Wealth from Land
Appreciation
We are in the habit of thinking of land and buildings
together as "real estate" and forgetting to notice that
land and buildings are fundamentally different. Buildings
depreciate, every year. The land was there before we were
born, and will be there long after we're gone, while
buildings come and go. Land appreciates, as a result of
our common investment in services and infrastructure; as
a result of population increase, as a result of
technological innovations (e.g., think of the impact of
air conditioning and fiberglass boats on land prices in
the American south) and as a result of the natural
amenities in the area. None of these are something any of
us can rightly take credit for, or claim rightly as our
private treasure. Materials for buildings are
readily available and one can be substituted for another;
nothing can be substituted for land! When demand for
buildings increases, so can the supply of building
materials. But land is different, and when demand rises,
as it must if population increases, its value increases
because its supply is fixed.
Should some of us be permitted to grow wealthy on
this, or treat it as our private piggy bank, while others
(our landless, our young, our commuters, to name just
three groups) have to pay the fortunate ones who
privatize the economic value of land? This is privilege
at its worst, and the ripple effects throughout American
society (as in every other society — think of the
places and ways we provide foreign aid, and how little
effect it has on the lives of the poor, but how much the
powerful appreciate it) are far-reaching and
devastating.
The alternative, of course, is to tax land value, to
treat it as our common
treasure, to be collected to support spending on the
common good. The positive effects of this are as positive
as the ripple effects of privilege are devastating. This
is the remedy of which
Henry George wrote and spoke. Our American ancestors
ended chattel slavery. Can we make
our generation the one that
brings awareness and an end to something equally cruel
and devastating — and far more widespread?
Henry George:
Concentrations of Wealth Harm America
(excerpt from Social
Problems)
(1883)
An acquaintance of mine died in San Francisco
recently, leaving $4,000,000, which will go to heirs to
be looked up in England. I have known many men more
industrious, more skilful, more temperate than he -- men
who did not or who will not leave a cent. This man did
not get his wealth by his industry, skill or temperance.
He no more produced it than did those lucky relations in
England who may now do nothing for the rest of their
lives. He became rich by getting hold of a piece of land
in the early days, which, as San Francisco grew, became
very valuable. His wealth represented not what he had
earned, but what the monopoly of this bit of the earth's
surface enabled him to appropriate of the earnings of
others.
A man died in Pittsburgh, the other
day, leaving $3,000,000. He may or may not have been
particularly industrious, skilful and economical, but it
was not by virtue of these qualities that he got so rich.
It was because he went to Washington and helped lobby
through a bill which, by way of "protecting American
workmen against the pauper labor of Europe," gave him the
advantage of a sixty-per-cent, tariff. To the day of his
death he was a stanch protectionist, and said free trade
would ruin our "infant industries." Evidently the
$3,000,000 which he was enabled to lay by from his own
little cherub of an "infant industry" did not represent
what he had added to production. It was the advantage given
him by the tariff that enabled him to scoop it up from
other people's earnings.
"Beneath all political problems lies the
social problem of the distribution of
wealth."
This element of monopoly, of
appropriation and spoliation will, when we come to analyze
them, be found largely to account for all great
fortunes....
Take the great Vanderbilt fortune.
The first Vanderbilt was a boatman who earned money by hard
work and saved it. But it was not working and saving that
enabled him to leave such an enormous fortune. It was
spoliation and monopoly. As soon as he got money enough he
used it as a club to extort from others their earnings. He
ran off opposition lines and monopolized routes of
steamboat travel. Then he went into railroads, pursuing the
same tactics. The Vanderbilt fortune no more comes from
working and saving than did the fortune that Captain Kidd
buried.
Or take the great Gould fortune. Mr.
Gould might have got his first little start by superior
industry and superior self-denial. But it is not that which
has made him the master of a hundred millions. It was by
wrecking railroads, buying judges, corrupting legislatures,
getting up rings and pools and combinations to raise or
depress stock values and transportation rates.
So, like wise, of the great fortunes
which the Pacific railroads have created. They have been
made by lobbying through profligate donations of lands,
bonds and subsidies, by the operations of Credit Mobilier
and Contract and Finance Companies, by monopolizing and
gouging. And so of fortunes made by such combinations as
the Standard Oil Company, the Bessemer Steel Ring, the
Whisky Tax Ring, the Lucifer Match Ring, and the various
rings for the "protection of the American workman from the
pauper labor of Europe."
Or take the fortunes made out of
successful patents. Like that element in so many fortunes
that comes from the increased value of land, these result
from monopoly, pure and simple. And though I am not now
discussing the expediency of patent laws, it may be
observed, in passing, that in the vast majority of cases
the men who make fortunes out of patents are not the men
who make the inventions.
Through all great fortunes, and, in
fact, through nearly all acquisitions that in these days
can fairly be termed fortunes, these elements of monopoly,
of spoliation, of gambling run. The head of one of the
largest manufacturing firms in the United States said to me
recently, "It is not on our ordinary business that we make
our money; it is where we can get a monopoly." And this, I
think, is generally true.
The Evils of Monopolists
Consider the important part in
building up fortunes which the increase of land values
has had, and is having, in the United States. This is, of
course, monopoly, pure and simple. When land
increases in value it does not mean that its owner has
added to the general wealth. The owner may never have
seen the land or done aught to improve it. He may, and
often does, live in a distant city or in another country.
Increase of land values simply means that the owners, by
virtue of their appropriation of something that existed
before man was, have the power of taking a larger share
of the wealth produced by other people's labor. Consider
how much the monopolies created and the advantages given
to the unscrupulous by the tariff and by our system of
internal taxation -- how much the railroad (a business in
its nature a monopoly), telegraph, gas, water and other
similar monopolies, have done to concentrate wealth; how
special rates, pools, combinations, corners,
stock-watering and stock-gambling, the destructive use of
wealth in driving off or buying off opposition which the
public must finally pay for, and many other things which
these will suggest, have operated to build up large
fortunes, and it will at least appear that the unequal
distribution of wealth is due in great measure to sheer
spoliation; that the reason why those who work hard get
so little, while so many who work little get so much, is,
in very large measure, that the earnings of the one class
are, in one way or another, filched away from them to
swell the incomes of the other.
That individuals are constantly
making their way from the ranks of those who get less than
their earnings to the ranks of those who get more than
their earnings, no more proves this state of things right
than the fact that merchant sailors were constantly
becoming pirates and participating in the profits of
piracy, would prove that piracy was right and that no
effort should be made to suppress it.
I am not denouncing the rich, nor seeking, by
speaking of these things, to excite envy and hatred; but
if we would get a clear understanding of social problems,
we must recognize the fact that it is due to monopolies
which we permit and create, to advantages which we give
one man over another, to methods of extortion sanctioned
by law and by public opinion, that some men are enabled
to get so enormously rich while others remain so
miserably poor. If we look around us and note the
elements of monopoly, extortion and spoliation which go
to the building up of all, or nearly all, fortunes, we
see on the one hand now disingenuous are those who preach
to us that there is nothing wrong in social relations and
that the inequalities in the distribution of wealth
spring from the inequalities of human nature; and on the
other hand, we see how wild are those who talk as though
capital were a public enemy, and propose plans for
arbitrarily restricting the acquisition of wealth.
Capital is a good; the capitalist is a helper, if he is
not also a monopolist. We can safely let any one get as
rich as he can if he will not despoil others in doing
so.
There are deep wrongs in the present
constitution of society, but they are not wrongs inherent
in the constitution of man nor in those social laws which
are as truly the laws of the Creator as are the laws of the
physical universe. They are wrongs resulting from bad
adjustments which it is within our power to amend. The
ideal social state is not that in which each gets an equal
amount of wealth, but in which each gets in proportion to
his contribution to the general stock. And in such a social
state there would not be less incentive to exertion than
now; there would be far more incentive. Men will be more
industrious and more moral, better workmen and better
citizens, if each takes his earnings and carries them home
to his family, than where they put their earnings in a
"pot" and gamble for them until some have far more than
they could have earned, and others have little or nothing.
...
Read the entire
article
H.G. Brown: Significant
Paragraphs from Henry George's Progress & Poverty,
Chapter 5: The Basic Cause of Poverty (in the
unabridged:
Book V: The Problem Solved)
The truth is self-evident. Put to any one capable of
consecutive thought this question:
"Suppose there should arise from the English Channel
or the German Ocean a no man's land on which common labor
to an unlimited amount should be able to make thirty
shillings a day and which should remain unappropriated
and of free access, like the commons which once comprised
so large a part of English soil. What would be the effect
upon wages in England?"
He would at once tell you that common wages throughout
England must soon increase to thirty shillings a day.
And in response to another question, "What would be
the effect on rents?" he would at a moment's reflection
say that rents must necessarily fall; and if he thought
out the next step he would tell you that all this would
happen without any very large part of English labor being
diverted to the new natural opportunities, or the forms
and direction of industry being much changed; only that
kind of production being abandoned which now yields to
labor and to landlord together less than labor could
secure on the new opportunities. The great rise in wages
would be at the expense of rent.
Take now the same man or another — some
hardheaded business man, who has no theories, but knows
how to make money. Say to him: "Here is a little village;
in ten years it will be a great city — in ten years
the railroad will have taken the place of the stage
coach, the electric light of the candle; it will abound
with all the machinery and improvements that so
enormously multiply the effective power of labor. Will,
in ten years, interest be any higher?"
He will tell you, "No!"
"Will the wages of common labor be any higher; will it
be easier for a man who has nothing but his labor to make
an independent living?"
He will tell you, "No; the wages of common labor will
not be any higher; on the contrary, all the chances are
that they will be lower; it will not be easier for the
mere laborer to make an independent living; the chances
are that it will be harder."
"What, then, will be higher?"
"Rent; the value of land. Go, get yourself a piece of
ground, and hold possession."
And if, under such circumstances, you take his advice,
you need do nothing more. You may sit down and smoke your
pipe; you may lie around like the lazzaroni of Naples or
the leperos of Mexico; you may go up in a balloon, or
down a hole in the ground; and without doing one stroke
of work, without adding one iota to the wealth of the
community, in ten years you will be rich! In the new city
you may have a luxurious mansion; but among its public
buildings will be an almshouse. ... read the whole
chapter
Rev. A. C. Auchmuty: Gems from George, a themed
collection of excerpts from the writings of Henry
George (with links to sources)
THE poverty to which in advancing civilization great
masses of men are condemned, is not the freedom from
distraction and temptation which sages have sought and
philosophers have praised: it is a degrading and
embruting slavery, that cramps the higher nature, dulls
the finer feelings, and drives men by its pain to acts
which the brutes would refuse. It is into this helpless,
hopeless poverty, that crushes manhood and destroys
womanhood, that robs even childhood of its innocence and
joy, that the working classes are being driven by a force
which acts upon them like a resistless and unpitying
machine. The Boston collar manufacturer who pays his
girls two cents an hour may commiserate their condition,
but he, as they, is governed by the law of competition,
and cannot pay more and carry on his business, for
exchange is not governed by sentiment. And so, through
all intermediate gradations, up to those who receive the
earnings of labor without return, in the rent of land, it
is the inexorable laws of supply and demand, a power with
which the individual can no more quarrel or dispute than
with the winds and the tides, that seem to press down the
lower classes into the slavery of want.
But, in reality, the cause is that which always has, and
always must result in slavery — the monopolization
by some of what nature has designed for all. . . .
Private ownership of land is the nether millstone.
Material progress is the upper millstone. Between them;
with an increasing pressure, the working classes are
being ground. —
Progress & Poverty —
Book VII, Chapter 2, Justice of the Remedy: Enslavement
of laborers the ultimate result of private property in
land
IT is not in the relations of capital and labor; it is
not in the pressure of population against subsistence
that an explanation of the unequal development of our
civilization is to be found. The great cause of
inequality in the distribution of wealth is inequality in
the ownership of land. The ownership of land is the great
fundamental fact which ultimately determines the social,
the political and, consequently, the intellectual and
moral condition of a people. And it must be so. For land
is the habitation of man, the storehouse upon which he
must draw for all his needs, the material to which his
labor must be applied for the supply of all his desires;
for even the products of the sea cannot be taken, the
light of the sun enjoyed, or any of the forces of nature
utilized, without the use of land or its products. On the
land we are born, from it we live, to it we return again
— children of the soil as truly as is the blade of
grass or the flower of the field. —
Progress & Poverty
— Book V, Chapter 2: The Problem Solved: The
persistence of poverty amid advancing wealth
THERE is nothing strange or inexplicable in the phenomena
that are now perplexing the world. It is not that
material progress is not in itself a good, it is not that
nature has called into being children for whom she has
failed to provide; it is not that the Creator has left on
natural laws a taint of injustice at which even the human
mind revolts, that material progress brings such bitter
fruits. That amid our highest civilization men faint and
die with want is not due to the niggardliness of nature,
but to the injustice of man. Vice and misery, poverty and
pauperism, are not the legitimate results of increase of
population and industrial development; they only follow
increase of population and industrial development because
land is treated as private property — they are the
direct and necessary results of the violation of the
supreme law of justice, involved in giving to some men
the exclusive possession of that which nature provides
for all men. —
Progress & Poverty
— Book VII, Chapter 1, Justice of the Remedy:
Injustice of private property in land
... go to "Gems from
George"
Louis Post: Outlines
of Louis F. Post's Lectures, with Illustrative Notes and
Charts (1894)
c. Significance of the Upward Tendency of
Rent
Now, what is the meaning of this tendency of Rent to
rise with social progress, while Wages tend to fall? Is
it not a plain promise that if Rent be treated as common
property, advances in productive power shall be steps in
the direction of realizing through orderly and natural
growth those grand conceptions of both the socialist and
the individualist, which in the present condition of
society are justly ranked as Utopian? Is it not likewise
a plain warning that if Rent be treated as private
property, advances in productive power will be steps in
the direction of making slaves of the many laborers, and
masters of a few land-owners? Does it not mean that
common ownership of Rent is in harmony with natural law,
and that its private appropriation is disorderly and
degrading? When the cause of Rent and the tendency
illustrated in the preceding chart are considered in
connection with the self-evident truth that God made the
earth for common use and not for private monopoly, how
can a contrary inference hold? Caused and increased by
social growth, 97 the benefits of which should be common,
and attaching to land, the just right to which is equal,
Rent must be the natural fund for public expenses. 98
97. Here, far away from civilization, is
a solitary settler. Getting no benefits from
government, he needs no public revenues, and none of
the land about him has any value. Another settler
comes, and another, until a village appears. Some
public revenue is then required. Not much, but some.
And the land has a little value, only a little; perhaps
just enough to equal the need for public revenue. The
village becomes a town. More revenues are needed, and
land values are higher. It becomes a city. The public
revenues required are enormous, and so are the land
values.
98. Society, and society alone, causes
Rent. Rising with the rise, advancing with the growth,
and receding with the decline of society, it measures
the earning power of society as a whole as
distinguished from that of the individuals. Wages, on
the other hand, measure the earning power of the
individuals as distinguished from that of society as a
whole. We have distinguished the parts into which
Wealth is distributed as Wages and Rent; but it would
be correct, indeed it is the same thing, to regard all
wealth as earnings, and to distinguish the two kinds as
Communal Earnings and Individual Earnings. How, then,
can there be any question as to the fund from which
society should be supported? How can it be justly
supported in any other way than out of its own
earnings?
If there be at all such a thing as design in the
universe — and who can doubt it? — then has
it been designed that Rent, the earnings of the
community, shall be retained for the support of the
community, and that Wages, the earnings of the
individual, shall be left to the individual in proportion
to the value of his service. This is the divine law,
whether we trace it through complex moral and economic
relations, or find it in the eighth commandment.
d. Effect of Confiscating Rent to Private
Use.
By giving Rent to individuals society ignores this
most just law, 99 thereby creating social disorder and
inviting social disease. Upon society alone, therefore,
and not upon divine Providence which has provided
bountifully, nor upon the disinherited poor, rests the
responsibility for poverty and fear of poverty.
99. "Whatever dispute arouses the
passions of men, the conflict is sure to rage, not so
much as to the question 'Is it wise?' as to the
question 'Is it right?'
"This tendency of popular discussions to
take an ethical form has a cause. It springs from a law
of the human mind; it rests upon a vague and
instinctive recognition of what is probably the deepest
truth we can grasp. That alone is wise which is just;
that alone is enduring which is right. In the narrow
scale of individual actions and individual life this
truth may be often obscured, but in the wider field of
national life it everywhere stands out.
"I bow to this arbitrament, and accept
this test." — Progress and Poverty, book vii, ch.
i.
The reader who has been deceived into
believing that Mr. George's proposition is in any
respect unjust, will find profit in a perusal of the
entire chapter from which the foregoing extract is
taken.
Let us try to trace the connection by means of a
chart, beginning with the white spaces on page 68. As
before, the first-comers take possession of the best
land. But instead of leaving for others what they do not
themselves need for use, as in the previous
illustrations, they appropriate the whole space, using
only part, but claiming ownership of the rest. We may
distinguish the used part with red color, and that which
is appropriated without use with blue. Thus: [chart]
But what motive is there for appropriating more of the
space than is used? Simply that the appropriators may
secure the pecuniary benefit of future social growth.
What will enable them to secure that? Our system of
confiscating Rent from the community that earns it, and
giving it to land-owners who, as such, earn
nothing.100
100. It is reported from Iowa that a few
years ago a workman in that State saw a meteorite fall,
and. securing possession of it after much digging, he
was offered $105 by a college for his "find." But the
owner of the land on which the meteorite fell claimed
the money, and the two went to law about it. After an
appeal to the highest court of the State, it was
finally decided that neither by right of discovery, nor
by right of labor, could the workman have the money,
because the title to the meteorite was in the man who
owned the land upon which it fell.
Observe the effect now upon Rent and Wages. When other
men come, instead of finding half of the best land still
common and free, as in the corresponding chart on page
68, they find all of it owned, and are obliged either to
go upon poorer land or to buy or rent from owners of the
best. How much will they pay for the best? Not more than
1, if they want it for use and not to hold for a higher
price in the future, for that represents the full
difference between its productiveness and the
productiveness of the next best. But if the first-comers,
reasoning that the next best land will soon be scarce and
theirs will then rise in value, refuse to sell or to rent
at that valuation, the newcomers must resort to land of
the second grade, though the best be as yet only partly
used. Consequently land of the first grade commands Rent
before it otherwise would.
As the sellers' price, under these circumstances, is
arbitrary it cannot be stated in the chart; but the
buyers' price is limited by the superiority of the best
land over that which can be had for nothing, and the
chart may be made to show it: [chart]
And now, owing to the success of the appropriators of
the best land in securing more than their fellows for the
same expenditure of labor force, a rush is made for
unappropriated land. It is not to use it that it is
wanted, but to enable its appropriators to put Rent into
their own pockets as soon as growing demand for land
makes it valuable.101 We may, for illustration, suppose
that all the remainder of the second space and the whole
of the third are thus appropriated, and note the effect:
[chart]
At this point Rent does not increase nor Wages fall,
because there is no increased demand for land for use.
The holding of inferior land for higher prices, when
demand for use is at a standstill, is like owning lots in
the moon — entertaining, perhaps, but not
profitable. But let more land be needed for use, and
matters promptly assume a different appearance. The new
labor must either go to the space that yields but 1, or
buy or rent from owners of better grades, or hire out.
The effect would be the same in any case. Nobody for the
given expenditure of labor force would get more than 1;
the surplus of products would go to landowners as Rent,
either directly in rent payments, or indirectly through
lower Wages. Thus: [chart]
101. The text speaks of Rent only as a
periodical or continuous payment — what would be
called "ground rent." But actual or potential Rent may
always be, and frequently is, capitalized for the
purpose of selling the right to enjoy it, and it is to
selling value that we usually refer when dealing in
land.
Land which has the power of yielding
Rent to its owner will have a selling value, whether it
be used or not, and whether Rent is actually derived
from it or not. This selling value will be the
capitalization of its present or prospective power of
producing Rent. In fact, much the larger proportion of
laud that has a selling value is wholly or partly
unused, producing no Rent at all, or less than it would
if fully used. This condition is expressed in the chart
by the blue color.
"The capitalized value of land is the
actuarial 'discounted' value of all the net incomes
which it is likely to afford, allowance being made on
the one hand for all incidental expenses, including
those of collecting the rents, and on the other for its
mineral wealth, its capabilities of development for any
kind of business, and its advantages, material, social,
and aesthetic, for the purposes of residence." —
Marshall's Prin., book vi, ch. ix, sec. 9.
"The value of land is commonly expressed
as a certain number of times the current money rental,
or in other words, a certain 'number of years'
purchase' of that rental; and other things being equal,
it will be the higher the more important these direct
gratifications are, as well as the greater the chance
that they and the money income afforded by the land
will rise." — Id., note.
"Value . . . means not utility, not any
quality inhering in the thing itself, but a quality
which gives to the possession of a thing the power of
obtaining other things, in return for it or for its
use. . . Value in this sense — the usual sense
— is purely relative. It exists from and is
measured by the power of obtaining things for things by
exchanging them. . . Utility is necessary to value, for
nothing can be valuable unless it has the quality of
gratifying some physical or mental desire of man,
though it be but a fancy or whim. But utility of itself
does not give value. . . If we ask ourselves the reason
of . . . variations in . . . value . . . we see that
things having some form of utility or desirability, are
valuable or not valuable, as they are hard or easy to
get. And if we ask further, we may see that with most
of the things that have value this difficulty or ease
of getting them, which determines value, depends on the
amount of labor which must be expended in producing
them ; i.e., bringing them into the place, form and
condition in which they are desired. . . Value is
simply an expression of the labor required for the
production of such a thing. But there are some things
as to which this is not so clear. Land is not produced
by labor, yet land, irrespective of any improvements
that labor has made on it, often has value. . . Yet a
little examination will show that such facts are but
exemplifications of the general principle, just as the
rise of a balloon and the fall of a stone both
exemplify the universal law of gravitation. . . The
value of everything produced by labor, from a pound of
chalk or a paper of pins to the elaborate structure and
appurtenances of a first-class ocean steamer, is
resolvable on analysis into an equivalent of the labor
required to produce such a thing in form and place;
while the value of things not produced by labor, but
nevertheless susceptible of ownership, is in the same
way resolvable into an equivalent of the labor which
the ownership of such a thing enables the owner to
obtain or save." —
Perplexed Philosopher, ch. v.
The figure 1 in parenthesis, as an item of Rent,
indicates potential Rent. Labor would give that much for
the privilege of using the space, but the owners hold out
for better terms; therefore neither Rent nor Wages is
actually produced, though but for this both might be.
In this chart, notwithstanding that but little space
is used, indicated with red, Wages are reduced to the
same low point by the mere appropriation of space,
indicated with blue, that they would reach if all the
space above the poorest were fully used. It thereby
appears that under a system which confiscates Rent to
private uses, the demand for land for speculative
purposes becomes so great that Wages fall to a minimum
long before they would if land were appropriated only for
use.
In illustrating the effect of confiscating Rent to
private use we have as yet ignored the element of social
growth. Let us now assume as before (page 73), that
social growth increases the productive power of the given
expenditure of labor force to 100 when applied to the
best land, 50 when applied to the next best, 10 to the
next, 3 to the next, and 1 to the poorest. Labor would
not be benefited now, as it appeared to be when on page
73 we illustrated the appropriation of land for use only,
although much less land is actually used. The prizes
which expectation of future social growth dangles before
men as the rewards of owning land, would raise demand so
as to make it more than ever difficult to get land. All
of the fourth grade would be taken up in expectation of
future demand; and "surplus labor" would be crowded out
to the open space that originally yielded nothing, but
which in consequence of increased labor power now yields
as much as the poorest closed space originally yielded,
namely, 1 to the given expenditure of labor force.102
Wages would then be reduced to the present productiveness
of the open space. Thus: [chart]
102. The paradise to which the youth of
our country have so long been directed in the advice,
"Go West, young man, go West," is truthfully described
in "Progress and Poverty," book iv, ch. iv, as follows
:
"The man who sets out from the eastern
seaboard in search of the margin of cultivation,
where he may obtain land without paying rent, must,
like the man who swam the river to get a drink, pass
for long distances through half-titled farms, and
traverse vast areas of virgin soil, before he reaches
the point where land can be had free of rent —
i.e., by homestead entry or preemption."
If we assume that 1 for the given expenditure of labor
force is the least that labor can take while exerting the
same force, the downward movement of Wages will be here
held in equilibrium. They cannot fall below 1; but
neither can they rise above it, no matter how much
productive power may increase, so long as it pays to hold
land for higher values. Some laborers would continually
be pushed back to land which increased productive power
would have brought up in productiveness from 0 to 1, and
by perpetual competition for work would so regulate the
labor market that the given expenditure of labor force,
however much it produced, could nowhere secure more than
1 in Wages.103 And this tendency would persist until some
labor was forced upon land which, despite increase in
productive power, would not yield the accustomed living
without increase of labor force. Competition for work
would then compel all laborers to increase their
expenditure of labor force, and to do it over and over
again as progress went on and lower and lower grades of
land were monopolized, until human endurance could go no
further.104 Either that, or they would be obliged to
adapt themselves to a lower scale of living.105
103. Henry Fawcett, in his work on
"Political Economy," book ii, ch. iii, observes with
reference to improvements in agricultural implements
which diminish the expense of cultivation, that they do
not increase the profits of the farmer or the wages of
his laborers, but that "the landlord will receive in
addition to the rent already paid to him, all that is
saved in the expense of cultivation." This is true not
alone of improvements in agriculture, but also of
improvements in all other branches of industry.
104. "The cause which limits speculation
in commodities, the tendency of increasing price to
draw forth additional supplies, cannot limit the
speculative advance in land values, as land is a fixed
quantity, which human agency can neither increase nor
diminish; but there is nevertheless a limit to the
price of land, in the minimum required by labor and
capital as the condition of engaging in production. If
it were possible to continuously reduce wages until
zero were reached, it would be possible to continuously
increase rent until it swallowed up the whole produce.
But as wages cannot be permanently reduced below the
point at which laborers will consent to work and
reproduce, nor interest below the point at which
capital will be devoted to production, there is a limit
which restrains the speculative advance of rent. Hence,
speculation cannot have the same scope to advance rent
in countries where wages and interest are already near
the minimum, as in countries where they are
considerably above it. Yet that there is in all
progressive countries a constant tendency in the
speculative advance of rent to overpass the limit where
production would cease, is, I think, shown by recurring
seasons of industrial paralysis." — Progress and
Poverty, book iv, ch. iv.
105. As Puck once put it, "the man who
makes two blades of grass to grow where but one grew
before, must not be surprised when ordered to 'keep off
the grass.' "
They in fact do both, and the incidental disturbances
of general readjustment are what we call "hard times."
106 These culminate in forcing unused land into the
market, thereby reducing Rent and reviving industry. Thus
increase of labor force, a lowering of the scale of
living, and depression of Rent, co-operate to bring on
what we call "good times." But no sooner do "good times"
return than renewed demands for land set in, Rent rises
again, Wages fall again, and "hard times" duly reappear.
The end of every period of "hard times" finds Rent higher
and Wages lower than at the end of the previous
period.107
106. "That a speculative advance in rent
or land values invariably precedes each of these
seasons of industrial depression is everywhere clear.
That they bear to each other the relation of cause and
effect, is obvious to whoever considers the necessary
relation between land and labor." — Progress and
Poverty, book v, ch. i.
107. What are called "good times" reach
a point at which an upward land market sets in. From
that point there is a downward tendency of wages (or a
rise in the cost of living, which is the same thing) in
all departments of labor and with all grades of
laborers. This tendency continues until the fictitious
values of land give way. So long as the tendency is
felt only by that class which is hired for wages, it is
poverty merely; when the same tendency is felt by the
class of labor that is distinguished as "the business
interests of the country," it is "hard times." And
"hard times" are periodical because land values, by
falling, allow "good times" to set it, and by rising
with "good times" bring "hard times" on again. The
effect of "hard times" may be overcome, without much,
if any, fall in land values, by sufficient increase in
productive power to overtake the fictitious value of
land.
The dishonest and disorderly system under which
society confiscates Rent from common to individual uses,
produces this result. That maladjustment is the
fundamental cause of poverty. And progress, so long as
the maladjustment continues, instead of tending to remove
poverty as naturally it should, actually generates and
intensifies it. Poverty persists with increase of
productive power because land values, when Rent is
privately appropriated, tend to even greater increase.
There can be but one outcome if this continues: for
individuals suffering and degradation, and for society
destruction. ...
Q32. Is not ownership of land necessary to induce
its improvement? Does not history show that private
ownership is a step in advance of common
ownership?
A. No. Private use was doubtless a step in advance of
common use. And because private use seems to us to have
been brought about under the institution of private
ownership, private ownership appears to the superficial
to have been the real advance. But a little observation
and reflection will remove that impression. Private
ownership of land is not necessary to its private use.
And so far from inducing improvement, private ownership
retards it. When a man owns land he may accumulate wealth
by doing nothing with the land, simply allowing the
community to increase its value while he pays a merely
nominal tax, upon the plea that he gets no income from
the property. But when the possessor has to pay the value
of his land every year, as he would have to under the
single tax, and as ground renters do now, he must improve
his holding in order to profit by it. Private possession
of land, without profit except from use, promotes
improvement; private ownership, with profit regardless of
use, retards improvement. Every city in the world, in its
vacant lots, offers proof of the statement. It is the
lots that are owned, and not those that are held upon
ground-lease, that remain vacant.
... read the
book
Michael Hudson: The
Lies of the Land: How and why land gets undervalued
Turning land-value gains into capital
gains
Hiding the free lunch
Two appraisal methods
How land gets a negative value!
Where did all the land value go?
A curious asymmetry
Site values as the economy's "credit
sink"
Immortally aging buildings
Real estate industry's priorities
THE FREE LUNCH
* Its cost to
citizens
* Its cost to the
economy
SUMMARY
YOU MAY THINK the largest category of
assets in this countrly is industrial plant and machinery.
In fact the US Federal Reserve Board's
annual balance sheet shows real estate to be the economy's
largest asset, two-thirds of America's
wealth and more than 60 percent of that in land, depending
on the assessment method.
Most capital gains are land-value
gains. The big players do not want their profits in rent,
which is taxed as ordinary income, but in capital gains,
taxed at a lower rate. To benefit as much as
possible from today's real estate bubble of fast rising
land values they pledge a property's rent income to pay
interest on the debt for as much property as they can buy
with as little of their own money as possible. After
paying off the mortgage lender they sell the property and
get to keep the "capital gain".
This price appreciation is
actually a "land gain," that is, it's not from providing
start-up capital for new enterprises, but from sitting on
a rising asset already in place, the land. Its
value rises because neighbourhoods are upgraded, mortgage
money is ample, and rezoning is favorable from farmland
on the outskirts of cities to gentrification of the core
to create high-income residential developments. The
potential capital gain can be huge. That's why developers
are willing to pay their mortgage lenders so much of
their rent income, often all of it. ...
SUMMARY
For hundreds of years property's value has been
calculated by discounting its flow of rental income at
the going rate of interest. The lower the interest rate,
the higher the price a given rental stream will justify
-- or as property owners express it, the more years' rent
a property will bring. What is so striking about land
values today is that they are rising for reasons
independent of their earnings stream. The major new
consideration is their prospect for future "capital"
(that is, land-price) gains. In sum, the ultimate aim of
real estate investors no longer is so much to seek income
-- most of which is pledged to their bankers as interest
payments on the property they acquire -- as much as to
seek property gains. Politically opportunites abound.
Merely changing zoning in New York City in the 1980s
to allow using commercial loft spaces for residential
purposes had the effect of multiplying asset values five
or tenfold.
Whether the gains come from selling
the property or from borrowing more money against it, the
essential phenomenon is the rapid growth in asset values
and real estate's uniquely favored tax treatment. That's
why investors choose real estate instead of bonds or
stocks, and much of the strategy underlying corporate
takeovers has followed the strategies they developed over
the past half century.
Nationwide the capital-gains
dimension needs to be incorporated into the rental revenue
statistics to measure real estate's total returns.
This sector's nearly complete success in
escaping the tax collector has placed an enormous tax
burden on everyone else. read the entire
article
Bill Batt: Who Says
Cities are Poor? They Just Don't Know How to Tax Their
Wealth!
One could argue that the failure to tax every bit of
economic rent that accretes to land sites also has
destructive consequences, although this is somewhat open
to debate. Classical economists agree that rent
collection ought to be at least the sum of inflation plus
interest, otherwise the public is facilitating
speculation in ways that distorts urban configurations
even more than they constitute an inequity. But land
sites frequently rise in market price far more than the
rate of inflation, especially in times (as is perhaps
true today) that a "bubble" in an economic cycle is in
full flower. Some municipalities, especially on the east
and west coasts of US, are today claiming to have
increases in housing prices of as high as 20 percent per
annum, a fever that surely will not last and will be
especially destructive when it collapses.[19] Land
values are what create that bubble; buildings are subject
to continuing depreciation just like cars, computers,
refrigerators or any other manufactured (capital) item.
Recovering the economic rent reduces and perhaps even
eliminates the speculative bubbles and swings that (some
argue) account for economic cycles, fostering stability
and regularity in economic planning and development that
make for improved financial health to all.
This reality brings into stark relief the choices
which local political leaders have. They may
suggest increasing taxes on economic rent (i.e., on land
value) or recognize that most property owners are
counting on treating their homes and other property not
as places to live and work so much as investments and
then lament the poverty of their cities. Owners expect to
reap a gain from their property when they sell, and they
are often positioned to make any threat to that
entitlement politically unpalatable. Farmers sometimes
regard selling their farms as their retirement security.
Homeowners sell with the expectation that this gain will
provide them the means to enter long term end-of-life
facilities if necessary. Heirs also oppose that recapture
just as with a reverse mortgage. But for every
long-term property owner that walks away with a
lifetime's benefit of increased rent attached to a land
title, there are just as many — if not more —
young households or emerging businesses that are
prohibited from acquiring a property because of the
prohibitively expensive costs. In this sense, a title to
a socially created stream of rental benefits constitutes
a monopoly privilege to an unearned windfall gain for a
lucky few. It is both unjust and is socially and
economically destructive to the greater good. ...
read the whole
article
Bill Batt: Painless
Taxation
Abstract Real tax reform could
do away with those taxes that are resented by the large
proportion of our population. We could replace all taxes
on wages and on interest by instead taxing economic rent.
Rent is windfall income; it is income that arises not
from the efforts of any person or corporation; it comes
about as a surplus gain from common social enterprise.
There is ample moral warrant for society to lay claim to
that which it has created, as well as to that which no
individual or party has earned. Analysis increasingly
makes clear that economic rent in all its forms is far
larger than official government figures indicate; in fact
it is likely sufficient to supplant all current taxes on
labor and capital (wages and interest) which are
acknowledged to have so many negative effects. Recovering
economic rent in all its manifestations by taxing its
various bases actually can foster economic performance
and yield other benefits that make it the natural source
of revenue for governments. Such a tax is essentially
painless. ...
The Tax Base
The next concern should be upon what base to impose a
tax — not about taxing whom but taxing what. There
are only three possibilities, as all revenue streams
necessarily come from one of three factors of economic
production —
1) upon resources found raw in nature (what was
classically called land),
2) upon our labor, or
3) upon things created by human hands or minds
(capital).
No other source exists; every possible tax must be on
one or some combination of these parts. Each of these
factors has its price: the price of land is counted in
economic rent; the price of labor is in wages, and the
price of capital (its liquid form) is in interest.
Any tax on capital has its downside effects, so that
taxing savings causes people to save less, taxing
consumption causes people to buy less, and taxing
buildings causes people to build less. The result is that
economists as well as businessmen usually frown upon
taxing capital. Another alternative is to tax labor, but
it is even more widely understood that taxing labor
normally discourages people from working as much as they
would in the absence of a tax. From this comes sentiment
against taxing labor, even though for want of any
alternative, people have today commonly come to accept it
as a necessity. But electing to tax labor, just as for
taxing capital, forecloses a discussion of the virtues of
taxing land — not necessarily land as earth, but
rather land as location. Yet land rent is the
most attractive tax base of all, as rent is not earned;
it is windfall income, entirely the result of being well
situated in any market of scarce natural resources and
where community demand (rather than one's own efforts)
leads to an appreciation of that land's price.
To be sure many people have learned to position
themselves in situations where a land's market value is
likely to rise — indeed these people come to think
of themselves as astute investors. But the fact is that
that market gain is not of their own doing at all; it is
the result of common enterprise creating a surplus that
comes to settle on land sites. An investment in land, in
any form it might take, is speculation in greater or
lesser degree.
Land in all its forms is a tax base that also conforms
well to all the classic principles of sound tax theory as
enumerated above. Land is classically taken to mean not
just surfaces of the earth but places in time, in space,
in any medium whether it be solid, liquid or gas, and
even as a form of light, in the electromagnetic spectrum,
and in life forms. One needs to return to 19th century
classical economic definitions of the factors of
production to appreciate the separate significance of
land as it was understood in its manifold forms. One
should ask how it is that land, so important to 19th
century classical economic theory, has been given so
little attention today in neoclassical economics. This is
a story only now recovered from the dusty archives of
academic economic history. Once understood and
appreciated, it may be one of the greatest, if very
silent, political revolutions of world
history.[4] ... read the whole
article
Bill Batt: The
Compatibility of Georgist Economics and Ecological
Economics
In the Georgist view, this economic rent is the
public’s birthright, and the failure to collect it
and to use it to pay for the general costs of government
services is a moral as well as a public policy lapse.
Georgists regard the private confiscation of public
wealth as mistaken policy if not actually an immoral
transgression — in a word, theft! He himself was an
advocate of the public owning and protecting “the
commons” and what is today often called
“natural capital.” Studies have shown that if
economic rent were collected in full as well as other
appropriate revenues such as user fees and green taxes,
the total income would likely be enough to pay not only
the costs of all government services but provide a
citizens’ dividend of significant amounts as
well.48
Statistical data is difficult to compile, but what
studies have been attempted to date indicate that
economic rent in all its forms and from all its sources
comprises approximately a third of the economy as it is
currently calculated.49 Arrangements such as these are to
the followers of Henry George a far more efficient and
moral system of public finance. ... read the whole
article
Mason Gaffney: Unearned increments and
reality in California's recall election
California homeowners are wallowing in unearned
increments beyond the dreams of avarice, while its
governments are courting bankruptcy.
Warren Buffett dared point this out, and overnight
changed from the Oracle of Omaha into the Numbskull of
Nebraska because he does not understand the "reality of
California politics," the oxymoron du jour. ...
Most candidates for Governor fled like startled deer.
Buffett's sponsor, well-tailored Mr. Muscles, recalled
meeting a tearful widow who said she would have been
taxed out of her home were it not for Prop 13. Poor
thing, her home had risen in value. No one asked her
name, or whether she knew what she was talking about, or
had her claims audited - being a tearful widow "on a
fixed income" insulates one from reality checks. The
press chimed in with pix of poster oldsters, gazing from
their multi-million dollar perches over the blue Pacific,
fretting about Buffett's solecism and its possible effect
on them, never mind anyone else.
Fact is, unearned increments ARE income, at the time
they accrue. Illiquid? They are better than cash income
because you can turn them into cash by borrowing on them,
and pay no income tax on the cash. If you have trouble
with that, the tax man himself will arrange it for you by
placing a tax lien on your appreciated home, rather than
foreclose and evict you. This helps explain why we never
actually see one of these evicted widows suffering from
unearned increments -- they are maudlin figments for
mythmakers. The evictees we do see are renters who
couldn't pay, and had no equity to mortgage. Who cries
for them?
Several rich candidates would pay more under a revived
property tax than they pay in income taxes.
- Mr. Muscles, like previous Hollywood idols, gets
most of his income as land appreciation. This income is
not taxable unless he sells, and not then if he hires
good lawyers, which of course he does, to play his
cards right.
- Arianna Huffington lives in a $7 million home, but
reports little net taxable income.
- Warren Buffett himself, like the owners of so much
California land, resides and reports his income out of
state.
These facts should tell us something about who pays
most of the property tax, but no candidate is inferring
principles from mere facts. ... read the whole
article
Ted Gwartney:
A Free Market Strategy to Reduce Sprawl
If land holders can produce a higher return on
investment by not using land for productive purposes but
rather hold it for a higher price from those willing and
able to pay the higher price in the future, there is a
flaw in public policy. Public policy thereby gives
speculative, nonproductive investment a higher return
than productive investment. Sprawl is subsidized by taxes
on production and distribution and the failure to
recapture the benefits resulting from public
improvements. If we choose to end this subsidy, we would
reduce sprawl.
One example that I know is that of a friend who bought
land within the city but did nothing with it. I asked him
why he put good money into an investment that had no
visible return? He replied that, by holding the land for
future sale or development, his long term return, in
capital gains would exceed 18% annually. If he built a
building on the site now, his long term return would only
be 12% annually, including both net income plus capital
gains. Why should he use his land now when it would be
more profitable for him to not use it, but to hold it for
a larger future gain?
Most major cities have a substantial amount of fully
serviced but unused or underused land sites. It is
estimated that 38% of the land area in Los Angeles is
unused, 30% in New York City and 25% in Washington, D.C.
Intercity sites are bypassed because land speculators
receive a greater benefit by ignoring the highest and
best use of land sites. A greater profit is made when
development is delayed and the land price increases to
higher levels. But building within existing developed
areas uses the existing and underused infrastructure,
roads, transit, public facilities, and services. Sprawl
requires new expenditures on public goods and services,
more government, more taxes, more dislocation. ...
read the whole article
Nic Tideman:
Land Taxation and Efficient Land Speculation
The optimal timing of development is an important
allocative function that can be either enhanced or
degraded by the impact of land taxes on land speculation.
This paper discusses four types of taxes on land:
- taxes on the rental value of land,
- taxes on the sale value of land,
- taxes on realized income from land, and
- taxes on realized gains from the sale of land.
All four taxes reduce incentives for speculation in
land, which is generally beneficial. The third and fourth
produce distortions with respect to incentives to develop
land, while the first and second do not. All four taxes
have some beneficial effect of mitigating imperfections
in capital markets. All permit reduction or elimination
of taxes with significant dead-weight losses, such as
those on improvements. ...
read the whole article
Frank Stilwell and Kirrily Jordan: The Political Economy of Land:
Putting Henry George in His Place
Land is the most basic of all economic resources,
fundamental to the form that economic development takes.
Its use for agricultural purposes is integral to the
production of the means of our subsistence. Its use in an
urban context is crucial in shaping how effectively
cities function and who gets the principal benefits from
urban economic growth. Its ownership is a major
determinant of the degree of economic inequality:
surges of land prices, such as have occurred in
Australian cities during the last decade, cause major
redistributions of wealth. In both an urban and
rural context the use of land – and nature more
generally – is central to the possibility of
ecological sustainability. Contemporary social concerns
about problems of housing affordability and environmental
quality necessarily focus our attention on ‘the
land question.’ ...
Are George’s arguments about land ownership and
wealth inequality relevant today? Australia provides an
interesting example, because land is the single largest
item in national wealth. Laurie Aarons outlines the
concentration of farming land in particular in the hands
of a few very wealthy corporations and individuals
– what he refers to as ‘corporate
squattocracy’ (Aarons, 1999: 23). The relentless
increase in urban land values in recent years has also
produced dramatic redistributions of wealth. In the State
of New South Wales, for example, land values increased by
about $361 billion over the period 1993 – 2003. The
existing land-based taxes clawed back only $44 billion in
government revenues, comprising only about 12% of the
land-related economic surplus. So 88% was retained as
‘unearned income’ by landowners (Stilwell and
Jordan, forthcoming). A higher rate of land tax with
fewer exemptions could have substantially reduced this
private wealth appropriation. This is not necessarily to
posit the desirability of recouping 100% through land
tax, because that would certainly raise major problems of
people’s ability to pay, given that much of the
increased wealth resulting from land price inflation has
not been realised as current income. But it is indicative
of the current imbalance between private and public
appropriations of the surplus arising from increases in
land-based wealth. ...
The demand for land involves both use values and
exchange values. People seek land because the housing
built on it provides shelter and security, but they also
purchase it as a store of wealth and a means of capital
appreciation. A particularly important driver of real
estate prices has been the speculative demand, as
investors seek capital gains in the property market. In
Australia, this has been such common and longstanding
practice that it has been referred to as ‘the
national hobby’ (Sandercock, 1979). By
‘creaming off’ a part of this potential
capital gain, a higher uniform rate of land tax would act
as a disincentive to this property speculation, and could
therefore be expected to exert a downward influence on
property prices. Georgists have always been emphatic that
land taxes are different from other taxes in this respect
– they depress prices because they reduce demand.
So the usual fears that a tax will be ‘passed
on’ to customers (such as housing tenants, in this
case) do not apply. By making land less attractive as an
item to be purchased in the hope of making capital gains,
land tax can therefore be an important check on the
inflationary process. ... read the whole
article
Peter Barnes:
Capitalism 3.0 — Chapter 5: Reinventing the Commons
(pages 65-78)
Suppose you buy a house for $300,000, and without
improving it, sell it a few years later for $400,000. You
pay off the mortgage and walk away with a pile of cash.
Your private wealth increases. But think about what
caused the house to rise in value. It wasn’t
anything you did. Rather, it was the fact that your
neighborhood became more popular. That, in turn, resulted
from population shifts, a new highway perhaps, an
improved school, or the beautification efforts of
neighbors. In other words, your increased wealth is a
capture of socially created value. It shows up as private
wealth but is really a gift of society. ...
read the whole chapter
|
To share this page with a friend:
right click, choose "send," and add your
comments.
|
|
Red links have not been
visited; .
Green links are pages you've seen
|
Essential Documents pertinent
to this theme:
|
|