
means, or mortgage his labor for years, in order to
obtain land to cultivate;
- the builder of a city homestead would not have to
lay out as much for a small lot as for the house he
puts upon it*;
- the company that proposed to erect a manufactory
would not have to expend a great part of its capital
for a site.
- And what would be paid from year to year to the
state would be in lieu of all the taxes now levied upon
improvements, machinery, and stock.
*Many persons, and among them
some professional economists, have never succeeded in
getting a thorough comprehension of this point. Thus,
the editor has heard the objection advanced that the
greater cheapness of land is no advantage to the poor
man who is trying to save enough from his earnings to
buy a piece of land; for, it is said, the higher
taxes on the land after it is acquired, offset the
lower purchase price. What such objectors do not see
is that even if the lower price of land does no more
than balance the higher tax on it, (and this
overlooks, for one thing, the discouragement to
speculation in land), the reduction or removal of
other taxes is all clear gain. It is easier to save
in proportion as earnings and commodities are
relieved of taxation. It is easier to buy land,
because its selling price is lower, if the land is
taxed. And although the land, after its purchase,
continues to be taxed, not only can this tax be fully
paid out of the annual interest on the saving in the
purchase price, but also there is to be reckoned the
saving in taxes on buildings and other improvements
and in whatever other taxes are thus rendered
unnecessary. H.G.B. ... read the whole
chapter
Henry George: The Condition of Labor
— An Open Letter to Pope Leo XIII in response to
Rerum Novarum (1891)
That the value attaching to land with social growth is
intended for social needs is shown by the final proof.
God is indeed a jealous God in the sense that nothing but
injury and disaster can attend the effort of men to do
things other than in the way he has intended; in the
sense that where the blessings he proffers to men are
refused or misused they turn to evils that scourge us.
And just as for the mother to withhold the provision that
fills her breast with the birth of the child is to
endanger physical health, so for society to refuse to
take for social uses the provision intended for them is
to breed social disease.
For refusal to take for public purposes the
increasing values that attach to land with social growth
is to necessitate the getting of public revenues by taxes
that lessen production, distort distribution and corrupt
society. It is to leave some to take what justly belongs
to all; it is to forego the only means by which it is
possible in an advanced civilization to combine the
security of possession that is necessary to improvement
with the equality of natural opportunity that is the most
important of all natural rights. It is thus at the basis
of all social life to set up an unjust inequality between
man and man, compelling some to pay others for the
privilege of living, for the chance of working, for the
advantages of civilization, for the gifts of their God.
But it is even more than this. The very robbery
that the masses of men thus suffer gives rise in
advancing communities to a new robbery. For the value
that with the increase of population and social advance
attaches to land being suffered to go to individuals who
have secured ownership of the land, it prompts to a
forestalling of and speculation in land wherever there is
any prospect of advancing population or of coming
improvement, thus producing an artificial scarcity of the
natural elements of life and labor, and a strangulation
of production that shows itself in recurring spasms of
industrial depression as disastrous to the world as
destructive wars. It is this that is driving men from the
old countries to the new countries, only to bring there
the same curses. It is this that causes our material
advance not merely to fail to improve the condition of
the mere worker, but to make the condition of large
classes positively worse. It is this that in our richest
Christian countries is giving us a large population whose
lives are harder, more hopeless, more degraded than those
of the veriest savages. It is this that leads so many men
to think that God is a bungler and is constantly bringing
more people into his world than he has made provision
for; or that there is no God, and that belief in him is a
superstition which the facts of life and the advance of
science are dispelling.
The darkness in light, the weakness in strength, the
poverty amid wealth, the seething discontent foreboding
civil strife, that characterize our civilization of
today, are the natural, the inevitable results of our
rejection of God’s beneficence, of our ignoring of
his intent. Were we on the other hand to follow his
clear, simple rule of right, leaving scrupulously to the
individual all that individual labor produces, and taking
for the community the value that attaches to land by the
growth of the community itself, not merely could evil
modes of raising public revenues be dispensed with, but
all men would be placed on an equal level of opportunity
with regard to the bounty of their Creator, on an equal
level of opportunity to exert their labor and to enjoy
its fruits. And then, without drastic or restrictive
measures the forestalling of land would cease. For then
the possession of land would mean only security for the
permanence of its use, and there would be no object for
any one to get land or to keep land except for use; nor
would his possession of better land than others had
confer any unjust advantage on him, or unjust deprivation
on them, since the equivalent of the advantage would be
taken by the state for the benefit of all.
The Right Reverend Dr. Thomas Nulty, Bishop of Meath,
who sees all this as clearly as we do, in pointing out to
the clergy and laity of his diocese* the design of Divine
Providence that the rent of land should be taken for the
community, says:
I think, therefore, that I may fairly infer, on the
strength of authority as well as of reason, that the
people are and always must be the real owners of the
land of their country. This great social fact appears
to me to be of incalculable importance, and it is
fortunate, indeed, that on the strictest principles of
justice it is not clouded even by a shadow of
uncertainty or doubt. There is, moreover, a charm and a
peculiar beauty in the clearness with which it reveals
the wisdom and the benevolence of the designs of
Providence in the admirable provision he has made for
the wants and the necessities of that state of social
existence of which he is author, and in which the very
instincts of nature tell us we are to spend our lives.
A vast public property, a great national fund, has been
placed under the dominion and at the disposal of the
nation to supply itself abundantly with resources
necessary to liquidate the expenses of its government,
the administration of its laws and the education of its
youth, and to enable it to provide for the suitable
sustentation and support of its criminal and pauper
population. One of the most interesting peculiarities
of this property is that its value is never stationary;
it is constantly progressive and increasing in a direct
ratio to the growth of the population, and the very
causes thatincrease and multiply the demands made on it
increase proportionately its ability to meet
them.
* Letter addressed to the Clergy and Laity of the
Diocese of Meath, Ireland, April 2, 1881.
There is, indeed, as Bishop Nulty says, a peculiar
beauty in the clearness with which the wisdom and
benevolence of Providence are revealed in this great
social fact, the provision made for the common needs of
society in what economists call the law of rent. Of all
the evidence that natural religion gives, it is this that
most clearly shows the existence of a beneficent God, and
most conclusively silences the doubts that in our days
lead so many to materialism.
For in this beautiful provision made by natural law
for the social needs of civilization we see that God has
intended civilization; that all our discoveries and
inventions do not and cannot outrun his forethought, and
that steam, electricity and labor-saving appliances only
make the great moral laws clearer and more important. In
the growth of this great fund, increasing with social
advance — a fund that accrues from the growth of
the community and belongs therefore to the community
— we see not only that there is no need for the
taxes that lessen wealth, that engender corruption, that
promote inequality and teach men to deny the gospel; but
that to take this fund for the purpose for which it was
evidently intended would in the highest civilization
secure to all the equal enjoyment of God’s bounty,
the abundant opportunity to satisfy their wants, and
would provide amply for every legitimate need of the
state. We see that God in his dealings with men has not
been a bungler or a niggard; that he has not brought too
many men into the world; that he has not neglected
abundantly to supply them; that he has not intended that
bitter competition of the masses for a mere animal
existence and that monstrous aggregation of wealth which
characterize our civilization; but that these evils which
lead so many to say there is no God, or yet more
impiously to say that they are of God’s ordering,
are due to our denial of his moral law. We see that the
law of justice, the law of the Golden Rule, is not a mere
counsel of perfection, but indeed the law of social life.
We see that if we were only to observe it there would be
work for all, leisure for all, abundance for all; and
that civilization would tend to give to the poorest not
only necessities, but all comforts and reasonable
luxuries as well. We see that Christ was not a mere
dreamer when he told men that if they would seek the
kingdom of God and its right-doing they might no more
worry about material things than do the lilies of the
field about their raiment; but that he was only declaring
what political economy in the light of modern discovery
shows to be a sober truth.
Your Holiness, even to see this is deep and lasting
joy. For it is to see for one’s self that there is
a God who lives and reigns, and that be is a God of
justice and love — Our Father who art in Heaven. It
is to open a rift of sunlight through the clouds of our
darker questionings, and to make the faith that trusts
where it cannot see a living thing. ... read the whole
letter
Louis Post: Outlines
of Louis F. Post's Lectures, with Illustrative Notes and
Charts (1894)
d. Effect of Confiscating Rent to Private
Use.
By giving Rent to individuals society ignores this
most just law, 99 thereby creating social disorder and
inviting social disease. Upon society alone, therefore,
and not upon divine Providence which has provided
bountifully, nor upon the disinherited poor, rests the
responsibility for poverty and fear of poverty.
99. "Whatever dispute arouses the
passions of men, the conflict is sure to rage, not so
much as to the question 'Is it wise?' as to the
question 'Is it right?'
"This tendency of popular discussions to
take an ethical form has a cause. It springs from a law
of the human mind; it rests upon a vague and
instinctive recognition of what is probably the deepest
truth we can grasp. That alone is wise which is just;
that alone is enduring which is right. In the narrow
scale of individual actions and individual life this
truth may be often obscured, but in the wider field of
national life it everywhere stands out.
"I bow to this arbitrament, and accept
this test." — Progress and Poverty, book vii, ch.
i.
The reader who has been deceived into
believing that Mr. George's proposition is in any
respect unjust, will find profit in a perusal of the
entire chapter from which the foregoing extract is
taken.
Let us try to trace the connection by means of a
chart, beginning with the white spaces on page 68. As
before, the first-comers take possession of the best
land. But instead of leaving for others what they do not
themselves need for use, as in the previous
illustrations, they appropriate the whole space, using
only part, but claiming ownership of the rest. We may
distinguish the used part with red color, and that which
is appropriated without use with blue. Thus: [chart]
But what motive is there for appropriating more of the
space than is used? Simply that the appropriators may
secure the pecuniary benefit of future social growth.
What will enable them to secure that? Our system of
confiscating Rent from the community that earns it, and
giving it to land-owners who, as such, earn
nothing.100
100. It is reported from Iowa that a few
years ago a workman in that State saw a meteorite fall,
and. securing possession of it after much digging, he
was offered $105 by a college for his "find." But the
owner of the land on which the meteorite fell claimed
the money, and the two went to law about it. After an
appeal to the highest court of the State, it was
finally decided that neither by right of discovery, nor
by right of labor, could the workman have the money,
because the title to the meteorite was in the man who
owned the land upon which it fell.
Observe the effect now upon Rent and Wages. When other
men come, instead of finding half of the best land still
common and free, as in the corresponding chart on page
68, they find all of it owned, and are obliged either to
go upon poorer land or to buy or rent from owners of the
best. How much will they pay for the best? Not more than
1, if they want it for use and not to hold for a higher
price in the future, for that represents the full
difference between its productiveness and the
productiveness of the next best. But if the first-comers,
reasoning that the next best land will soon be scarce and
theirs will then rise in value, refuse to sell or to rent
at that valuation, the newcomers must resort to land of
the second grade, though the best be as yet only partly
used. Consequently land of the first grade commands Rent
before it otherwise would.
As the sellers' price, under these circumstances, is
arbitrary it cannot be stated in the chart; but the
buyers' price is limited by the superiority of the best
land over that which can be had for nothing, and the
chart may be made to show it: [chart]
And now, owing to the success of the appropriators of
the best land in securing more than their fellows for the
same expenditure of labor force, a rush is made for
unappropriated land. It is not to use it that it is
wanted, but to enable its appropriators to put Rent into
their own pockets as soon as growing demand for land
makes it valuable.101 We may, for illustration, suppose
that all the remainder of the second space and the whole
of the third are thus appropriated, and note the effect:
[chart]
At this point Rent does not increase nor Wages fall,
because there is no increased demand for land for use.
The holding of inferior land for higher prices, when
demand for use is at a standstill, is like owning lots in
the moon — entertaining, perhaps, but not
profitable. But let more land be needed for use, and
matters promptly assume a different appearance. The new
labor must either go to the space that yields but 1, or
buy or rent from owners of better grades, or hire out.
The effect would be the same in any case. Nobody for the
given expenditure of labor force would get more than 1;
the surplus of products would go to landowners as Rent,
either directly in rent payments, or indirectly through
lower Wages. Thus: [chart]
101. The text speaks of Rent only as a
periodical or continuous payment — what would be
called "ground rent." But actual or potential Rent may
always be, and frequently is, capitalized for the
purpose of selling the right to enjoy it, and it is to
selling value that we usually refer when dealing in
land.
Land which has the power of yielding Rent
to its owner will have a selling value, whether it be
used or not, and whether Rent is actually derived from
it or not. This selling value will be the
capitalization of its present or prospective power of
producing Rent. In fact, much the larger proportion of
laud that has a selling value is wholly or partly
unused, producing no Rent at all, or less than it would
if fully used. This condition is expressed in the chart
by the blue color.
"The capitalized value of land is the
actuarial 'discounted' value of all the net incomes
which it is likely to afford, allowance being made on
the one hand for all incidental expenses, including
those of collecting the rents, and on the other for its
mineral wealth, its capabilities of development for any
kind of business, and its advantages, material, social,
and aesthetic, for the purposes of residence." —
Marshall's Prin., book vi, ch. ix, sec. 9.
"The value of land is commonly expressed
as a certain number of times the current money rental,
or in other words, a certain 'number of years'
purchase' of that rental; and other things being equal,
it will be the higher the more important these direct
gratifications are, as well as the greater the chance
that they and the money income afforded by the land
will rise." — Id., note.
"Value . . . means not utility, not any
quality inhering in the thing itself, but a quality
which gives to the possession of a thing the power of
obtaining other things, in return for it or for its
use. . . Value in this sense — the usual sense
— is purely relative. It exists from and is
measured by the power of obtaining things for things by
exchanging them. . . Utility is necessary to value, for
nothing can be valuable unless it has the quality of
gratifying some physical or mental desire of man,
though it be but a fancy or whim. But utility of itself
does not give value. . . If we ask ourselves the reason
of . . . variations in . . . value . . . we see that
things having some form of utility or desirability, are
valuable or not valuable, as they are hard or easy to
get. And if we ask further, we may see that with most
of the things that have value this difficulty or ease
of getting them, which determines value, depends on the
amount of labor which must be expended in producing
them ; i.e., bringing them into the place, form and
condition in which they are desired. . . Value is
simply an expression of the labor required for the
production of such a thing. But there are some things
as to which this is not so clear. Land is not produced
by labor, yet land, irrespective of any improvements
that labor has made on it, often has value. . . Yet a
little examination will show that such facts are but
exemplifications of the general principle, just as the
rise of a balloon and the fall of a stone both
exemplify the universal law of gravitation. . . The
value of everything produced by labor, from a pound of
chalk or a paper of pins to the elaborate structure and
appurtenances of a first-class ocean steamer, is
resolvable on analysis into an equivalent of the labor
required to produce such a thing in form and place;
while the value of things not produced by labor, but
nevertheless susceptible of ownership, is in the same
way resolvable into an equivalent of the labor which
the ownership of such a thing enables the owner to
obtain or save." —
Perplexed Philosopher, ch. v.
The figure 1 in parenthesis, as an item of Rent,
indicates potential Rent. Labor would give that much for
the privilege of using the space, but the owners hold out
for better terms; therefore neither Rent nor Wages is
actually produced, though but for this both might be.
In this chart, notwithstanding that but little space
is used, indicated with red, Wages are reduced to the
same low point by the mere appropriation of space,
indicated with blue, that they would reach if all the
space above the poorest were fully used. It thereby
appears that under a system which confiscates Rent to
private uses, the demand for land for speculative
purposes becomes so great that Wages fall to a minimum
long before they would if land were appropriated only for
use.
In illustrating the effect of confiscating Rent to
private use we have as yet ignored the element of social
growth. Let us now assume as before (page 73), that
social growth increases the productive power of the given
expenditure of labor force to 100 when applied to the
best land, 50 when applied to the next best, 10 to the
next, 3 to the next, and 1 to the poorest. Labor would
not be benefited now, as it appeared to be when on page
73 we illustrated the appropriation of land for use only,
although much less land is actually used. The prizes
which expectation of future social growth dangles before
men as the rewards of owning land, would raise demand so
as to make it more than ever difficult to get land. All
of the fourth grade would be taken up in expectation of
future demand; and "surplus labor" would be crowded out
to the open space that originally yielded nothing, but
which in consequence of increased labor power now yields
as much as the poorest closed space originally yielded,
namely, 1 to the given expenditure of labor force.102
Wages would then be reduced to the present productiveness
of the open space. Thus: [chart]
102. The paradise to which the youth of
our country have so long been directed in the advice,
"Go West, young man, go West," is truthfully described
in "Progress and Poverty," book iv, ch. iv, as follows
:
"The man who sets out from the eastern
seaboard in search of the margin of cultivation,
where he may obtain land without paying rent, must,
like the man who swam the river to get a drink, pass
for long distances through half-titled farms, and
traverse vast areas of virgin soil, before he reaches
the point where land can be had free of rent —
i.e., by homestead entry or preemption."
If we assume that 1 for the given expenditure of labor
force is the least that labor can take while exerting the
same force, the downward movement of Wages will be here
held in equilibrium. They cannot fall below 1; but
neither can they rise above it, no matter how much
productive power may increase, so long as it pays to hold
land for higher values. Some laborers would continually
be pushed back to land which increased productive power
would have brought up in productiveness from 0 to 1, and
by perpetual competition for work would so regulate the
labor market that the given expenditure of labor force,
however much it produced, could nowhere secure more than
1 in Wages.103 And this tendency would persist until some
labor was forced upon land which, despite increase in
productive power, would not yield the accustomed living
without increase of labor force. Competition for work
would then compel all laborers to increase their
expenditure of labor force, and to do it over and over
again as progress went on and lower and lower grades of
land were monopolized, until human endurance could go no
further.104 Either that, or they would be obliged to
adapt themselves to a lower scale of living.105
103. Henry Fawcett, in his work on
"Political Economy," book ii, ch. iii, observes with
reference to improvements in agricultural implements
which diminish the expense of cultivation, that they do
not increase the profits of the farmer or the wages of
his laborers, but that "the landlord will receive in
addition to the rent already paid to him, all that is
saved in the expense of cultivation." This is true not
alone of improvements in agriculture, but also of
improvements in all other branches of industry.
104. "The cause which limits speculation
in commodities, the tendency of increasing price to
draw forth additional supplies, cannot limit the
speculative advance in land values, as land is a fixed
quantity, which human agency can neither increase nor
diminish; but there is nevertheless a limit to the
price of land, in the minimum required by labor and
capital as the condition of engaging in production. If
it were possible to continuously reduce wages until
zero were reached, it would be possible to continuously
increase rent until it swallowed up the whole produce.
But as wages cannot be permanently reduced below the
point at which laborers will consent to work and
reproduce, nor interest below the point at which
capital will be devoted to production, there is a limit
which restrains the speculative advance of rent. Hence,
speculation cannot have the same scope to advance rent
in countries where wages and interest are already near
the minimum, as in countries where they are
considerably above it. Yet that there is in all
progressive countries a constant tendency in the
speculative advance of rent to overpass the limit where
production would cease, is, I think, shown by recurring
seasons of industrial paralysis." — Progress and
Poverty, book iv, ch. iv.
105. As Puck once put it, "the man who
makes two blades of grass to grow where but one grew
before, must not be surprised when ordered to 'keep off
the grass.' "
They in fact do both, and the incidental disturbances
of general readjustment are what we call "hard times."
106 These culminate in forcing unused land into the
market, thereby reducing Rent and reviving industry. Thus
increase of labor force, a lowering of the scale of
living, and depression of Rent, co-operate to bring on
what we call "good times." But no sooner do "good times"
return than renewed demands for land set in, Rent rises
again, Wages fall again, and "hard times" duly reappear.
The end of every period of "hard times" finds Rent higher
and Wages lower than at the end of the previous
period.107
106. "That a speculative advance in rent
or land values invariably precedes each of these
seasons of industrial depression is everywhere clear.
That they bear to each other the relation of cause and
effect, is obvious to whoever considers the necessary
relation between land and labor." — Progress and
Poverty, book v, ch. i.
107. What are called "good times" reach a
point at which an upward land market sets in. From that
point there is a downward tendency of wages (or a rise
in the cost of living, which is the same thing) in all
departments of labor and with all grades of laborers.
This tendency continues until the fictitious values of
land give way. So long as the tendency is felt only by
that class which is hired for wages, it is poverty
merely; when the same tendency is felt by the class of
labor that is distinguished as "the business interests
of the country," it is "hard times." And "hard times"
are periodical because land values, by falling, allow
"good times" to set it, and by rising with "good times"
bring "hard times" on again. The effect of "hard times"
may be overcome, without much, if any, fall in land
values, by sufficient increase in productive power to
overtake the fictitious value of land.
The dishonest and disorderly system under which
society confiscates Rent from common to individual uses,
produces this result. That maladjustment is the
fundamental cause of poverty. And progress, so long as
the maladjustment continues, instead of tending to remove
poverty as naturally it should, actually generates and
intensifies it. Poverty persists with increase of
productive power because land values, when Rent is
privately appropriated, tend to even greater increase.
There can be but one outcome if this continues: for
individuals suffering and degradation, and for society
destruction. ... read
the book
Charles B. Fillebrown: A Catechism of Natural
Taxation, from Principles of Natural Taxation
(1917)
Q19. Why should buildings and all other
improvements and personal property and capital be exempt
from taxes?
A. Because a tax on them falls upon industry, and so
increases the cost of living, while continuing the
invidious exemption of the present net land value.
... read
the whole article
Bill Batt: Who Says
Cities are Poor? They Just Don't Know How to Tax Their
Wealth!
The Failure to Tax Rent
The performance of economies freighted by experience
with conventional taxes is much reduced, as has been
widely acknowledged. One Harvard study estimated that
taxes on income exert a deadweight loss equal to a third
of the amount that is collected, half if payroll taxes
are included.[17] Sales taxes
are equally as onerous. But taxing land, due to its fixed
(inelastic) supply, has zero burden; it therefore has no
encumbrance or drag on economic activity whatsoever. By
reducing all the taxes on labor and capital and instead
shifting the burden to various forms of land as a revenue
base, it is possible not only to garner sufficient income
for government programs but to relieve the market from
the friction that slows its performance. Cities then get
a double dividend by shifting to a land tax: downtaxing
any form of labor and capital frees up its potential;
uptaxing land value by the recovery of rent prompts its
more intensive use. Revenue yield could even be increased
in such a tax regime without much additional burden on
homes. This is because underused landsites in the urban
cores would feel the greatest increases.
It should be further noted that wherever tax burdens
are first incurred they are ultimately shifted through
the economy until they come out of economic
rent.[18] By their
initial imposition on other factors of production,
however, they encumber the performance of markets and
foster inequities among populations that is both
inefficient and unjust. This is not difficult to explain:
labor is responsive to the forces of market location,
even if not always in the short run. People are always
free to locate where burdens are less onerous, thus
avoiding efforts to collect taxes when their labor is so
targeted. Capital is even more mobile, especially so in
the age of contemporary communication and wired
transfers. By taxing capital a municipality is insuring
that its investment base will be reduced. Only locations,
and the rent that attaches to them, cannot be moved and
are beyond escaping the reach of taxation. One can't take
one's land to Cancun or Bermuda.
One could argue that the failure to tax every bit of
economic rent that accretes to land sites also has
destructive consequences, although this is somewhat open
to debate. Classical economists agree that rent
collection ought to be at least the sum of inflation plus
interest, otherwise the public is facilitating
speculation in ways that distorts urban configurations
even more than they constitute an inequity. But land
sites frequently rise in market price far more than the
rate of inflation, especially in times (as is perhaps
true today) that a "bubble" in an economic cycle is in
full flower. Some municipalities, especially on the east
and west coasts of US, are today claiming to have
increases in housing prices of as high as 20 percent per
annum, a fever that surely will not last and will be
especially destructive when it collapses.[19] Land values
are what create that bubble; buildings are subject to
continuing depreciation just like cars, computers,
refrigerators or any other manufactured (capital) item.
Recovering the economic rent reduces and perhaps even
eliminates the speculative bubbles and swings that (some
argue) account for economic cycles, fostering stability
and regularity in economic planning and development that
make for improved financial health to all.
This reality brings into stark relief the choices
which local political leaders have. They may suggest
increasing taxes on economic rent (i.e., on land value)
or recognize that most property owners are counting on
treating their homes and other property not as places to
live and work so much as investments and then lament the
poverty of their cities. Owners expect to reap a gain
from their property when they sell, and they are often
positioned to make any threat to that entitlement
politically unpalatable. Farmers sometimes regard selling
their farms as their retirement security. Homeowners sell
with the expectation that this gain will provide them the
means to enter long term end-of-life facilities if
necessary. Heirs also oppose that recapture just as with
a reverse mortgage. But for every long-term property
owner that walks away with a lifetime's benefit of
increased rent attached to a land title, there are just
as many — if not more — young households or
emerging businesses that are prohibited from acquiring a
property because of the prohibitively expensive costs. In
this sense, a title to a socially created stream of
rental benefits constitutes a monopoly privilege to an
unearned windfall gain for a lucky few. It is both unjust
and is socially and economically destructive to the
greater good. ... read
the whole article
Bill Batt: Comment on Parts of the
NYS Legislative Tax Study Commission's 1985 study
“Who Pays New York Taxes?”
Little justification exists for taxing buildings, or
improvements of any sort, so this question is easily
disposed of. The practice is explained largely as a
matter of historical inertia. Only in the recent century
or two have buildings represented any significant capital
value; prior to the rise of major cities, the value of
real property lay essentially in land. American cities
today typically record aggregate assessed land values
– at least when the valuations are well-done
– at about 40% to 60% of total taxable value, that
is, of land and buildings taken together.31 Skyscrapers
reflect enormous capital investment, and this expenditure
is warranted because of the enormous value of locational
sites. Each site gets its market price from the fact that
the total neighborhood context creates an attractive
market presence and ambience. By taxing buildings,
however, we impose a penalty on their optimum development
as well as on the incentives for their maintenance.
Moreover, taxes on buildings take away from whatever
burden would otherwise be imposed on sites, with the
result that incentives for their highest and best use is
weakened. Lastly, the technical and administrative
challenges of properly assessing the value of
improvements is daunting, particularly since they must be
depreciated for tax and accounting purposes, evaluated
for potential replacement, and so on. In fact most costs
associated with administration of property taxation and
appeal litigation involve disputes over the valuation of
structures, not land values.
Land value taxation, on the other hand, overcomes all
these obstacles. Locations are the beneficiaries of
community services whether they are improved or not. As
has been forcefully argued by this writer and others
elsewhere,32 a tax on land value conforms to all the
textbook principles of sound tax theory. Some further
considerations are worth reviewing, however, when looking
at ground rent as a flow rather than as a “present
value” stock. The technical ability to trace
changes in the market prices of sites – or as can
also be understood, the variable flow of ground rent to
those sites – by the application of GIS (geographic
information systems) real-time recording of sales
transactions invites wholesale changes in the maintenance
of cadastral data. The transmittal of sales records as
typically received in the offices of local governments
for purposes of title registration over to
Assessors’ offices allows for the possibility of a
running real-time mapping of market values. Given also
that GIS algorithms can now calculate the land value
proportions reasonably accurately, this means that
“landvaluescapes” are easily created in ways
analogous to maps that portray other common geographic
features. These landvaluescapes reflect the flow of
ground rent through local or regional economies, and can
also be used to identify the areas of greatest market
vitality and enterprise. The flow of economic rent can
easily be taxed in ways that overcomes the mistaken
notion that it is a stock. Just as income is recognized
as a flow of money, rent too can (and should) be
understood as such.
The question still begs to be answered, “why tax
land?” And what happens when we don’t
tax land? Henry George answered this more than a century
ago more forcefully and clearly, perhaps, than anyone has
since. He recognized full well that the economic surplus
not expended by human hands or minds in the production of
capital wealth gravitates to land. Particular land sites
come to reflect the value of their strategic location for
market exchanges by assuming a price for their monopoly
use. Regardless whether those who acquire title to such
sites use them to the full extent of their potential, the
flow of rent to such locations is commensurate with their
full capacity. This is why John Stuart Mill more than a
century ago observed that, “Landlords grow richer
in their sleep without working, risking or
economizing. The increase in the value
of land, arising as it does from the efforts of an entire
community, should belong to the community and not to the
individual who might hold title.”33 Absent its
recovery by taxation this rent becomes a “free
lunch” to opportunistically situated
titleholders. When offered for sale, the
projected rental value is capitalized in the present
value for purposes of attaching a market price and sold
as a commodity. Yet simple justice calls for the recovery
in taxes what is the community’s creation.
Moreover, the failure to recover the land rent connected
to sites makes it necessary to tax productive activities
in our economy, and this leads to economic and technical
inefficiency known as “deadweight loss.”34 It
means that the economy performs suboptimally.
Land, and by this Henry George meant any natural
factor of production not created by human hands or minds,
is ours only to use, not to buy or sell as a commodity.
In the equally immortal words of Jefferson a century
earlier, “The earth belongs in usufruct to the
living; . . . [It is] given as a common stock for men to
labor and live on.”35 This passage likely needs a
bit of parsing for the modern reader. The word usufruct,
understood since Roman times, has almost passed from use
today. It means “the right to use the property of
another so long as its value is not diminished.”36
Note also that Jefferson regarded the earth as a
“common stock;” not allotted to individuals
with possessory titles. Only the phrase “to the
living” might be subject to challenge by
forward-looking environmentalists who, taking an idea
from Native American cultures, argue that “we do
not inherit the earth from our ancestors; we borrow it
from our children.” The presumption that real
property titles are acquired legitimately is a claim that
does not withstand scrutiny; rather all such titles owe
their origin ultimately to force or fraud.37
If we own the land sites that we occupy only in
usufruct, and the rent that derives from those sites is
due to community enterprise, it is not a large logical
leap to argue that the community’s recovery of that
rent should be the proper source of taxation. This is the
Georgist argument: that the recapture of land rent is the
proper – indeed the natural – source of
taxation.38 ... read the whole
commentary
Bill Batt: The
Nexus of Transportation, Economic Rent, and Land
Use
... The failure to collect site rent leads to a
distortion in land use configurations. If patterns
unfolded along the lines of both social preference and
economic efficiency, high value landsites would tend to
have high value buildings, and low value landsites would
tend to be vacant or have very modest buildings.
Consistent with this, urban centers sites would tend to
have office and commercial use, surrounded by lower-value
residential land uses, and still further out would be
farms and forests. The ratio of building to land value,
land to total value (or for that matter any other ratio
between buildings, land, and total values) would be
relatively constant throughout a region. Instead, the
ratio of land value to total value consistently tends to
reveal a patchwork of random development. This
inefficient settlement of land sites is what we know as
sprawl. ... read the
whole article
Bill Batt: How Our
Towns Got That Way (1996 speech)
In classical economics, the definition of capital
grew out of labor mixed with earlier capital. Land, by
conventional definition, was not capital, nor was it a
component of wealth. Rather land was its own category.
Conflating land into capital allowed
land rent to be hidden and diluted in ways so that the
unearned increment arising from social improvements fell
to speculators rather than being returned to society in
rent. The failure of society to recapture the appropriate
level of land rent from titleholders led also to
depression of labor wages at the margin, creating poverty
and artificial scarcity of labor where otherwise it could
be relieved. Hence the title of George's book,
Progress and Poverty. George
recognized that the value of any land parcel arose out of
its social activity, not from anything which a
titleholder might have done to it. He recognized that
many, perhaps most, titleholders in land were
speculators, reaping the benefit of others' investments,
and selling out at last when their price was met. Hence
it made sense that society had a right to a return on
what it had brought about, as well as from the fact that
those titles could never be other than leaseholds. That
land rent, shortly confused by use of the words "single
tax," was, to George, the rightful return to society.
...
Failure to recapture
publicly-created land rents through the tax mechanism
provided the incentive to speculators to buy land, not to
use it in production but to hold it for the rise. In this
way, choice parcels remain undeveloped or underdeveloped
relative to the full extent that their values warrant and
development occurs instead in remote areas where
opportunity for profit is more immediate. The result was
low density development what we know as sprawl.
To some people this may be
counter-intuitive. It may not be obvious that increasing
taxes on a parcel of land will foster its improvement.
Consider, however, the possibility that there are two
parcels of land in roughly the same location and of equal
size. You own a vacant parcel and another next to it has a
twenty-story building. If only the land-value is taxed you
will be paying the same tax revenue as your neighbor. What
are you likely to do with your parcel? If you are rational,
you will either build a twenty-story building or else sell
the land to someone who will. In this way improvements tend
to be clustered in high-land-value areas except where it is
prohibited, perhaps for a park.
Jessica Matthews, now with the Council on Foreign
Relations, recently wrote a syndicated piece observing
that:
In a now familiar sequence, developers reach for
the cheapest land, out in the cow pastures. Government is
left to fill in behind with brand new infrastructure
roads, sewerage systems and schools paid for in part by
those whose existing roads and schools are left to
decline. Property values rise in a ring that marches
steadily outward from the city and fall in older suburbs
inside the moving edge.
Because residential development can't
meet the public bills, local governments compete for
commercial investment with tax discounts that deplete their
revenues still further. Property taxes then rise, providing
an incentive for new development.
Years of such leap-frogging
construction devours land at an astonishing pace. Now if
the full social opportunity cost of land occupancy were
charged to landholders, the reward of (and incentive for)
speculation would be obliterated, and land now locked up by
speculators would be transferred to users. Users would
employ more labor and engender more capital development
instead of seeing it locked up in wasted space.
Absent adequate taxation the regions
at the periphery are the first developed, just as Ms.
Matthews observes.
The economics profession is only now
coming to recognize its responsibility for what it has
wrought. Economists are coming to recognize the costs of
sprawl, and studies show how astonishingly inefficient the
suburban lifestyle is. One review of the literature on the
subject of comparative development costs published by the
Urban Land Institute revealed that "houses built in
sprawling developments may cost 40 to 400 percent more to
serve than if they were located close to major facilities,
were clustered in contiguous areas, and incorporated a
variety of housing types."... read the whole
article
Bill Batt: The Compatibility of Georgist
Economics and Ecological Economics
The Georgist main agenda, as earlier noted, is
economic justice. If one searches the term
“economic justice” online, the first site
that will appear is the Georgist website, progress.org. The starting
point is that people are entitled to what they earn, but
only to what they earn.50 The fruits of the commons
generated in rent might also be distributed to citizens
equally if not used to finance the general services of
government. In practice this means the abolition of those
taxes that represent an unjust capture of one’s
personal property — taxes such as income, sales,
and other nuisance taxes. It accepts, to be sure, the
need to collect user fees, Pigouvian taxes, and perhaps
sumptuary (sin) taxes. It argues aggressively for the
collection of economic rent in support of government and,
for any remaining surplus, its distribution as a
citizens’ dividend. The justification for the
collection of rent has several grounds:
- the first is to preclude the entitlement of
windfall gains to those who have unfairly captured
monopoly control of parts of what are rightfully the
public commons.
- A second reason is to enhance the efficiency
of economic productivity which the failure to collect
rent prevents. It is not just that monopoly control of
commons sites drives less attractive and less valuable
land into production because the primary choices are
unavailable; it is also that the use of alternative taxes
leads to a deadweight loss in the economy which reduces
the wealth of every citizen except the monopoly
titleholder.The proper collection of land rent leads to
increases in economic efficiency in a way that wages are
not artificially depressed and more opportunities arise
in the labor market.
The result of these factors leads to a greater
equality in the income of each person.
...
Failure to collect land rent leads to speculation
and the resulting boom-bust economic cycles that are so
destructive to the general economy.67 Henry George in Progress and Poverty (Bk V, Ch1) identified
the "speculative advance of land values" as the "great
initiatory cause of industrial depressions." Economic
cycles can be linked to just about every downturn over
the course of two centuries, the more so as the economy
has come to be monetized. Frederick Lewis Allen, the
great journalist gives a compelling account of how the
Florida land boom (and later bust) antedated the Great
Depression.68
More recently a similar speculative bubble explains the
Asian economic crash, particularly in
Thailand.69 When
the Japanese economy was at its peak, the value of land
in Tokyo alone exceeded that of the entire United States,
and the appraised land value under the Imperial Palace
was as great as all the real estate in
California.70 The
most convincing study of the relationship between land
value cycles and more general economic cycles is one done
for Australia by a contemporary Georgist
economist.71
There are some students of the American economy that
believe that we are the cusp of a crash in land values
that have been bid up over decades, and that this could
well precipitate a market downturn that could be
long-enduring.72... read the whole
article
|
To share this page with a friend:
right click, choose "send," and add your
comments.
|
|
Red links have not been
visited; .
Green links are pages you've seen
|
Essential Documents pertinent
to this theme:
|
|