Speculation
If you know the movie Mr. Smith Goes to
Washington, the underlying story is one of
special interests, specifically land speculation —
in this case, the land surrounding a prospective dam site
in Smith's home state.
H.G. Brown: Significant Paragraphs
from Henry George's Progress & Poverty, Chapter 4: Land
Speculation Causes Reduced Wages
There is a cause, not yet adverted to, which must be
taken into consideration fully to explain the influence
of material progress upon the distribution of wealth.
That cause is the confident expectation of the
future enhancement of land values, which arises
in all progressive countries from the steady increase of
rent, and which leads to speculation, or
the holding of land for a higher price than it would then
otherwise bring.
We have hitherto assumed, as is generally assumed in
elucidations of the theory of rent, that the actual
margin of cultivation always coincides with what may be
termed the necessary margin of cultivation — that
is to say, we have assumed that cultivation extends to
less productive points only as it becomes necessary from
the fact that natural opportunities are at the more
productive points fully utilized.
This, probably, is the case in stationary or very
slowly progressing communities, but in rapidly
progressing communities, where the swift and steady
increase of rent gives confidence to calculations of
further increase, it is not the case. In such
communities, the confident expectation of increased
prices produces, to a greater or less extent, the effects
of a combination among landholders, and tends to the
withholding of land from use, in expectation of higher
prices, thus forcing the margin of cultivation farther
than required by the necessities of production. ...
read the
whole chapter
Henry George: Justice
the Object -- Taxation the Means (1890)
If the limitation is not in labour and not in
capital, it must be in land. But there is no scarcity of
land from the Atlantic to the Pacific, for there you will
find unused or only half-used land. Aye, even where
population is densest. Have you not land enough in San
Francisco? Go to that great city of New York, where
people are crowded together so closely, the great
majority of them, that physical health and moral health
are in many cases alike impossible. Where, in spite of
the fact that the rich men of the whole country gravitate
there, only four per cent of the families live in
separate houses of their own, and sixty-five per cent of
the families are crowded two or more to the single floor
— crowded together layer on layer, in many places,
like sardines in a box. Yet, why are there not more
houses there? Not because there is not enough capital to
build more houses, and yet not because there is not land
enough on which to build more houses.
Today one half of the
area of New York City is unbuilt upon — is absolutely
unused. When there is such a pressure, why don't people go
to these vacant lots and build there? Because though
unused, the land is owned; because, speculating upon the
future growth of the city, the owners of those vacant lots
demand thousands of dollars before they will permit anyone
to put a house upon them. What you see in New York,
you may see everywhere. Come into the coalfields of
Pennsylvania; there you will frequently find thousands and
thousands of miners unable to work, either locked out by
their employers, or striking as a last resource against
their pitiful wages being cut down a little more.
Read the entire article
Henry George: The Condition of Labor
— An Open Letter to Pope Leo XIII in response to
Rerum Novarum (1891)
That the value attaching to land with social growth is
intended for social needs is shown by the final proof.
God is indeed a jealous God in the sense that nothing but
injury and disaster can attend the effort of men to do
things other than in the way he has intended; in the
sense that where the blessings he proffers to men are
refused or misused they turn to evils that scourge us.
And just as for the mother to withhold the provision that
fills her breast with the birth of the child is to
endanger physical health, so for society to refuse to
take for social uses the provision intended for them is
to breed social disease.
For refusal to take for public purposes the increasing
values that attach to land with social growth is to
necessitate the getting of public revenues by taxes that
lessen production, distort distribution and corrupt
society. It is to leave some to take what justly belongs
to all; it is to forego the only means by which it is
possible in an advanced civilization to combine the
security of possession that is necessary to improvement
with the equality of natural opportunity that is the most
important of all natural rights. It is thus at the basis
of all social life to set up an unjust inequality between
man and man, compelling some to pay others for the
privilege of living, for the chance of working, for the
advantages of civilization, for the gifts of their God.
But it is even more than this. The very robbery that the
masses of men thus suffer gives rise in advancing
communities to a new robbery. For the value that
with the increase of population and social advance
attaches to land being suffered to go to individuals who
have secured ownership of the land, it prompts to a
forestalling of and speculation in land wherever there is
any prospect of advancing population or of coming
improvement, thus producing an artificial scarcity of the
natural elements of life and labor, and a strangulation
of production that shows itself in recurring spasms of
industrial depression as disastrous to the world as
destructive wars. It is this that is driving men
from the old countries to the new countries, only to
bring there the same curses. It is this that causes our
material advance not merely to fail to improve the
condition of the mere worker, but to make the condition
of large classes positively worse. It is this that in our
richest Christian countries is giving us a large
population whose lives are harder, more hopeless, more
degraded than those of the veriest savages. It is this
that leads so many men to think that God is a bungler and
is constantly bringing more people into his world than he
has made provision for; or that there is no God, and that
belief in him is a superstition which the facts of life
and the advance of science are dispelling. ...
But worse perhaps than all else is the way in which
this substituting of vague injunctions to charity for the
clear-cut demands of justice opens an easy means for the
professed teachers of the Christian religion of all
branches and communions to placate Mammon while
persuading themselves that they are serving God. Had the
English clergy not subordinated the teaching of justice
to the teaching of charity — to go no further in
illustrating a principle of which the whole history of
Christendom from Constantine’s time to our own is
witness — the Tudor tyranny would never have
arisen, and the separation of the church been averted;
had the clergy of France never substituted charity for
justice, the monstrous iniquities of the ancient
régime would never have brought the horrors of the
Great Revolution; and in my own country had those who
should have preached justice not satisfied themselves
with preaching kindness, chattel slavery could never have
demanded the holocaust of our civil war.
No, your Holiness; as faith without works is dead, as
men cannot give to God his due while denying to their
fellows the rights be gave them, so charity unsupported
by justice can do nothing to solve the problem of the
existing condition of labor. Though the rich were to
“bestow all their goods to feed the poor and give
their bodies to be burned,” poverty would continue
while property in land continues.
Take the case of the rich man today who is honestly
desirous of devoting his wealth to the improvement of the
condition of labor. What can he do?
- Bestow his wealth on those who need it? He may help
some who deserve it, but will not improve general
conditions. And against the good he may do will be the
danger of doing harm.
- Build churches? Under the shadow of churches
poverty festers and the vice that is born of it
breeds.
- Build schools and colleges? Save as it may lead men
to see the iniquity of private property in land,
increased education can effect nothing for mere
laborers, for as education is diffused the wages of
education sink.
- Establish hospitals? Why, already it seems to
laborers that there are too many seeking work, and to
save and prolong life is to add to the pressure.
- Build model tenements? Unless he cheapens house
accommodations he but drives further the class he would
benefit, and as he cheapens house accommodations he
brings more to seek employment and cheapens wages.
- Institute laboratories, scientific schools,
workshops for physical experiments? He but stimulates
invention and discovery, the very forces that, acting
on a society based on private property in land, are
crushing labor as between the upper and the nether
millstone.
- Promote emigration from places where wages are low
to places where they are somewhat higher? If he does,
even those whom he at first helps to emigrate will soon
turn on him to demand that such emigration shall be
stopped as reducing their wages.
- Give away what land he may have, or refuse to take
rent for it, or let it at lower rents than the market
price? He will simply make new landowners or partial
landowners; he may make some individuals the richer,
but he will do nothing to improve the general condition
of labor.
- Or, bethinking himself of those public-spirited
citizens of classic times who spent great sums in
improving their native cities, shall he try to beautify
the city of his birth or adoption? Let him widen and
straighten narrow and crooked streets, let him build
parks and erect fountains, let him open tramways and
bring in railroads, or in any way make beautiful and
attractive his chosen city, and what will be the
result? Must it not be that those who appropriate
God’s bounty will take his also? Will it not be
that the value of land will go up, and that the net
result of his benefactions will be an increase of rents
and a bounty to landowners? Why, even the mere
announcement that he is going to do such things will
start speculation and send up the value of land by
leaps and bounds.
What, then, can the rich man do to improve the
condition of labor?
He can do nothing at all except to use his strength
for the abolition of the great primary wrong that robs
men of their birthright. The justice of God laughs at the
attempts of men to substitute anything else for it. ...
read the whole
letter
Rev. A. C. Auchmuty: Gems from George, a themed
collection of excerpts from the writings of Henry
George (with links to sources)
The Laws of Social Life
TAKE now some hard-headed businessman, who
has no theories, but knows how to make money. Say to him:
"Here is a little village; in ten years it will be a
great city — in ten years the railroad will have
taken the place of the stagecoach, the electric light of
the candle; it will abound with all the machinery and
improvements that so enormously multiply the effective
power of labor. Will, in ten years, interest be any
higher?"
He will tell you, "No!"
"Will the wages of common labor be any higher; will it be
easier for a man who has nothing but his labor to make an
independent living?"
He will tell you, "No; the wages of common labor will not
be any higher; on the contrary, all the chances are that
they will be lower; it will not be easier for the mere
laborer to make an independent living; the chances are
that it will be harder."
"What, then, will be higher?" " Rent; the value of land.
Go; get yourself a piece of ground, and hold
possession."
And if, under such circumstances, you take his advice,
you need do nothing more. You may sit down and smoke your
pipe; you may lie around like the lazzaroni of Naples or
the leperos of Mexico: you may go up in a balloon, or
down a hole in the ground; and without doing one stroke
of work, without adding one iota to the wealth of the
community, in ten years you will be rich! In the new city
you may have a luxurious mansion; but among its public
buildings will be an almshouse. —
Progress & Poverty
— Book V, Chapter 2: The Problem Solved: The
Persistence of Poverty amid Advancing Wealth
THERE may be disputes as to whether there is yet a
science of political economy, that is to say, whether our
knowledge of the natural economic laws is as yet so large
and well digested as to merit the title of science. But
among those who recognize that the world we live in is in
all its spheres governed by law, there can be no dispute
as to the possibility of such a science. — The
Science of Political Economy —
unabridged: Book I, Chapter 14, The Meaning of Political
Economy: Political Economy as Science and as Art
• abridged:
Part 1, Chapter 12: Political Economy as Science and
Art
THE domain of law is not confined to physical nature. It
just as certainly embraces the mental and moral universe,
and social growth and social life have their laws as
fixed as those of matter and of motion. Would we make
social life healthy and happy, we must discover those
laws, and seek our ends in accordance with them. —
Social Problems
— Chapter 22: Conclusion
THE mode of taxation is quite as important as the
amount. As a small burden badly placed may distress a
horse that could carry with ease a much larger one
properly adjusted, so a people may be impoverished and
their power of producing wealth destroyed by taxation,
which, if levied in another way, could be borne with
ease. —
Progress & Poverty
— Book VIII, Chapter 3, Application of the Remedy:
The Proposition Tried by the Canons of Taxation
IF we impose a tax upon buildings, the users of
buildings must finally pay it, for the erection of
buildings will cease until building rents become high
enough to pay the regular profit and the tax besides. If
we impose a tax upon manufactures or imported goods, the
manufacturer or importer will charge it in a higher price
to the jobber, the jobber to the retailer, and the
retailer to the consumer. Now, the consumer, on whom the
tax thus ultimately falls, must not only pay the amount
of the tax, but also a profit on this amount to everyone
who has thus advanced it — for profit on the
capital he has advanced in paying taxes is as much
required by each dealer as profit on the capital he has
advanced in paying for goods. —
Progress & Poverty
— Book VIII, Chapter 3, Application of the Remedy:
The Proposition Tried by the Canons of Taxation
THE way taxes raise prices is by increasing the cost of
production, and checking supply. But land is not a thing
of human production, and taxes upon rent cannot check
supply. Therefore though a tax on rent compels the
landowners to pay more, it gives them no power to obtain
more for the use of their land, as it in no way tends to
reduce the supply of land. On the contrary, by compelling
those who hold land on speculation to sell or let for
what they can get, a tax on land values tends to increase
the competition between owners, and thus to reduce the
price of land. —
Progress & Poverty
— Book VIII, Chapter 3, Application of the Remedy:
The Proposition Tried by the Canons of Taxation
... go to "Gems from
George"
Winston Churchill: Land Price as a Cause of
Poverty (1909 speech in Parliament)
When the Leader of the Opposition seeks by
comparisons to show that the same reasoning which has
been applied to land ought also in logic and by every
argument of symmetry to be applied to the unearned
increment derived from other processes which are at work
in our modern civilisation, he only shows by each example
he takes how different are the conditions which attach to
the possession of land and speculation in the value of
land from those which attach to other forms of business
speculation.
"If," he inquires, "you tax the
unearned increment on land, why don't you tax the unearned
increment from a large block of stock? I buy a piece of
land; the value rises. I buy stocks; their value rises."
But the operations are entirely dissimilar.
- In the first speculation the unearned
increment derived from land arises from a wholly sterile
process, from the mere withholding of a commodity which
is needed by the community.
- In the second case, the investor in a block of
shares does not withhold from the community what the
community needs.
The one operation is in restraint
of trade and in conflict with the general interest, and
the other is part of a natural and healthy process, by
which the economic plant of the world is nourished and
from year to year successfully and notably
increased. ... Read the
whole piece
Charles B. Fillebrown: A Catechism of Natural
Taxation, from Principles of Natural Taxation
(1917)
Q41. Why would the single tax be an improvement
upon present systems of taxation?
A. Because: (1) The taking for public uses of that value
which justly belongs to the public is not a tax; (2) it
would relieve all workers and capitalists of those taxes
by which they are now unjustly burdened, and (3) it would
make unprofitable the holding of land idle.
Q52. In old cities, it is not nearly all the land
in use?
A. About one half the area of New York and Chicago is
classed by the assessors as vacant. In Boston the
proportion is: occupied, 45 percent; vacant, 43
percent; marsh, 12 percent.
Q58. What expected result of the
single tax needs studious emphasis?
A. That it would unlock the land to labor at its present
value for use, instead of locking out labor from the land
by a prohibitive price based upon the future value for
use. ... read
the whole article
John Dewey: Steps to
Economic Recovery
You cannot study Henry George without learning how
intimately each of these wrongs and evils is bound up
with our land system. One of our great national
weaknesses is speculation. Everybody recognizes that fact
in the stock market orgy of our late boom days. Only a
few realize the extent to which speculation in land is
the source of many troubles of the farmer, the part it
has played in loading banks and insurance companies with
frozen assets and compelling the closing of thousands of
banks, nor how the high rents, the unpayable mortgages
and the slums of the cities are connected with
speculation in land values. All authorities on public
works hold that the most fruitful field for them is slum
clearance and better housing. Yet only a few seem to
realize that with our present situation this improvement
will put a bonus in the pockets of landlords, and the
land speculator will be the one to profit
financially--for after all, buildings are built on
land.
So with taxation. There are all sorts of tinkering
going on, but the tinkers and patchers shut their eyes to
the fact that the socially produced annual value of land
-- not of improvements, but of ground-rent value -- is
about five billion dollars, and that its appropriation by
those who create it, the community, would at once relieve
the tax burden and ultimately would solve the tax
problem. Of late the federal government has concerned
itself with the problems of home ownership, but again by
methods of tinkering that may easily in the long run do
more harm than good. The community's acquisition of its
own creation, ground-rent value, would both reduce the
price of land and entirely eliminate taxes on
improvement, thus making ownership easier. And how anyone
expects to solve the unemployment question by putting the
sanction of both legality and high pecuniary reward upon
the ability of the few to keep the many from equal access
to land and to the raw material, without which labor is
impossible, I do not see -- and no one else does. For the
tinkerers assume that unemployment must continues, only
with government assistance to those who are necessarily
out of work. By all means let us help those that now need
it, but for the future let us prevent the cause instead
of merely mitigating the effects. ... read the whole speech
Upton Sinclair: The
Consequences of Land Speculation are Tenantry and Debt on
the Farms, and Slums and Luxury in the Cities
I know of a woman — I have never had the
pleasure of making her acquaintance, because she lives in
a lunatic asylum, which does not happen to be on my
visiting list. This woman has been mentally incompetent
from birth. She is well taken care of, because her father
left her when he died the income of a large farm on the
outskirts of a city. The city has since grown and the
land is now worth, at conservative estimate, about twenty
million dollars. It is covered with office buildings, and
the greater part of the income, which cannot be spent by
the woman, is piling up at compound interest. The woman
enjoys good health, so she may be worth a hundred million
dollars before she dies.
I choose this case because it is one about which there
can be no disputing; this woman has never been able to do
anything to earn that twenty million dollars. And if a
visitor from Mars should come down to study the
situation, which would he think was most insane, the
unfortunate woman, or the society which compels thousands
of people to wear themselves to death in order to pay her
the income of twenty million dollars?
The fact that this woman is insane makes it easy to
see that she is not entitled to the "unearned increment"
of the land she owns. But how about all the other people
who have bought up and are holding for speculation the
most desirable land? The value of this land increases,
not because of anything these owners do — not
because of any useful service they render to the
community — but purely because the community as a
whole is crowding into that neighborhood and must have
use of the land.
The speculator who bought this land thinks that he
deserves the increase, because he guessed the fact that
the city was going to grow that way. But it seems clear
enough that his skill in guessing which way the community
was going to grow, however useful that skill may be to
himself, is not in any way useful to the community. The
man may have planted trees, or built roads, and put in
sidewalks and sewers; all that is useful work, and for
that he should be paid. But should he be paid for
guessing what the rest of us were going to need?
Before you answer, consider the consequences of this
guessing game. The consequences of land speculation are
tenantry and debt on the farms, and slums and luxury in
the cities. A great part of the necessary land is held
out of use, and so the value of all land continually
increases, until the poor man can no longer own a home.
The value of farm land also increases; so year by year
more independent farmers are dispossessed, because they
cannot pay interest on their mortgages. So the land
becomes a place of serfdom, that land described by the
poet, "where wealth accumulates and men decay." The great
cities fill up with festering slums, and a small class of
idle parasites are provided with enormous fortunes, which
they do not have to earn, and which they cannot
intelligently spend. ... read the whole
article
Louis Post: Outlines
of Louis F. Post's Lectures, with Illustrative Notes and
Charts (1894)
d. Effect of Confiscating Rent
to Private Use.
By giving Rent to individuals society ignores this
most just law, 99 thereby creating social disorder and
inviting social disease. Upon society alone, therefore,
and not upon divine Providence which has provided
bountifully, nor upon the disinherited poor, rests the
responsibility for poverty and fear of poverty.
99. "Whatever dispute arouses the
passions of men, the conflict is sure to rage, not so
much as to the question 'Is it wise?' as to the
question 'Is it right?'
"This tendency of popular discussions to
take an ethical form has a cause. It springs from a law
of the human mind; it rests upon a vague and
instinctive recognition of what is probably the deepest
truth we can grasp. That alone is wise which is just;
that alone is enduring which is right. In the narrow
scale of individual actions and individual life this
truth may be often obscured, but in the wider field of
national life it everywhere stands out.
"I bow to this arbitrament, and accept
this test." — Progress and Poverty, book vii, ch.
i.
The reader who has been deceived into
believing that Mr. George's proposition is in any
respect unjust, will find profit in a perusal of the
entire chapter from which the foregoing extract is
taken.
Let us try to trace the connection by means of a
chart, beginning with the white spaces on page 68. As
before, the first-comers take possession of the best
land. But instead of leaving for others what they do not
themselves need for use, as in the previous
illustrations, they appropriate the whole space, using
only part, but claiming ownership of the rest. We may
distinguish the used part with red color, and that which
is appropriated without use with blue. Thus: [chart]
But what motive is there for appropriating more of the
space than is used? Simply that the appropriators may
secure the pecuniary benefit of future social growth.
What will enable them to secure that? Our system of
confiscating Rent from the community that earns it, and
giving it to land-owners who, as such, earn
nothing.100
100. It is reported from Iowa that a few
years ago a workman in that State saw a meteorite fall,
and. securing possession of it after much digging, he
was offered $105 by a college for his "find." But the
owner of the land on which the meteorite fell claimed
the money, and the two went to law about it. After an
appeal to the highest court of the State, it was
finally decided that neither by right of discovery, nor
by right of labor, could the workman have the money,
because the title to the meteorite was in the man who
owned the land upon which it fell.
Observe the effect now upon Rent and Wages. When other
men come, instead of finding half of the best land still
common and free, as in the corresponding chart on page
68, they find all of it owned, and are obliged either to
go upon poorer land or to buy or rent from owners of the
best. How much will they pay for the best? Not more than
1, if they want it for use and not to hold for a higher
price in the future, for that represents the full
difference between its productiveness and the
productiveness of the next best. But if the first-comers,
reasoning that the next best land will soon be scarce and
theirs will then rise in value, refuse to sell or to rent
at that valuation, the newcomers must resort to land of
the second grade, though the best be as yet only partly
used. Consequently land of the first grade commands Rent
before it otherwise would.
As the sellers' price, under these circumstances, is
arbitrary it cannot be stated in the chart; but the
buyers' price is limited by the superiority of the best
land over that which can be had for nothing, and the
chart may be made to show it: [chart]
And now, owing to the success of the appropriators of
the best land in securing more than their fellows for the
same expenditure of labor force, a rush is made for
unappropriated land. It is not to use it that it is
wanted, but to enable its appropriators to put Rent into
their own pockets as soon as growing demand for land
makes it valuable.101 We may, for illustration, suppose
that all the remainder of the second space and the whole
of the third are thus appropriated, and note the effect:
[chart]
At this point Rent does not increase nor Wages fall,
because there is no increased demand for land for use.
The holding of inferior land for higher prices, when
demand for use is at a standstill, is like owning lots in
the moon — entertaining, perhaps, but not
profitable. But let more land be needed for use, and
matters promptly assume a different appearance. The new
labor must either go to the space that yields but 1, or
buy or rent from owners of better grades, or hire out.
The effect would be the same in any case. Nobody for the
given expenditure of labor force would get more than 1;
the surplus of products would go to landowners as Rent,
either directly in rent payments, or indirectly through
lower Wages. Thus: [chart]
101. The text speaks of Rent only as a
periodical or continuous payment — what would be
called "ground rent." But actual or potential Rent may
always be, and frequently is, capitalized for the
purpose of selling the right to enjoy it, and it is to
selling value that we usually refer when dealing in
land.
Land which has the power of yielding
Rent to its owner will have a selling value, whether it
be used or not, and whether Rent is actually derived
from it or not. This selling value will be the
capitalization of its present or prospective power of
producing Rent. In fact, much the larger proportion of
laud that has a selling value is wholly or partly
unused, producing no Rent at all, or less than it would
if fully used. This condition is expressed in the chart
by the blue color.
"The capitalized value of land is the
actuarial 'discounted' value of all the net incomes
which it is likely to afford, allowance being made on
the one hand for all incidental expenses, including
those of collecting the rents, and on the other for its
mineral wealth, its capabilities of development for any
kind of business, and its advantages, material, social,
and aesthetic, for the purposes of residence." —
Marshall's Prin., book vi, ch. ix, sec. 9.
"The value of land is commonly expressed
as a certain number of times the current money rental,
or in other words, a certain 'number of years'
purchase' of that rental; and other things being equal,
it will be the higher the more important these direct
gratifications are, as well as the greater the chance
that they and the money income afforded by the land
will rise." — Id., note.
"Value . . . means not utility, not any
quality inhering in the thing itself, but a quality
which gives to the possession of a thing the power of
obtaining other things, in return for it or for its
use. . . Value in this sense — the usual sense
— is purely relative. It exists from and is
measured by the power of obtaining things for things by
exchanging them. . . Utility is necessary to value, for
nothing can be valuable unless it has the quality of
gratifying some physical or mental desire of man,
though it be but a fancy or whim. But utility of itself
does not give value. . . If we ask ourselves the reason
of . . . variations in . . . value . . . we see that
things having some form of utility or desirability, are
valuable or not valuable, as they are hard or easy to
get. And if we ask further, we may see that with most
of the things that have value this difficulty or ease
of getting them, which determines value, depends on the
amount of labor which must be expended in producing
them ; i.e., bringing them into the place, form and
condition in which they are desired. . . Value is
simply an expression of the labor required for the
production of such a thing. But there are some things
as to which this is not so clear. Land is not produced
by labor, yet land, irrespective of any improvements
that labor has made on it, often has value. . . Yet a
little examination will show that such facts are but
exemplifications of the general principle, just as the
rise of a balloon and the fall of a stone both
exemplify the universal law of gravitation. . . The
value of everything produced by labor, from a pound of
chalk or a paper of pins to the elaborate structure and
appurtenances of a first-class ocean steamer, is
resolvable on analysis into an equivalent of the labor
required to produce such a thing in form and place;
while the value of things not produced by labor, but
nevertheless susceptible of ownership, is in the same
way resolvable into an equivalent of the labor which
the ownership of such a thing enables the owner to
obtain or save." —
Perplexed Philosopher, ch. v.
The figure 1 in parenthesis, as an item of Rent,
indicates potential Rent. Labor would give that much for
the privilege of using the space, but the owners hold out
for better terms; therefore neither Rent nor Wages is
actually produced, though but for this both might be.
In this chart, notwithstanding that but little space
is used, indicated with red, Wages are reduced to the
same low point by the mere appropriation of space,
indicated with blue, that they would reach if all the
space above the poorest were fully used. It thereby
appears that under a system which confiscates Rent to
private uses, the demand for land for speculative
purposes becomes so great that Wages fall to a minimum
long before they would if land were appropriated only for
use.
In illustrating the effect of confiscating Rent to
private use we have as yet ignored the element of social
growth. Let us now assume as before (page 73), that
social growth increases the productive power of the given
expenditure of labor force to 100 when applied to the
best land, 50 when applied to the next best, 10 to the
next, 3 to the next, and 1 to the poorest. Labor would
not be benefited now, as it appeared to be when on page
73 we illustrated the appropriation of land for use only,
although much less land is actually used. The prizes
which expectation of future social growth dangles before
men as the rewards of owning land, would raise demand so
as to make it more than ever difficult to get land. All
of the fourth grade would be taken up in expectation of
future demand; and "surplus labor" would be crowded out
to the open space that originally yielded nothing, but
which in consequence of increased labor power now yields
as much as the poorest closed space originally yielded,
namely, 1 to the given expenditure of labor force.102
Wages would then be reduced to the present productiveness
of the open space. Thus: [chart]
102. The paradise to which the youth of
our country have so long been directed in the advice,
"Go West, young man, go West," is truthfully described
in "Progress and Poverty," book iv, ch. iv, as follows
:
"The man who sets out from the eastern
seaboard in search of the margin of cultivation,
where he may obtain land without paying rent, must,
like the man who swam the river to get a drink, pass
for long distances through half-titled farms, and
traverse vast areas of virgin soil, before he reaches
the point where land can be had free of rent —
i.e., by homestead entry or preemption."
If we assume that 1 for the given expenditure of labor
force is the least that labor can take while exerting the
same force, the downward movement of Wages will be here
held in equilibrium. They cannot fall below 1; but
neither can they rise above it, no matter how much
productive power may increase, so long as it pays to hold
land for higher values. Some laborers would continually
be pushed back to land which increased productive power
would have brought up in productiveness from 0 to 1, and
by perpetual competition for work would so regulate the
labor market that the given expenditure of labor force,
however much it produced, could nowhere secure more than
1 in Wages.103 And this tendency would persist until some
labor was forced upon land which, despite increase in
productive power, would not yield the accustomed living
without increase of labor force. Competition for work
would then compel all laborers to increase their
expenditure of labor force, and to do it over and over
again as progress went on and lower and lower grades of
land were monopolized, until human endurance could go no
further.104 Either that, or they would be obliged to
adapt themselves to a lower scale of living.105
103. Henry Fawcett, in his work on
"Political Economy," book ii, ch. iii, observes with
reference to improvements in agricultural implements
which diminish the expense of cultivation, that they do
not increase the profits of the farmer or the wages of
his laborers, but that "the landlord will receive in
addition to the rent already paid to him, all that is
saved in the expense of cultivation." This is true not
alone of improvements in agriculture, but also of
improvements in all other branches of industry.
104. "The cause which limits speculation
in commodities, the tendency of increasing price to
draw forth additional supplies, cannot limit the
speculative advance in land values, as land is a fixed
quantity, which human agency can neither increase nor
diminish; but there is nevertheless a limit to the
price of land, in the minimum required by labor and
capital as the condition of engaging in production. If
it were possible to continuously reduce wages until
zero were reached, it would be possible to continuously
increase rent until it swallowed up the whole produce.
But as wages cannot be permanently reduced below the
point at which laborers will consent to work and
reproduce, nor interest below the point at which
capital will be devoted to production, there is a limit
which restrains the speculative advance of rent. Hence,
speculation cannot have the same scope to advance rent
in countries where wages and interest are already near
the minimum, as in countries where they are
considerably above it. Yet that there is in all
progressive countries a constant tendency in the
speculative advance of rent to overpass the limit where
production would cease, is, I think, shown by recurring
seasons of industrial paralysis." — Progress and
Poverty, book iv, ch. iv.
105. As Puck once put it, "the man who
makes two blades of grass to grow where but one grew
before, must not be surprised when ordered to 'keep off
the grass.' "
They in fact do both, and the incidental disturbances
of general readjustment are what we call "hard times."
106 These culminate in forcing unused land into the
market, thereby reducing Rent and reviving industry. Thus
increase of labor force, a lowering of the scale of
living, and depression of Rent, co-operate to bring on
what we call "good times." But no sooner do "good times"
return than renewed demands for land set in, Rent rises
again, Wages fall again, and "hard times" duly reappear.
The end of every period of "hard times" finds Rent higher
and Wages lower than at the end of the previous
period.107
106. "That a speculative advance in rent
or land values invariably precedes each of these
seasons of industrial depression is everywhere clear.
That they bear to each other the relation of cause and
effect, is obvious to whoever considers the necessary
relation between land and labor." — Progress and
Poverty, book v, ch. i.
107. What are called "good times" reach
a point at which an upward land market sets in. From
that point there is a downward tendency of wages (or a
rise in the cost of living, which is the same thing) in
all departments of labor and with all grades of
laborers. This tendency continues until the fictitious
values of land give way. So long as the tendency is
felt only by that class which is hired for wages, it is
poverty merely; when the same tendency is felt by the
class of labor that is distinguished as "the business
interests of the country," it is "hard times." And
"hard times" are periodical because land values, by
falling, allow "good times" to set it, and by rising
with "good times" bring "hard times" on again. The
effect of "hard times" may be overcome, without much,
if any, fall in land values, by sufficient increase in
productive power to overtake the fictitious value of
land.
The dishonest and disorderly system under which
society confiscates Rent from common to individual uses,
produces this result. That maladjustment is the
fundamental cause of poverty. And progress, so long as
the maladjustment continues, instead of tending to remove
poverty as naturally it should, actually generates and
intensifies it. Poverty persists with increase of
productive power because land values, when Rent is
privately appropriated, tend to even greater increase.
There can be but one outcome if this continues: for
individuals suffering and degradation, and for society
destruction.
f. The Single Tax Retains Rent
for Common Use.
To retain Rent for common use it is not necessary to
abolish land-titles, nor to let land out to the highest
bidder, nor to invent some new mechanism of taxation, nor
in any other way to directly change existing modes of
holding land for use, or existing machinery for
collecting public revenues. "Great changes can be best
brought about under old forms."109 Let land be held
nominally as it is now. Let taxes be collected by the
same kind of machinery as now. But abolish all taxes
except those that fall upon actual and potential Rent,
that is to say, upon land values.
109. "Such dupes are men to custom, and
so prone
To rev'rence what is ancient and can plead
A course of long observance for its use,
That even servitude, the worst of ills,
Because delivered down from sire to son
Is kept and guarded as a sacred thing."
—Cowper.
It is only custom that makes the
ownership of land seem reasonable. I have frequently
had occasion to tell of the necessity under which the
city of Cleveland, Ohio, found itself, of paying a
land-owner several thousand dollars for the right to
swing a bridge-draw over his land. When I described the
matter in that way, the story attracted no attention;
it seemed perfectly reasonable to the ordinary lecture
audience. But when I described the transaction as a
payment by the city to a land-owner of thousands of
dollars for the privilege of swinging the draw "through
that man's air," the audience invariably manifested its
appreciation of the absurdity of such an ownership. The
idea of owning air was ridiculous; the idea of owning
land was not. Yet who can explain the difference,
except as a matter of custom?
To the same effect was the question of
the Rev. F. L. Higgins to a friend. While stationed at
Galveston, Tex., Mr. Higgins fell into a discussion
with his friend as to the right of government to make
land private property. The friend argued that no matter
what the abstract right might be, the government had
made private property of land, and people had bought
and sold upon the strength of the government title, and
therefore land titles were morally absolute.
"Suppose," said Mr. Higgins, "that the
government should vest in a corporation title to the
Gulf of Mexico, so that no one could fish there, or
sail there, or do anything in or upon the waters of the
Gulf without permission from the corporation. Would
that be right?"
"No," answered the friend.
"Well, suppose the corporation should
then parcel out the Gulf to different parties until
some of the people came to own the whole Gulf to the
exclusion of everybody else, born and unborn. Could any
such title be acquired by these purchasers, or their
descendants or assignees, as that the rest of the
people if they got the power would not have a moral
right to abrogate it?"
"Certainly not," said the friend.
"Could private titles to the Gulf
possibly become absolute in morals?"
"No."
"Then tell me," asked Mr. Higgins, "what
difference it would make if all the water were taken
off the Gulf and only the bare land left."
If that were done it is doubtful if land-owners could
any longer confiscate enough Rent to be worth the
trouble. Even though some surplus were still kept by
them, it would be so much more easy to secure Wealth by
working for it than by confiscating Rent to private use,
to say nothing of its being so much more respectable,
that speculation in land values would practically be
abandoned. At any rate, the question of a surplus —
Rent in excess of the requirements of the community
— may be readily determined when the principle that
Rent justly belongs to the community and Wages to the
individual shall have been recognized by society in the
adoption of the Single Tax. 110
110. Thomas G. Shearman, Esq., of
New York, author of the famous magazine article on "Who
Owns the United States," estimates that sixty-five per
cent of the present annual value of the land in the
United States would pay all the present expenses of
American government — federal, state, county, and
municipal. ... read the book
Louis Post: Outlines
of Louis F. Post's Lectures, with Illustrative Notes and
Charts (1894) — Appendix: FAQ
Q5. If the full rental value were taken would it
not produce too much revenue and encourage official
extravagance? If only what was needed for an economical
administration of government, would not land still have a
speculative value?
A. In the first part of your question you are thinking of
a vast centralized government as administering public
revenues. With the revenues raised locally, each locality
being assessed for its contribution to the state and the
nation, there would be no such danger. The
possibility of this danger would be still further reduced
by the fact that private business would then offer
greater pecuniary prizes than would public office,
wherefore public office would be sought for purer
purposes than as money-making opportunities. As to the
second part of your question, the speculative value of
land would be wiped out as soon as the tax on land values
was high enough and that on improvement values low enough
to make production more profitable than
speculation. And this point would be reached
long before the whole rental value was absorbed in
taxation.
Q22. What difference would it make to tenants
whether they paid land rent to the community or to
private owners?
A. When they pay it to the community they are paying it
in part to themselves, and what others pay they share in;
for they are part of the community. They are also exempt
from taxes. And since there would be no inducement to
speculate in land if rent went to the community, land
would be more plentiful and rents would consequently be
lower.
Q43. Is there any land question in places where
land is cheap? In Texas, for example, you can get land as
cheap as two dollars an acre. Is there a land question
there?
A. There is no place where land is cheap in the sense
implied by the question. Land commands a low price in
many places, but it is poor land; it is not cheap land.
It is true that in Texas there is land that can be had
for two dollars an acre, but it would yield less profit
to each unit of labor and capital expended upon it than
land in New York City which costs hundreds of thousands
of dollars an acre. The valuable New York land is the
cheaper of the two. The land question is the question in
every place where land costs more than it is worth for
immediate use.
Q44. Though some people have made money by owning
land, isn't it true that others have lost? And don't the
losses more than off-set the gains?
A. Possibly. But that has no bearing upon the question.
What men lose through investments in land, the community
does not gain; but what they gain the community does
lose. Therefore, as between land speculators and the
community, the losses cannot be charged against the
gains.
Q45. What is the difference between speculation in
land and in other kinds of property?
A. If all the products of the world were cornered by
speculators, but land were free, new products would soon
appear and the ill effects of the speculation would
quickly pass away. But if all the land were cornered by
speculators, though everything else were free, the people
would immediately be dependent upon the speculators for a
chance to live. That illustrates the difference.
Q46. How can it be possible that speculative land
values cause business depressions when, as any business
man will tell you, the whole item of land value —
whether ground rent or interest on purchase money —
is one of the smallest items in every
business?
A. You overlook the fact that the item of speculative
rent is the only item which the business man does not get
back again. The cost of his goods, the expense of clerk
hire, the rent of his building, the wear and tear of
implements, are all received back, in the course of
normal business, in the prices of his goods. Even his
ground rent, to the extent that it is normal (i.e., what
it would be if the supply of land were determined alone
by land in use, and not affected by the land that is held
out of use for higher values), comes back to him in the
sense that his aggregate profits are that much greater
than they would be where ground rent was less. But the
extra ground rent which he is obliged to pay, in
consequence of the abnormal scarcity of land, is a dead
weight; it does not come back to him. Therefore, even if
infinitesimal in amount, as compared with the other
expenses of his business — and that is by no means
admitted — it is the one expense which may break a
thriving business down. Besides, it is not alone the
ground rent paid by the business man for his location
that bears down upon his business prosperity; the weight
of abnormally high land values in general presses upon
business in general, and by obstructing the flow of trade
forces the weaker business units to the wall. It is not
altogether safe to deduce general economic principles
from the ledgers of particular business houses.
... read the
book
Charles T. Root — Not a Single Tax! (1925)
But before this time the reader, unless he has given
previous attention to the subject, is full of objections
to the above doctrine: "How about the law?" he is asking.
"Hasn't a man the right to buy a piece of land as cheaply
as he can, to do what he pleases with it, and hold on to
it till he gets ready to sell?" The answer is that at
present he certainly has this statutory right, which has
been so long and so universally recognized that most
people suppose it to be not only a legal, but a real or
equitable right. A shrewd man, foreseeing the direction
of growth of population in a city, for example, can buy a
well-located block at a moderate figure from some less
far-seeing owner, can let it grow up to weeds, fence it
off against all comers and give it no further attention
except to pay the very small tax usually imposed upon
vacant land.
Meantime the increasing community builds up all around
it with homes, banks, stores, churches, schools, paving
and lighting the streets, giving police and fire
protection, etc., and at last comes to need this block so
urgently that the owner is fairly begged to sell it, at
three or ten or fifty times what it cost him. Quite often
the purchaser at this enormous advance is the very
community which has through its presence and the
expenditure of its taxes created practically the whole
value of the land in question!
It was said above that an individual has a statutory
right to pursue this very common course. That was an
error. The statement should have been that he has a
statutory wrong; for no disinterested person can follow
the course of land speculation as almost universally
practiced, without feeling its rank injustice.
How did so evident a wrong become so firmly
established? ...
But — and right here is one of the prime
advantages of the abolition of taxation — Mr.
Rhinelastor, in order to get satisfactory return from his
land, must improve it. Unless he is satisfied with a
small income from it, to wit, the proportion of the
economic rent which the community chooses to leave in his
hands, he must put upon his land the best building the
location will warrant. The rents of this building will be
his in their entirety, not one dollar of them being taken
from him by taxation. If he is not prepared or not
willing to do this he would probably find it more
profitable, before he leaves the country, to sell the
land to some one of the many persons who are eager to
build upon it. It will always be salable, although not by
any means at present figures.
Now imagine for a moment the effect upon the
appearance of a city and upon the comfort of its
population which would result from the change of fiscal
policy which this article proposes. At present, a
tempting premium is placed upon keeping land unimproved
or inadequately improved, while a heavy penalty is
imposed upon improvement. Most land appreciates
constantly. All buildings depreciate from the moment of
completion. Yet the building is taxed equally with the
land.
What incentive does such a system offer the
speculative landowner to put up a commodious,
well-lighted modern structure in place of the old ruin
which now pays him so well? The old one cannot depreciate
much more, and while paying a trifling tax because of its
physical worthlessness, he is thereby enabled to collect
and pocket the economic rent of the ground, which the
community is continually rendering more valuable. The new
building would absorb a large amount of capital, would
begin to run down even before it could be occupied, and
would be taxed to the limit. Why then is not the landlord
justified in letting well enough alone, enjoying the
growing economic rent, and waiting till he can get a
fancy price for the right to collect it?
But reverse the conditions. Reclaim for the community
its natural income, making it expensive either to keep
needed land vacant or to withhold it from the ready and
willing to improve it to the full extent of its
possibilities.
Does it require severe intellectual effort to foresee
the results? Better and better houses, apartments,
tenements, offices and stores, more employment for labor
in all enterprises now held back by the shadow of the
tax-gatherer, an end of all tax-lying, tax-evasion and
tax-injustice, and withal, a public revenue adequate to
all real public needs. ... read the whole article
Michael Hudson: The
Lies of the Land: How and why land gets undervalued
Turning land-value gains into capital
gains
Hiding the free lunch
Two appraisal methods
How land gets a negative value!
Where did all the land value go?
A curious asymmetry
Site values as the economy's "credit
sink"
Immortally aging buildings
Real estate industry's priorities
THE FREE LUNCH
* Its cost to
citizens
* Its cost to the
economy
SUMMARY
Hiding the free lunch
BAUDELAIRE OBSERVED that the devil wins at the
point where he convinces humanity that he does not exist.
The Financial, Insurance and Real Estate (FIRE)
sectors seem to have adopted a kindred philosophy that
what is not quantified and reported will be invisible to
the tax collector, leaving more to be pledged for
mortgage credit and paid out as interest. It appears to
have worked. To academic theorists as
well, breathlessly focused on their own particular
hypothetical world, the magnitude of land rent and
land-price gains has become invisible.But not to investors. They are out to pick a
property whose location value increases faster rate than
the interest charges, and they want to stay away from
earnings on man-made capital -- like improvements. That's
earned income, not the "free lunch" they get from land
value increases.
Chicago School economists insist that
no free lunch exists. But when one begins to look beneath
the surface of national income statistics and the national
balance sheet of assets and liabilities, one can see that
modern economies are all about obtaining a free lunch.
However, to make this free ride go all the faster,
it helps if the rest of the world does not
see that anyone is getting the proverbial something for
nothing - what classical economists called
unearned income, most
characteristically in the form of land rent. You start by using a method of appraising that
undervalues the real income producer, land. Here's how it's
done. ...
YOU MAY THINK the largest category of assets in this
countrly is industrial plant and machinery. In fact
the US Federal Reserve Board's annual
balance sheet shows real estate to be the economy's
largest asset, two-thirds of America's
wealth and more than 60 percent of that in land,
depending on the assessment method.
Most capital gains are land-value
gains. The big players do not want their profits in rent,
which is taxed as ordinary income, but in capital gains,
taxed at a lower rate. To benefit as much as
possible from today's real estate bubble of fast rising
land values they pledge a property's rent income to pay
interest on the debt for as much property as they can buy
with as little of their own money as possible. After
paying off the mortgage lender they sell the property and
get to keep the "capital gain".
This price appreciation is actually a
"land gain," that is, it's not from providing start-up
capital for new enterprises, but from sitting on a rising
asset already in place, the land. Its value rises
because neighbourhoods are upgraded, mortgage money is
ample, and rezoning is favorable from farmland on the
outskirts of cities to gentrification of the core to
create high-income residential developments. The
potential capital gain can be huge. That's why developers
are willing to pay their mortgage lenders so much of
their rent income, often all of it.
SUMMARY
For hundreds of years property's value
has been calculated by discounting its flow of rental
income at the going rate of interest. The lower the
interest rate, the higher the price a given rental stream
will justify -- or as property owners express it, the more
years' rent a property will bring. What is so striking
about land values today is that they are rising for reasons
independent of their earnings stream. The major new
consideration is their prospect for future "capital" (that
is, land-price) gains. In sum, the ultimate aim of real
estate investors no longer is so much to seek income --
most of which is pledged to their bankers as interest
payments on the property they acquire -- as much as to seek
property gains. Politically opportunites abound. Merely
changing zoning in New York City in the 1980s to allow
using commercial loft spaces for residential purposes had
the effect of multiplying asset values five or
tenfold.
Whether the gains come from selling
the property or from borrowing more money against it, the
essential phenomenon is the rapid growth in asset values
and real estate's uniquely favored tax treatment. That's
why investors choose real estate instead of bonds or
stocks, and much of the strategy underlying corporate
takeovers has followed the strategies they developed over
the past half century.
Nationwide the capital-gains
dimension needs to be incorporated into the rental revenue
statistics to measure real estate's total returns.
This sector's nearly complete success in
escaping the tax collector has placed an enormous tax
burden on everyone else. read the entire
article Mason Gaffney: Henry George 100
Years Later: The Great Reconciler
In 1879, George electrified the world by
identifying one underlying cause for two great economic
plagues:
- chronic poverty arising from insufficient
demand for labor, and
- cycles of boom and bust.
These twin plagues
arose from concentrated ownership of land, compounded by
land speculation. Large landowners and speculators
(often one and the same) held the best land idle or
underused, forcing labor onto marginal land and driving
down wages. Collapse of speculative land price bubbles
caused periodic slumps.
(By "land" George meant exclusive
rights to use natural resources in a specified territory.
It included mining, water, fishing, and timber rights,
road and rail rights-of way, and some patents. George
emphasized the high value and productivity of urban land,
which facilitated communication and trade. Today, we
would add to "land" such items as taxi medallions,
telecommunications licenses and pollution
"rights".)
George followed his analysis with a
plausible, practicable remedy: eliminate all taxes except
for a tax on land values. The "single tax," as it later
became known, would invigorate the economy by breaking up
large idle holdings, making land available to those who
would use it. And it would suck the air out of speculative
bubbles, damping the boom and bust cycle.
... read
the whole article Mason Gaffney: George's Economics of
Abundance: Replacing dismal choices with practical
resolutions and synergies
... Equity and
efficiency
George refutes the commonplace idea that we must
choose between equity and efficiency. This idea is
premised on identifying "equity" with price and rent
controls designed to help the poor against the rich; or
with counter-incentive progressive income taxation, with
its warping, suppressive effects. George rejects both
price controls and progressive income taxation, and
identifies a different tax policy that brings us both
equity and efficiency together. He
would untax productive activity, and instead base taxes
on land, in proportion to its value. This
combines the magic of justice with the magic of
incentive.
George's land tax promotes equity
toward the landless in at least four ways.
- One, it relieves them of taxes, to the
extent that landowners pay more;
- Two, it makes jobs by removing all tax
penalties from hiring workers, and also because the
land tax, a fixed charge, spurs landowners to use land
to earn cash to pay the taxes;
- Three, while jobs are generating new money
incomes, new production supplies more goods and
services. Those give substance to the money incomes,
precluding inflation such as poisoned the springs of
Keynesian "fiscal stimulus";
- Four, it offers the landless new chances to
acquire land themselves,as old owners
release surplus lands to the market.
... read the
whole article
Mason Gaffney: The
Taxable Capacity of Land
To stimulate building is also
to uphold and fortify the tax base, even though you do
not tax the new buildings directly. Some people fault the
"depressing" canyons of Manhattan, between the
skyscrapers. In my observation, it is not the canyons
that depress Manhattan. When the GM building went up,
Fortune Magazine reported it doubled the rents of stores
across the deep canyon so formed. Its spillover
effects were highly positive. What really depresses
Manhattan are rather the centenarian firetraps and the
activities they attract. They tend to downvalue other
lands nearby, eroding the tax base.
Consider the effect of
floorspace rentals on ground rents and land values.
Doubling floorspace rentals will more than double land
values, through a kind of leverage effect. That is
because all cash flows above a constant
amount required for the building will inure as ground
rents. The higgling and arbitrage of the market
will see to that. Once that constant is met, everything
above it goes to landownership as such, raising land
prices which are the land tax base.
When you observe cities
much, the positive neighborhood effects of replacing old
buildings with new are irresistible and contagious,
raising land prices all around. The converse is also
true: the negative neighborhood effects of letting old
junkers stand without replacement are depressive. Thus,
when you take the tax off new buildings, and put it on
the land under old tumbledowns, you kick off a general
process of revitalization that turns gloom into hope into
optimism: optimism that boosts land prices and the land
tax base.
There are three kinds of
slums.
- Type I slums develop on land in the
van of downtown expansion, on land held for a future
higher use. The speculators are milking the old
structures for any residual value. They don't much mind
when the tenants leave, and spare them the trouble of
an eviction when they want to sell or rebuild. That's
what they're in it for: the current use is
incidental.
- Type III slums (listed here out of
numerical order) develop on land that is no good, and
may never be, like floodplains and earthquake faults.
They also develop around abbatoirs, dumps, stockyards,
etc., although these are subject to change. In either
case, people are driven there by the inadequate
development of good land.
- Type II slums, our focus here, are
the most extensive. They occur on good or superior
residential land originally developed over fifty or a
hundred years ago. It may once have housed the upper
crust, but as the buildings aged without replacement
they "filtered down," and down, and down, until their
occupants began radiating negative neighborhood
effects. There comes a tipping point where the
neighborhood self- destructs cumulatively, because no
one wants to build new in a decayed, menacing
neighborhood. The renewal value of land is lost, the
tax base is lost, nothing remains but social and public
costs: a municipal disaster area. The city that fails
to renew itself on time is steering itself to this
fate, like Camden, the Bronx, East St. Louis, Benton
Harbor, MI, and Detroit.
That's the bad news. How do
you turn it around? When you drop buildings from the
property tax base, you change the arithmetic of
incentives, as we have discussed. Parachuting into the
middle of a slum is still hopeless, as before. Change
will come first to the fringes of the Type II slum, where
it merges into healthy neighborhoods. New development
likes to anchor onto healthy neighborhoods. Richard Hurd,
father of urban studies in America, taught us in 1902
that land values are marked by continuity in space. It's
still so. Fashions and technology change, but principles
last. Hope survives at the edge of the slum; land
there retains some renewal value. There is where you'll
first see change, because there is where the forces are
evenly balanced. Tip the forces for renewal, and there is
where it begins.
Once it begins, it proceeds
incrementally through the Type II slum. When it's
through, your oldest neighborhood has become your newest,
the cutting edge of progress, the showplace of the town.
That is how it has got to work; that is how it will work
when you exempt buildings and tax only land. When it is
through, you have a high tax base where now you have
nothing but fire and police calls.
... Read the
whole
article
Fred Foldvary: The Rent, the Whole Rent, and
Nothing but the Rent
Real-estate land rent and rentals arise from the
differing productivity of various sites: rent is the differential between the productivity
of a site relative to the least productive marginal
sites. This is the same as the "marginal product"
of land as used in economics. Buying
land for speculation anticipating higher future rentals
not paid for by the landowner can induce higher prices
for land that shifts the margin to inferior lands,
raising the rents on superior lands and lowering wages
set at the margin.... Read the whole
article
Fred E. Foldvary — The Ultimate Tax Reform: Public
Revenue from Land Rent
Some may wonder why anyone would own land if most of
the rent is taxed away. One would own land for the same
reason people rent land: in order to use it. Ownership
also gives the title holder rights of possession, the
ability to control the use of the site indefinitely.
Today there is also a speculative motive for owning
land, to profit from the increase in its price. With most
of the geo-rent tapped for public revenue, the
speculative motive would be dampened. That would benefit
the economy, since with a lower price of land, funds that
now go to buy land would instead go to build more capital
goods, hire more labor, or provide better training.
The tax on the geo-rent would be borne by the owner,
not the tenant. If a landlord, who was already charging
what the market could bear, tried to pass on the tax, he
would face vacancies. Some say that since the tax would
be invisible to renters, the link between using public
services and paying for them would be broken. But
productive public services increase the geo-rent, so that
link is there. If government revenue is wasted, then
indeed this does not generate rent, and a land value tax
without corresponding benefits would reduce land value.
Pressure for a productive use of public revenue would
come from the landowners more than from the tenants. But
that is no different than the situation today; poor folks
pay little or no income tax and no property tax, and
typically they get government assistance. This is an
argument not against the use of rent, but in favor of
privatizing government programs. In the private sector,
the link between ownership and control is stronger. ...
read the whole
document
Ted Gwartney: Estimating Land
Values
Not only is land rent a potentially important
source of public revenue, the tax on land is a means of
limiting excessive speculation in land prices. This would
ensure that the equal opportunity to be productive would
be available to all citizens. With limited money to
invest, people could invest in productive equipment and
wages, rather than in high land prices which produce no
additional tangible wealth. ...
THE SOURCE OF PUBLIC
REVENUE
What are the factors that cause land to have
market value and to whom does this market revenue
advantage properly belong? Land has market value for
three reasons:
- the limited supply and "natural" productivity
of the soil and natural resources,
- the publicly provided services, including
planning, improvements that increase the market value of
land and
- the growth of communities and peoples'
competitive demand for the exclusive use of prime
locations.
Land rent is the price that people and
businesses are willing to pay for the exclusive right to
possess and use a good land site for a period of time. For
example, people prefer to use sites of good location
because it gives them an advantage of spending less time in
travel by being near what they choose to do and where they
work. A businessman can sell more goods at a site where
many people pass each day, compared to a site where only a
few people would pass.
The collection of land rent should be
used as revenue, by the community for supplying public
needs. This returns the advantage an individual land
possessor receives from the exclusive use of a land site,
to the balance of the people who live within the community
and have allowed the land possessor the exclusive use of
the land site for the period of time.
ENVIRONMENTAL
PRESERVATION
It is the responsibility of the local communities
to insure that the market rent of land is collected for
public purposes. When a major part of
land rent is not collected, which is the case in most of
the world today, land title holders obtain rights to sell
the value of the public improvements which were made by
the whole community. The community added to the
market value to land by making improvements which
increases demand and rent for the land. The longer the
possessors hold the land out of use the greater will be
the bonus they obtain.
By prohibiting people from using good
land, the possessors force the premature use of other less
desirable land, which is more distant from the city. This
raises the cost of community improvements and the rental
value of the unused, but better located, land. This
precipitates the degradation of the rural environment by
using city land inefficiently -- and creates huge
unnecessary pressures on the natural
environment.
A problem that we face is that cities
throughout the world are spreading out and using land
prematurely which is not needed and should not be used.
That is because failure to collect land rent subsidizes the
waste of natural resources and clutters the environment.
Cities that collect the full rental value of land are more
compact and provide greater and less costly amenities for
their citizens.
Any moves to enact good government
principles without collecting the full market rent of the
land may result in a failure. People are guided by the
profit motive. When people can make a larger profit by
doing nothing, but keeping the land they possess out of use
for a long period of time, they will do so. When the
community collects the full market rent of land, they
eliminate the motive for keeping land out of efficient use,
because the unearned profit has been collected as public
revenue. ... Read the whole
article
Nic Tideman: The Case for Taxing Land
I. Taxing Land as Ethics and
Efficiency
II. What is Land?
III. The simple efficiency argument for
taxing land
IV. Taxing Land is Better Than
Neutral
V. Measuring the Economic Gains from
Shifting Taxes to Land
VI. The Ethical Case for Taxing
Land
VII. Answer to Arguments against Taxing
Land
There is a case for taxing land based on ethical
principles and a case for taxing land based on
efficiency principles. As a matter of logic,
these two cases are separate. Ethical
conclusions follow from ethical premises and
efficiency conclusions from efficiency
principles. However, it is natural for human
minds to conflate the two cases. It is easier to
believe that something is good if one knows that it is
efficient, and it is easier to see that something is
efficient if one believes that it is good.
Therefore it is important for a discussion of land
taxation to address both question of efficiency and
questions of ethics.
This monograph will first address the
efficiency case for taxing
land, because that is the less controversial
case. The efficiency case for taxing land has two
main parts. ...
To estimate the magnitudes of the impacts that
additional taxes on land would have on an economy, one
must have a model of the economy. I report on
estimates of the magnitudes of impacts on the U.S.
economy of shifting taxes to land, based on a
mathematical model that is outlined in the
Appendix.
The ethical case for
taxing land is based on two ethical premises:
...
The ethical case for taxing land ends with a
discussion of the reasons why recognition of the equal
rights of all to land may be essential for world
peace.
After developing the efficiency argument and the
ethical argument for taxing land, I consider a variety
of counter-arguments that have been offered against
taxing land. For a given level of other taxes, a
rise in the rate at which land is taxed causes a fall
in the selling price of land. It is sometimes
argued that only modest taxes on land are therefore
feasible, because as the rate of taxation on land
increases and the selling price of land falls, market
transactions become increasingly less reliable as
indicators of the value of land.
...
Another basis on which it is argued that greatly
increased taxes on land are infeasible is that if land
values were to fall precipitously, the financial system
would collapse. ...
Apart from questions of feasibility, it is
sometimes argued that erosion of land values from
taxing land would harm economic efficiency, because it
would reduce opportunities for entrepreneurs to use
land as collateral for loans to finance their
ideas. ...
.
Another ethical argument that is made against
taxing land is that the return to unusual ability is
“rent” just as the return to land is
rent. ...
But before developing any of these arguments, I
must discuss what land is.
The quantity of land that is employed in any
year reflects the response of land speculation to taxes
on land. ... Read the whole
article
Nic Tideman: Land Taxation and Efficient
Land Speculation
...Abstract from the continuous divisibility of
land and suppose that land comes in "sites." At each moment in time, each site is in one of three
states:
1. Suitable for agriculture.
2. Suitable for housing.
3. Suitable for commercial activity.
While each site can be
used for any activity, the net return will be greatest if
it is used for the activity for which it is suited,
provided that it remains in that activity long enough to
fully amortize the associated capital that is
state-specific, durable and immobile. What could
keep a site from remaining in an activity long enough to
amortize the associated capital is that from time to time a
site makes a transition from state 1 to state 2 or from
state 2 to state 3. These transitions are imperfectly
predictable. When a transition from state 2 to state 3
occurs unexpectedly, the course of action that maximizes
the net return to the site may entail scrapping prematurely
the residential structure built there and building a
commercial structure. In such an instance, one may be able
to look backward and say that it would have been better not
to have built the residential structure at all, but rather
to have left the site in agricultural use until the
transition to state 3 occurred. However, such reckoning can
affect investment decisions only to the extent that
transitions can be foreseen....
In addition to the land management
motive for seeking to foresee transitions, there is a
speculative motive, which differs in form and magnitude.
While the land management motive is concerned with the
possibility that capital will be wasted on a site that is
soon to undergo a transition in state, the speculative
motive arises from the gains to be made from owning title
to land at the time that its better future prospects become
generally known.
People differ in the costs they incur
in ascertaining whether the signs present at a particular
site herald a pending transition, and how soon it will
occur. Therefore those who have a comparative advantage in
foreseeing the transitions tend to do the speculating. A
speculator will incur the cost of ascertaining the
significance of the signs at a particular site if, based on
that speculator's experience, the probability of a
transition given the signs, multiplied by the increase in
the current value of the property if there is a transition,
is greater than the sum of the cost of making the
determination, the transactions costs of acquiring the site
and the net cost of holding the site until its future
prospects become generally known. The activity of
speculation yields a normal expected private return to the
funds spent on speculation, with particularly skillful
speculators also obtaining unusual returns to their unique
talents.
The speculative
return from foreseeing future transitions arises from
holding title to land when pending transitions become
generally known. This return is a purely private return,
with no corresponding social return, since the land will
increase in value whether or not any given speculator holds
it. The land-management return
from foreseeing future transitions, on the other hand,
arises from knowing not to employ capital on sites where
future transitions will cause the capital to depreciate
prematurely. This is a social return, since it
involves improving the allocation of scarce resources.
There is no necessary connection between the private return
and the social return. ...
The possibility that there could be no
social gain from an activity that produced private
speculative gains was recognized by Paul Samuelson (1957,
p. 209), in a discussion of the effects of uncertainty on
intertemporal price equilibrium
...
In the U.S., a further consideration
that causes development to be postponed is the possibility
of avoiding Federal income taxes on increases in land value
by including the land in one's estate. Estate taxes are
paid according to the actual value of the land (as they
would be paid on the proceeds if the land were sold), but
one's heirs pay taxes only on the increase in value after
it leaves the estate, so that taxes on the increase in
value during one's lifetime can be avoided.
An additional social cost of land
speculation was elucidated by Harry Gunnison Brown (1927).
He pointed out that when it is possible to profit from land
speculation, land will tend to be acquired by those who
have the most extreme beliefs about how much it will rise
in value, and that such beliefs will generally be more
optimistic than is warranted. Economists have given the
name "winner's curse" (Milgrom
& Weber, 1982) to the phenomenon that those who bid the
most tend to bid too much. The winner's
curse can cause the whole land market to become dominated
by persons with extreme beliefs about future rises in
value, creating an artificial scarcity of land for current
use, as those who have land wait for illusory future
opportunities. The winner's curse is thereby shifted to
society.
The next section discusses the features of various
taxes on land, and in particular their capacity to remove
the incentive for inefficient land speculation. ...
Read the whole
article
Bill Batt: Painless
Taxation
Abstract Real tax reform could
do away with those taxes that are resented by the large
proportion of our population. We could replace all taxes
on wages and on interest by instead taxing economic rent.
Rent is windfall income; it is income that arises not
from the efforts of any person or corporation; it comes
about as a surplus gain from common social enterprise.
There is ample moral warrant for society to lay claim to
that which it has created, as well as to that which no
individual or party has earned. Analysis increasingly
makes clear that economic rent in all its forms is far
larger than official government figures indicate; in fact
it is likely sufficient to supplant all current taxes on
labor and capital (wages and interest) which are
acknowledged to have so many negative effects. Recovering
economic rent in all its manifestations by taxing its
various bases actually can foster economic performance
and yield other benefits that make it the natural source
of revenue for governments. Such a tax is essentially
painless. ...
Any tax on capital has its downside effects, so that
taxing savings causes people to save less, taxing
consumption causes people to buy less, and taxing
buildings causes people to build less. The result is that
economists as well as businessmen usually frown upon
taxing capital. Another alternative is to tax labor, but
it is even more widely understood that taxing labor
normally discourages people from working as much as they
would in the absence of a tax. From this comes sentiment
against taxing labor, even though for want of any
alternative, people have today commonly come to accept it
as a necessity. But electing to tax labor, just as for
taxing capital, forecloses a discussion of the virtues of
taxing land — not necessarily land as earth, but
rather land as location. Yet land rent is the most
attractive tax base of all, as rent is not earned; it is
windfall income, entirely the result of being well
situated in any market of scarce natural resources and
where community demand (rather than one's own efforts)
leads to an appreciation of that land's price. To
be sure many people have learned to position themselves
in situations where a land's market value is likely to
rise — indeed these people come to think of
themselves as astute investors. But the fact is that that
market gain is not of their own doing at all; it is the
result of common enterprise creating a surplus that comes
to settle on land sites. An investment in land, in any
form it might take, is speculation in greater or lesser
degree. ...
The Possibility of Land (Rent)
Taxation
The key to understanding how taxing various forms of
land conform to sound tax theory comes with an
appreciation of the importance of economic rent. Largely
discarded in 20th century economic analysis, rent is the
price for the use of land. Just as the price of labor is
paid in wages and the price of capital is paid in
interest, land rent is the unearned increment that
attaches to land in the form of a surplus when its price
is not paid by its users. All taxes, ultimately, come out
of rent; however, by collecting revenue from other
sources, the rent is left to settle in ever increasing
encrustations on land sites, i.e., capitalized,
ultimately raising their market price. In so doing, these
land prices are distorted so that their optimal use is
not secured.
Examples of such distortion are not difficult to
identify. Consider, first of all, the use of locations in
our urban environments, many of which are underused while
prospective entrepreneurs are driven to second-best
locations because titleholders opt to let the rent
accrete and passively raise their market price. Land
speculation is rife most of all in instances where there
is a great disparity between the tax rate on these sites
and the rate of rent appreciation. When the holding costs
of ownership are nominal, there is no incentive for
improving them or selling to others who will, and urban
environments suffer as a result. Another example is rent
that collects to the electromagnetic spectrum, making it
attractive for owners of electronic media, communications
networks and so on, to rely on returns to their
investments even when the resource itself is sparsely
used. So also with the time slots for take-offs and
landings at airports. These opportunities are respected
as private property, even while they gain in market value
in response to the general traffic volume of the
facility. This occurs regardless whether the particular
airlines use their slots or not. London Mayor Ken
Livingstone has proposed to tax the rent from Heathrow
and Gatwick both for their revenue advantage and to
assure their more optimal use.[7] One could go
on, pointing to any number of instances where economic
rent is available to be had for the support of public
services in lieu of conventional taxes which we recognize
as destructive in their effects.[8] It is not
surprising that when pressed even conventional
(neoclassical) economists are often willing to concede
that the best possible tax of all is one placed on land
rent.[9] ... read the whole
article
Bill Batt: Who Says
Cities are Poor? They Just Don't Know How to Tax Their
Wealth!
One could argue that the failure to tax every bit of
economic rent that accretes to land sites also has
destructive consequences, although this is somewhat open
to debate. Classical economists agree that rent
collection ought to be at least the sum of inflation plus
interest, otherwise the public is facilitating
speculation in ways that distorts urban configurations
even more than they constitute an inequity. But land
sites frequently rise in market price far more than the
rate of inflation, especially in times (as is perhaps
true today) that a "bubble" in an economic cycle is in
full flower. Some municipalities, especially on the east
and west coasts of US, are today claiming to have
increases in housing prices of as high as 20 percent per
annum, a fever that surely will not last and will be
especially destructive when it collapses.[19] Land
values are what create that bubble; buildings are subject
to continuing depreciation just like cars, computers,
refrigerators or any other manufactured (capital) item.
Recovering the economic rent reduces and perhaps even
eliminates the speculative bubbles and swings that (some
argue) account for economic cycles, fostering stability
and regularity in economic planning and development that
make for improved financial health to all.
This reality brings into stark relief the choices
which local political leaders have. They may suggest
increasing taxes on economic rent (i.e., on land value)
or recognize that most property owners are counting on
treating their homes and other property not as places to
live and work so much as investments and then lament the
poverty of their cities. Owners expect to reap a gain
from their property when they sell, and they are often
positioned to make any threat to that entitlement
politically unpalatable. Farmers sometimes regard selling
their farms as their retirement security. Homeowners sell
with the expectation that this gain will provide them the
means to enter long term end-of-life facilities if
necessary. Heirs also oppose that recapture just as with
a reverse mortgage. But for every long-term property
owner that walks away with a lifetime's benefit of
increased rent attached to a land title, there are just
as many — if not more — young households or
emerging businesses that are prohibited from acquiring a
property because of the prohibitively expensive costs. In
this sense, a title to a socially created stream of
rental benefits constitutes a monopoly privilege to an
unearned windfall gain for a lucky few. It is both unjust
and is socially and economically destructive to the
greater good. ... read
the whole article
Mason Gaffney: Property Tax: Biases and
Reforms
What happens when a state radically slashes its
property tax? Michiganders are saying they must wait and
see, but there is no need for that: California can show
you 17 years of experience. To read your future, just
study our past. Here is what has happened since
California passed Proposition 13 in 1978.
...
Our fall of income per capita is
greater than appears from a purely monetary measure. Real
pay (in contrast $) has fallen more because of the drastic
rise in shelter prices. In San Francisco, shelter takes 50
percent of the median income, with many other cities,
especially coastal ones, not far behind. It is unusual to
find livable quarters for less than $600 per month. The
median home price rose 163 percent during the 1980s to
$258,000 (that is just the median - the mean is higher).
These prices are part of the C.O.L. of all renters and new
buyers, a part not fully incorporated in standard CPI
measures. ...
It should give one
pause. It is the expectable consequence of what the voters
did. They rejected the concept of taxing inert wealth in
favor of the alternative: taxing liquidity, cash flow,
work, production and commerce. The predictable
result has been to inhibit economic activity, and encourage
holding wealth inert and stagnant. They turned property
from a functional concept into a sacred one; from a
commission to be enterprising, hire people, produce goods,
and pay taxes into a welfare entitlement.
...
California had a construction boom in the late
1980s, but it was not healthy. It was marked by extreme
scatter and instability. Downtown L.A. was to become a
great new financial capital. But it now has nearly the
highest office vacancy rate in the U.S., with of course a
high rate of builder bankruptcies. Speculative builders
were led on to over-build, in part by anticipated higher
land rents and prices. This Lorelei effect was magnified
by national income-tax provisions luring on speculative
builders. But we have to ask why California fell harder
than other states, even with the object-lessons of the
oil states in clear view.
David Shulaman tersely summarized the distributive effects of Prop. 13 as he
left us to become Chief Equity Strategist for Salamon
Brothers in Manhattan: "it breached the
social compact." ...
Between 1945-50, one-eighth of all new
businesses started in the U.S. were established in L.A.
They were small, creative, flexible, miscellaneous, and too
varied and dynamic to classify. No Linnaeus could sort them
in static conventional boxes; they were the despair
traditional economic geographers and base theorists who
were at a loss to explain the region's thriving economy.
The new Angelenos stayed and started producing everything
for themselves, some things previously imported, and others
never seen before.
Eastern firms established branch
plants. Top eastern students came to California's great
university system and stayed behind to take jobs and make
careers here, then sent their children through California's
excellent public schools. California became famous for
supporting outstanding higher education, highways, water
supplies, public health, public safety, and other public
services, all without repelling business by taxation. There
was a regional "El Dorado Effect" as demand and supply grew
together. Growing local demand allowed for economies of
scale serving local markets. Food and shelter were cheap
and abundant. Land for business was accessible, providing a
basis for the California self-contained phenomenon. A
"continental tilt" developed in both interest rates and
wage rates, drawing in eastern capital and labor.
Why is that not continuing
today?
The invisible, pervasive change is due
to Proposition 13, which makes it possible to hold land at
negligible tax cost. In 1945 land was
taxed at 3 percent every year, building a fire under
holdouts to turn their land to use. Today that same tax
cost is well below 1 percent. Using Gwartney's Rule of
Thumb (see below under #2, A, "Reassessing Land
Frequently") it is about 1/8 of 1 percent: a rate of 1
percent applied to 1/8 of the true
value.
Landowners are only taxed now if they
use their land to hire people and produce something useful.
Then they are confronted by the drag of our high business
and employment and sales taxes, necessitated by the fall of
property taxes. A handful of oligopolistic landowners
control most of the market; small businesses are squeezed
out. This helps us segue from being at the cutting edge of
industrial progress to a third-world economy - from the NH
model to the AL model - with little relief in sight.
....
Does this help you understand why
California landowners are now so slow to adapt to new
demands? In 1945 the assessors were building fires under
landowners, so they sought new strategies to meet new
circumstances. Today there remains a weak incentive to
improve to improve property: tax collectors generally cost
them money when they make improvements. Sit still, lie low,
hire no one, hang on, produce nothing, and your holding
costs are negligible.... Read the whole
article
Ted Gwartney: A Free Market Strategy to
Reduce Sprawl
- Unused land is far more abundant than we
realize.
- End the Public Subsidy of Land Speculation and
Sprawl
- Counterproductive growth limitations and
regulations should be abolished.
- A Strategy for Urban Renewal
- A Strategy for Economic
Development
- Public Finance by Self-Financing
End the Public
Subsidy of Land Speculation and
Sprawl
... If land holders can produce a higher return on
investment by not using land for productive purposes but
rather hold it for a higher price from those willing and
able to pay the higher price in the future, there is a
flaw in public policy. Public policy thereby gives
speculative, nonproductive investment a higher return
than productive investment. Sprawl is subsidized by taxes
on production and distribution and the failure to
recapture the benefits resulting from public
improvements. If we choose to end this subsidy, we would
reduce sprawl.
One example that I know is that of a
friend who bought land within the city but did nothing with
it. I asked him why he put good money into an investment
that had no visible return? He replied that, by holding the
land for future sale or development, his long term return,
in capital gains would exceed 18% annually. If he built a
building on the site now, his long term return would only
be 12% annually, including both net income plus capital
gains. Why should he use his land now when it would be more
profitable for him to not use it, but to hold it for a
larger future gain?
Most major cities have a substantial
amount of fully serviced but unused or underused land
sites. It is estimated that 38% of the land area in Los
Angeles is unused, 30% in New York City and 25% in
Washington, D.C. Intercity sites are bypassed because land
speculators receive a greater benefit by ignoring the
highest and best use of land sites. A greater profit is
made when development is delayed and the land price
increases to higher levels. But building within existing
developed areas uses the existing and underused
infrastructure, roads, transit, public facilities, and
services. Sprawl requires new expenditures on public goods
and services, more government, more taxes, more
dislocation. ...
Counterproductive growth limitations
and regulations should be abolished.
Property taxes should not be levied on
new construction or existing improvements, when the revenue
needed could be obtained from the land values created and
maintained by the community.
The property tax could be shifted to
reduce the incentives for sprawl. If the property tax were
taken off urban buildings and focused on the land itself,
this would penalize land speculation and would reward
people who build on their land. Thus land speculation,
which promotes a "leap frog" development out of the city
and into the surrounding countryside, would decrease. The
proposed shift from traditional property tax to a "land
value tax" would penalize land speculation and encourage
urban redevelopment. Removing the tax on buildings makes
them cheaper to construct, renovate and operate, and more
affordable to buy or rent. Urban construction creates urban
jobs. Capital and labor both benefit. ...
One means that has long been available but not
brought into general use is to exempt buildings from the
real estate tax and begin to impose an annual tax on land
sites that makes holding land off the market for
speculation a costly proposition. An annual fee on land
should be set near what the land site alone would yield
if rented by the owner to the highest bidder. Think of
how this would change the behavior of land owners. If I
owned a parcel of land with a rental value of $6,000 a
year and that was near what the city charged me as my
annual fee, my return on investment as a land speculator
would be greatly reduced. In order to generate positive
cash flow I would either develop the land myself or put
it on the market so that someone else would develop it.
At the same time, if my tax rate on the building I
constructed on the land was zero, my incentive is to
construct a building that maximizes my cash flow (i.e.,
to develop the parcel to its highest and best use in the
market). At minimum, land prices would stabilize and the
increase in land brought onto the market would be
somewhat offset by increased demand. Land prices to
builders would tend to begin to fall over time....
Read the whole
article
Karl Williams: Land Value Taxation: The
Overlooked But Vital Eco-Tax
I. Historical overview
II. The problem of sprawl
III. Affordable and efficient public
transport
IV. Agricultural benefits
V. Financial concerns
VI. Conclusion: A greater
perspective
Appendix: "Natural Capitalism" -- A Case Study in
Blindness to Land Value Taxation
Synopsis
Land value taxation (LVT) has often been omitted
from the lists of natural resources for which eco-taxes
are being advocated. LVT provides strong financial
encouragement for land to be put to its optimal use and
will eliminate speculation on land, as occupants must pay
the full LVT whether the land is being fully utilised or
not. This leads to better land management, a reduction in
urban sprawl, less urban smothering of agricultural land,
and less farmland being pushed into
hinterland.
LVT makes the investment in resource-efficient
infrastructure affordable because the resulting enhanced
land values are "recycled" back into public coffers. One
particular application of LVT to agricultural land
provides much-needed financial incentives for organic
farming. Unlike other ecotaxes which "sow the seeds of
their own revenue demise," LVT actuallyincreases over
time as our environment is enhanced and is thus a stable
revenue base.
This paper argues that the LVT assessment process
shifts and refines our focus from monitoring human
activity onto our use and abuse of natural resources, as
any responsible form of stewardship should. It suggests
that only if land users are prepared to pay the full cost
of utilising resources should private resource holding be
permitted.
"The depletion of natural resources and the
despoliation of nature is due to a single reason: the
failure properly to measure the rental value of all of
nature's resources, and to make the users pay the
community for the benefits they receive." F. Harrison,
"The Corruption of Economics" ... read the entire
article
Nic Tideman: The Structure of an
Inquiry into the Attractiveness of A Social Order Inspired
by the Ideas of Henry George
I. Ethical Principles
A. People own themselves and therefore own what
they produce.
B. People have obligations to share equally the
opportunities that are provided by
nature.
C. People are free to interact with other
competent adults on whatever terms are mutually
agreed.
D. People have obligations to pay the costs
that their intrusive behaviors impose on
others.
II. Ethical Questions
A. What is the relationship between justice (as
embodied in the ethical principles) and community (or
peace or harmony)?
B. How are the weak to be provided
for?
C. How should natural opportunities be
shared?
D. Who should be included in the group among
whom rent should be shared equally?
E. Is there an obligation to compensate those
whose presently recognized titles to land and other
exclusive natural opportunities will lose value when rent
is shared equally?
F. Can a person who is occupying a per capita
share of land reasonably ask to be left undisturbed
indefinitely on that land?
G. What is the moral status of "intellectual
property?"
H. What standards of environmental respect can
people reasonably require of others?
I. What forms of land use control are
consistent with the philosophy of Henry
George?
III. Efficiency
Questions
A. Would public collection of the rent of land
provide enough revenue for an appropriate public
sector?
B. How much revenue could public collection of
rent raise?
C. Is it possible to assess land with sufficient
accuracy?
D. How much growth can a community expect if it
shifts taxes from improvements to land?
E. To what extent does the benefit that one
community receives from shifting taxes from buildings
to land come at the expense of other
communities?
F. What is the impact of land taxes on land
speculation?
G. How, if at all, does the impact of shifting the
source of public revenue to land change if it is a
whole nation rather than just a community that makes
the shift?
H. Is there a danger that the application of Henry
George's ideas would lead to a world of
over-development?
I. How would natural resources be managed
appropriately if they were regarded as the common
heritage of humanity? Read
the whole
article
Henry George: How to Help the
Unemployed (1894)
May it not be seen, from our
greatest cities to our newest territories, in the
speculation which has everywhere been driving up the
price of land -- that is to say, the toll that the active
factor in all production must pay for permission to use
the indispensable passive factor [land]. Across
the street from the City Hall of Chicago, where 1,400
men, "the great majority Americans by birth and almost
all of them voters," have been this winter sleeping in
the stone corridors, stands the Chamber of Commerce
Building, thirteen stories high. This great building cost
$800,000. The lot which it covers is worth over
$1,000,000! A few blocks from where the New York World is today distributing free
bread, land has been sold since the bread distribution
began at the rate of over $12,000,000 an acre! As for the
remotest outskirts, who has not heard of the mad rush for
the Cherokee Strip? ...
These recurring spasms of business
stagnation; these long-drawn periods of industrial
depression, common to the civilized world, do not come from
our treatment of money; are not caused and are not to be
cured by changes of tariffs. Protection is a robbery of
labor, and what is called free trade would give some
temporary relief, but speculation in land would only set in
the stronger, and at last labor and capital would again
resist, by partial cessation, the blackmail demanded for
their employment in production, and the same round would be
run again. There is but one remedy, and
that is what is now known as the single-tax -- the
abolition of all taxes upon labor and capital, and of all
taxes upon their processes and products, and the taking of
economic rent, the unearned increment which now goes to the
mere appropriator, for the payment of public expenses.
Charity can merely demoralize and pauperize, while
that indirect form of charity, the attempt to artificially
"make work" by increasing public expenses and by charity
woodyards and sewing-rooms, is still more dangerous. If, in
this sense, work is to be made, it can be made more quickly
by dynamite and kerosene.
But there is no need for charity; no
need for "making work." All that is needed is to remove the
restrictions that prevent the natural demand for the
products of work from availing itself of the natural
supply. Remove them today, and every unemployed man in the
country could find for himself employment tomorrow, and his
"effective demand" for the things he desires would infuse
new life into every subdivision of business and industry,
even that of the dentist, the preacher, the magazine
writer, or the actor.
The country is
suffering from "scarcity of employment." But let anyone
to-day attempt to employ his own labor or that of others,
whether in making two blades of grass grow where one grew
before, or in erecting a factory, and he will at once meet
the speculator to demand of him an unnatural price for the
land he must use, and the tax-gatherer to fine him for his
act in employing labor as if he had committed a
crime. The common-sense way to
cure "scarcity of employment" is to take taxes off the
products and processes of employment and to impose in their
stead the tax that would end speculation in
land.
But, it will be said, this is not
quick enough. On the contrary, it is quicker than anything
else. Even the public recognition of its need, by but a
part of the intelligence and influence that is now devoted
to charity appeals and schemes, would have such an effect
upon the speculative price of land as to at once set labor
and capital to work.
Read the entire article
Bill Batt: The
Nexus of Transportation, Economic Rent, and Land
Use
... capital investments affect the market value of
locational sites by conveying rent to those in any way
benefitting from the service. That rent accruing to
proximate sites and can easily recaptured to pay off the
debt service of project construction. Typically rent
collection is ignored, however, left instead in the hands
of titleholders whose sites are serviced by the
infrastructure investment. This drives speculation in
land, with all the negative effects it brings both
economically and politically. In fact the rent created by
capital investment in transportation can be enormous.
- One nine-mile stretch of
interstate highway in Albany, New York, costing $125
million to construct has yielded $3.8 billion in
increased land values within just two miles of its
corridor in the 40 years of its
existence.(27)
This is a thirty-fold return in a timespan typically used
for bond repayment!
- The Washington Metro created increments in
land value along much of the 101-mile system under of
construction in 1980 that easily exceeded $3.5 billion,
compared with the $2.7 billion of federal funds invested
in Metro up until that time.(28) No doubt the return is far greater
today.
The component of transportation costs constituting
capital expenditure can and should be recaptured through
the collection of land rent since it accounts for the
creation of that value particular to proximate locational
sites. ... read the
whole article
Bill Batt: Stemming
Sprawl: The Fiscal Approach
The differentials in land values are profound, even
more than most people realize. In 1995, in the small city
of Ithaca, New York, the highest quintile of land had a
value of over $56,000 per acre in the downtown center,
whereas the lowest quintile only a mile away falls to
less than $3,000.[14] Large city
centers have far higher site prices. Even in Polk County,
Iowa (which includes Des Moines), in the middle of
cornfields where I did a study two years ago, the highest
urban value land site was $31.3 million per acre, which
quickly declined to about $20,000 per acre only about a
mile away. In the spring of 1998, one land parcel (the
building was to be razed) of less than an acre in New
York City's Times Square and split in two pieces by
Broadway was sold by Prudential Life to Disney for
roughly $240 million.[15] To take
another instance, a nine-acre tract on the East River in
New York City occupied by an obsolete power plant was
purchased by Mort Zuckerman to build high-rise
condominiums two years ago. The sale price was in the
neighborhood of $680 million and would have been higher
were it not for some enormous costs associated with the
demolition of the old structures.[16] It should be
noted that the overwhelming proportion of land value is
in cities; relatively speaking, the site values of
peripheral lands, typically used for agriculture and
timber growth, are negligible. Land values are high in
urban areas because, over time, rent accrues to a site.
Each improvement in proximity to a property parcel
enhances the value of all other parcels. This makes even
unimproved sites attractive objects for speculation,
particularly when land sites surrounding it are to be
improved by adding either transportation service or new
structures. One nine-mile stretch of interstate highway
in Albany, New York, costing $125 million to construct,
has yielded $3.8 billion in increased land values
(constant dollars) within just two miles of its corridor
in the forty years of its existence.[17] This is a
thirty-fold return in a time span typically used for bond
repayment! The Washington Metro created increments in
land value along much of the 101-mile system completed by
1980 that easily exceeded $3.5 billion, compared with the
$2.7 billion of federal funds invested in Metro up until
that time.[18] Any major
building construction project, private or public, will
have a similar effect on adjacent land sites.
Differentials in land value can have a profound effect on
decisions made by titleholders, either positively by
inducing appropriate development in urban cores or
negatively by giving monopoly titleholders power to hold
sites out of use for long-term speculative gain. Such
decisions of course determine the character of urban
configurations and society as well. ... read the whole article
Bill Batt: How Our
Towns Got That Way (1996 speech)
Indeed the most widespread notion of property
ownership, especially in realms where Roman law had left
no legacy, was title in usufruct, meaning title to
use. But that meaning has gradually given way to the
prevailing conception of title in fee simple, even though
legal constraints have grown to curtail abuses of such
ownership and are even seen sometimes as assaults on it.
Krueckeberg notes that as many as nine kinds of property
rights have been distinguished:
- possession,
- use,
- alienation (the power to give
away),
- consumption,
- modification,
- destruction,
- management,
- exchange, and
- profit taking.
From the first
application of the land law of the New England settlers
there has been a gradual extension of private control over
land titles first to simple use, then the right to benefit,
and ultimately "to the idea of gain made by selling. Land
speculation, which was to spread across the continent,
radically transformed New England's democratic town
pattern." Concurrent with this spreading application
of titles in fee simple has come changes in the meaning of
the word property, a term which, although employed in the
Fourth and Fifth Amendments of the U.S. Constitution, was
amplified only during the second half of the 19th century.
The notion of land as a commodity has had pernicious
effects on the course of our whole
civilization. ...
read the whole article Weld Carter:
A
Clarion Call to Sanity, to Honesty, to
Justice (1982)
In our economy, land is a ready object
of speculation, and its value is constantly reflecting this
evil. What happens in a rising market, the up side of a
business cycle, is that investors see rising prices in land
as indicative of a boom. Thereupon, they try to increase
their holdings in such land, only to discover that their
present returns will not pay for the present costs of land;
the current price of land is not based on what the yield of
that land is today, but on what it is projected to be two
or three years from now. The difference tends to increase
until a point is reached where the imarginal buyer of land
suddenly finds himself unable to meet the rising costs to
which he has subjected himself. With bankruptcy threatening
him or having already been forced upon him, the land passes
from his hands, and the market temporarily becomes
overpriced. The bankruptcies increase, and ultimately land
values are brought back to levels which represent current
productivity, at which point the new boom will have
started.
In 1933, the University of Chicago
published a book by Homer Hoyt
entitled One Hundred Years of Land Values in
Chicago. This monumental study consists in 7 chapters,
of which each of the first five describes one of the five
major business cycles of the period in great
detail.
What was so outstanding about Hoyt's
book was its compelling confirmation of George's analysis,
some thirty-five years after George's death in 1897! What
is even more significant is Hoyt's handling of his data in
chapters six and seven, the balance of the study. In these
two chapters, he selects some sixteen events which not only
are present in each cycle, but which occur in the same
order in each cycle.
Mr. Hoyt concluded with the usual
caveat: that the mere fact that this sequence is observed
this many times does not guarantee that it will ever happen
again; which is to say that we can never prove truth, we
can only fail to disprove it.
The
graphic rendition of one such cycle appearing on the
following page was devised by John Monroe, the Director
of the Commerce and Industry Division of the Chicago
Henry George School of Social Science. For classroom use,
Mr. Monroe had set up a large magnetized blackboard with
a large inverted "U"; the sixteen items of the figure
were described on sixteen magnetized chips, which were
shuffled and distributed along the participants. The
author once had a class of five company presidents; after
defining the task, he never spoke during the exercise.
The individual members had sole control as to the place
on the curve where each chip belonged. It was thrilling
to see and hear the discussion and the ultimate
positioning of the individual chips. At completion, they
matched precisely the historically-based results of Hoyt.
Five converts, one of whom had been the President both of
Chicago's Real Estate Board and of its Building Managers
Association, as well as a trustee of the University of
Chicago, walked out of that session.
A Case History of Five Major Booms and Busts
1830-1933
1. Machine techniques, production methods
improved
2. Population begins to spurt up
3. Shortage of housing, office
& commercial space first felt
4. Rents begin to rise.
5. Selling prices of old buildings begin to
advance
6. Vacant lot purchases begin to rise
7. Rate of new construction begins to rise
sharply
8. Credit eases to stimulate volume of new
building
9. Rapid growth of population projected far into
the future
10. Prices of tracts near settled areas advance
rapidly to peak.
11. Large tracts subdivided beyond needs of
immediate development
12. Lavish public expenditures
13. Rate of population growth falls off
14. Vacancies reappear
15. Rise in rents slackens
16. Volume of building construction at peak.
17. Asking prices of land advance in face of fewer
land sales
18. Financial institutions continue loans on peak
values in face of lessened construction
19. Holders of 2nd mortgages begin to foreclose
with faith in 1st mortgages
20. Stock market crash
21. Unemployment mounts to peak; wages down
22. Increased movement of population to small city
or farm; doubling up in city
23. Vacancies mount to peak in houses, apartments,
offices, stores; industrial rents down
24. Interest charges high in proportion to net
rents
25. Taxes high in proportion to net rents
26. Second mortgage holders wiped out in flood of
first mortgage foreclosures
27. Bank failures mount; loaded with real-estate
"frozen assets."
28. Volume of new building at bottom
29. Subdividing stopped; most vacant land not
salable at any price
30. Construction costs at lowest point
source: Homer Hoyt: One Hundred Years of Land
Values in Chicago, Copyright University of Chicago
Press, 1933
|
There are banks which have gone under
supporting rising land prices, loaning money on land at
speculative price levels. The answer is
not to rescue those banks; it is to rid ourselves of the
fundamental process of speculation in land
values.
The wringing out of land speculation
from the dynamics of economics will remove that
unacknowledged offence which has so labored the economic
profession and the public at large. As Henry George
discovered and as Homer Hoyt so brilliantly depicted
speculative land prices as the cause of this bitter cycle,
so will its removal rid society of this hitherto hidden
defect. It will put the land market on a current value
basis and eliminate the terrible risks to which that market
has always been subject in the past.
The reason for such speculation under
the present practices is obvious. All products of labor are
subject to increases or decreases depending on supply and
demand. When an oversupply of any commodity begins to rear
its ugly head, prices tend downward and production is
thereby lessened until there is a contrary swing upward.
Land, on the other hand, is of fixed supply. Nothing man
does can increase or decrease the amount of land, and
therefore that brake that operates in the field of
production does not apply to land values and
prices.
Just think of the social benefits that
would accrue to a society that could, at a stroke, rid
itself of the potential hazards to which all prior
societies have been so subject. Production will then occur
on a steadily rising level, demand increases as the
well-being of society improves, new techniques develop, new
inventions are made, and all these will be benefits to the
community as a whole, and not just to the land-owners as in
the past. ... read the
whole essay Weld Carter: An Introduction to Henry
George
In addition, George differentiated sharply between
land itself and the products -- or wealth, as he termed
them -- which labor made from the land. "In producing
wealth, labor, with the aid of natural forces, but works
up, into the forms desired, pre-existing matter, and, to
produce wealth, must, therefore, have access to this
matter and to these forces -- that is to say, to land.
The land is the source of all wealth. It is the mine from
which must be drawn the ore that labor fashions. It is
the substance to which labor gives the form."
George saw, as between land and
products, certain elementary differences. "In every
essential, land differs from those things which... [are]
the product of human labor. ...It is the creation of God;
they are produced by man. It is fixed in quantity; they may
be increased illimitably. It exists, though generations
come and go; they in a little while decay and pass again
into the elements."
Having noted these differences, George proceeded
to use them as the basis for his examination of related
areas of economics, such as speculation. When asked how
speculation worked, George responded that a distinction
must be made between speculation in land and speculation
in products.
Writing of industrial depressions, he
said, "When, with the desire to consume more, there coexist
the ability and willingness to produce more, industrial and
commercial paralysis cannot be charged either to
overproduction or to overconsumption. Manifestly, the
trouble is that production and consumption cannot meet and
satisfy each other .
"How does this inability arise? It is
evidently and by common consent the result of speculation.
But of speculation in what?
"Certainly not of speculation in
things which are the products of labor ...for the effect of
speculation in such things, as is well shown in current
treatises that spare me the necessity of illustration, is
simply to equalize supply and demand, and to steady the
interplay of production and consumption by an action
analogous to that of a fly-wheel in a machine." In
other words, the tendency of speculation in products is to
increase the demand for products and therefore to increase
the price of products. This increased price will induce
more production, which, increasing the supply, will tend to
lower the price. Throughout this cycle, there has been a
stimulating effect on production in general.
He continued, "Therefore, if
speculation be the cause of these industrial depressions,
it must be speculation in things not the production of
labor, but yet necessary to the exertion of labor in the
production of wealth -- of things of fixed quantity; that
is to say, it must be speculation in
land."
How can this be? How can speculation
in land cause industrial depression? George explains,
"...that there is a connection between the rapid
construction of railroads and industrial depression, anyone
who understands what increased land values mean, and who
has noticed the effect which the construction of railroads
has upon land speculation, can easily see. Wherever a
railroad was built or projected, lands sprang up in value
under the influence of speculation, and thousands of
millions of dollars were added to the nominal values which
capital and labor were asked to pay outright, or to pay in
installments, as the price of being allowed to go to work
and produce wealth. The inevitable result was to check
production. .."
The tendency of speculation in land is
similar to that of speculation in products; it increases
the demand for land and thereby increases the price of
land. However, here the similarity ends. The supply of land
is fixed; as successive units of land become priced beyond
the level at which labor and capital can profitably engage
in production, an increasing (though artificial) scarcity
of land develops. "The inevitable result was to check
production."
So, according to George, another
difference between land and products is that speculation in
products tends to stimulate production, whereas speculation
in land tends to check production....
read
the whole article Mason Gaffney:
Full
Employment, Growth And Progress On A Small Planet:
Relieving Poverty While Healing The Earth
One way of denying the basic problem
is to call it “unbalanced growth,” as in Orange
County, where people recognize it as too many jobs relative
to the housing supply. It is not the
“unbalance” that is the problem, though: how
can there be too many jobs? It is too little housing that
is the problem, driving demand eastwards up through Sta.
Ana Canyon, with its awful traffic bottleneck, to central
Riverside County, where it meets demand fleeing north from
San Diego.
Now weave this pattern of scattered
settlement into the whole system. It forces auto-dependency and truck-dependency,
multiplying the need for fuels, pushing up their prices,
and lowering the real wages of those who have to consume
them in larger quantities at higher prices. Much of what looks like self-indulgent consumption of
U.S. motorists is not joy-riding, but the forced
consumption of commutation, forced by scattered urban
sprawl, the product of land
speculation. Auto-apologists get this backwards, of
course, making joy-riding the cause and sprawl the effect.
...
3. Detailed causes of artificial scarcity of
land. Major forces holding labor off better lands are
the following (George, 1879):
a. “Land
Speculation,” conceived as holding land
primarily for its anticipated rise in value. Hasty readers and simplifiers of George see only
this point, overlooking items b-f,
following.
b. High demands of the rich
for land as a totem, for pleasure and prestige.
This demand rises with income, in greater proportion than
income.
c. Advance of labor-stinting,
land-lavishing technology, roughly associated with
economies of scale.
d. Tax bias. Taxes based on
work, production, exchange, coupled with preferential tax
treatment of landholding, land income, land gains, etc.,
create a powerful bias in favor of wasting land and
downsizing labor forces (Gaffney,
1999).
e. Lack of basic
infrastructure and public services, due to
constraints on the tax base
f. Overpricing and poor
service from natural monopolies. ...
read the whole article
Mason Gaffney: Land as a Distinctive Factor
of Production
Land values are hypersensitive to
discount rates
The sensitivity of present values to discount
rates increases as the value being discounted. Land
values are discounted from more remote future values than
are values of most capital, even most durable and "fixed"
capital. Consider land yielding an expected
constant cash flow: let the interest rate double and the
present value is halved. Compare the present value
of a steer to be slaughtered in one year: let the
interest rate double from 5% to 10% and the present value
drops from .95 of slaughter value to .91. Even that
overstates it a lot because we haven't accounted for the
feed bill, but never mind, the point should be
clear.
Let buyers expect land's cash flow to rise
annually by a growth coefficient, G, and the valuation
formula is cash flow divided by the interest rate minus
the growth rate (I-G), rather than I alone. Now let
the interest rate double, and the present value is cut to
less than half.
Or let land be yielding a nominal current cash
flow and to be held in anticipation of a higher use to
begin 10 years down the road, and thirty years after that
to be renewed for an even higher use. Let there be
a whiff of oil, or the floating value of a shopping
center, or the possible extension of a freeway and a new
water supply paid by others. Let there be a fear
(or hope) that Washington will debauch the currency
sometime again in this century, or that another Howard
Jarvis will cut land taxes some more, or that future
building costs will fall: any and all of these, which are
common and familiar expectations, make present values of
land more sensitive to discount rates than in the simple
basic capitalization model which is based on assumed
constant cash flow in perpetuity.
Expectations like those denoted above by G, or
like the anticipated higher future use referred to, are
"a state of the public mind" (Richard Hurd, Principles of
City Land Values). They are incapable of proof or
disproof in the present and, whether proven true or false
in the future, will have lost relevance, to be replaced
by new expectations of new futures that unfold endlessly
as time passes. ...
Now consider the market for land
titles. This is the more relevant market as to
building, transferring land between uses, and changing
parcel sizes. If the market for land services is
slow, the market for land titles is viscous. There is
no flow of supply, none at all. There is no real
turnover in the sense of producing and using up.
There is only ownership turnover: the market only transfers
existing titles. (There is a supplemental market in
long leases, not addressed here.)
There are few highly motivated sellers, as there are
motivated sellers of spoiling produce and obsolescing
computers and vehicles. Median home-owners are
motivated, when transferred to another region. Few
other land sellers come close to that degree of motivation
(and the median home represents more capital than
land). Capital depreciates; goods spoil and
obsolesce; idle labor starves; but land silently rises in
value.
The aggregate of all land changes hands slowly, with one or
two percent turnover of ownership annually (measuring the
stock by value, not number of parcels - smaller, cheaper
parcels turn faster). But buyers often need adjacent
land, or land in particular districts or with particular
qualities, and find little or no land on the market, or
land controlled by one seller.
The slow ownership turnover cited above applies to total
real estate, i.e. land including any buildings on it.
Ownership turnover is even slower for bare land. If
the average building lasts 50 years, only 2% of the land is
available for re-use in any given year. Only a
fraction of that 2% is for sale; the rest is renewed by the
same owner. Whoever wants to buy available land in
any particular area is unlikely to be faced with the "many
sellers" premised by the competitive model.
Hoarding for vertical integration.
A common precaution against sticky markets is buying excess
land for possible future expansion. This behavior
makes markets that much more sticky. It is one of
those things that necessitates and justifies itself,
considered in the aggregate: it is self-aggravating and
self-authenticating. When anyone
buys and holds for his own future expansion, everyone has
to: it is a positive feedback loop of possessiveness
run wild.
The composite result of individuals'
buying for future contingent need is that the market in raw
land is turned to glue. It ceases to serve the median
person in time of need. The effect is a
species of vertical integration and, like all vertical
integration, it destroys the free market in raw materials
and vastly inflates the aggregate need for holding raw
materials. This is because thepooling effect such as the market provides
inherently. That is, the grocer obtains, stores and
keeps a wide variety of food and sundries on tap for
thousands of customers. Lacking a grocer, each
customer would have to maintain her own stores, and the
aggregate required would far exceed that in the common
grocery store. A good land market would likewise keep
land on tap for the contingent needs of all, greatly
lowering aggregate needs.
Assembly.
In certain ecotones (zones of change of land use)
the technical need is to assemble small parcels into
larger ones, as where commerce, industry and high rise
are moving into a district of single homes on small
lots. This condition maximizes market
failure. It normally takes years to assemble an
optimal parcel: one holdout can spoil years of
negotiating and financing.
Straw buyers and front men are used to keep
principals and their intentions secret. Speculators
are everywhere, trying to assemble large plots or hold up
other buyers. Whole districts are held by anonymous
absentees; buildings deteriorate, neighborhoods lose
their natural leaders and stabilizers, and communities
disintegrate leaving slums and blight, crime and arson,
public charges and vandalism.
The sum of those factors makes for an inefficient
market in land titles. Everyone who can tries to
acquire land for his own future expansion. Timely
subdivision may be foregone in anticipation of future
assembly problems, skipping an entire generation of
optimal land use. Neighbors adjusting lot lines
have only each other to deal with. Aggregate
landownership is highly concentrated because of the small
numbers who can invest for deferred yields; the number of
sellers in one district or for one use is more narrowly
limited because of spatial immobility and low turnover
and impossibility of new land creation. Financing
is especially difficult because the asset is not
self-liquidating. Many holders are waiting for the
rise, and/ or for greater certainty to be provided by the
advance commitments of others who are in turn waiting for
them. Net result: wasted, underutilized land....
read the whole article
Al Hartheimer:
Affordable
Housing and the Land Value Tax Perspective: a letter to
Asheville, North Carolina
In Asheville, there are about 4000 parcels of
residential vacant land out of about 25,000 parcels --
that's 16% of the total number of parcels, and that
represents about 13% of the total residential land value.
There are also 500 parcels of commercial and industrial
vacant land out of a total of 3500 parcels, or about 14%
of the total number of parcels, which represents 8% of
the total non-residential land value. That's a lot of vacant land. Why does it remain
vacant in the face of the need for affordable housing?
Probably the biggest factor is the low
carrying cost of a vacant lot. In
Asheville, on average, the annual tax on a vacant
residential lot is about $200. With a carrying cost so
low, the incentive is to hold on to the lot with the hope
that the city will recover and the value of the lot will
increase. ...
Read
the whole
article
Alanna Hartzok: In
the History of Thought: Henry George's "Single
Tax"
One day, while riding horseback
in the Oakland hills, merchant seaman and journalist
Henry George had a startling epiphany.
He realized that speculation and private profiteering in
the gifts of nature were the root causes of the unjust
distribution of wealth. The insights presented in
Progress and Poverty, George's
masterwork, launched him to fame. His
policy approach was known at that time as the "single
tax" - meaning that taxation should be shifted off of
labor and onto the socially created surplus value of land
and other natural resources. His message reached
as far as the great Russian Leo Tolstoy, who was so taken
with the idea that he frequently referred to George and
"Georgism" in his novel
Resurrection.... Read the whole
article
Frank Stilwell and Kirrily Jordan: The Political Economy of Land:
Putting Henry George in His Place
George saw land as a community resource provided by
nature, to which every human being had an equal right. He
argued that, since land was fixed in supply, the system
of private land ownership allowed the wealthy few to
enjoy exclusive rights to land and its benefits, while
alienating the poorer majority from land ownership and
forcing them to pay rent to landowners in order to access
this necessary resource. Moreover, the collection of
rents by landowners allowed them to increase their wealth
without contributing to the productive efforts of
society. As the population grew, so too did the demand
for land, forcing rents and land values ever higher. In
addition, increases in land value resulting from
publicly-funded developments, such as roads and public
transport systems, unduly benefited landowners at the
expense of the community. Such unearned gains from
landownership encouraged speculation in land, pushing
prices even higher, while exposing the economy to the
risks of speculative ‘booms’ and
‘busts’. ...
The demand for land involves both use values and
exchange values. People seek land because the housing
built on it provides shelter and security, but they also
purchase it as a store of wealth and a means of capital
appreciation. A particularly important driver of real
estate prices has been the speculative demand, as
investors seek capital gains in the property market. In
Australia, this has been such common and longstanding
practice that it has been referred to as ‘the
national hobby’ (Sandercock, 1979). By
‘creaming off’ a part of this potential
capital gain, a higher uniform rate of land tax would act
as a disincentive to this property speculation, and could
therefore be expected to exert a downward influence on
property prices. Georgists have always been emphatic that
land taxes are different from other taxes in this respect
– they depress prices because they reduce demand.
So the usual fears that a tax will be ‘passed
on’ to customers (such as housing tenants, in this
case) do not apply.4 By making land less attractive as an
item to be purchased in the hope of making capital gains,
land tax can therefore be an important check on the
inflationary process. ...
Concerns about urban policies also raise questions about
the current relevance of Georgist ideas. For example, it
is pertinent to ask whether a more uniform land tax would
encourage the more efficient utilisation of urban space.
George argued that, in order to cover the costs of a
higher rate of land tax, landowners would be forced to
put their land to its most productive use, and could not
afford to hold it idle. Here is a clear link with the
modern concerns to discourage ‘urban sprawl’
and to promote ‘urban consolidation.’ To the
extent that a higher land tax would encourage the
development of more housing in existing urban areas, the
pressures for housing development in outlying areas would
be significantly reduced. This, in turn, could reduce the
burgeoning demand for transport that is currently
characteristic of large cities.
Land tax also impacts on the politics of peripheral
urban expansion. Currently, the prospect of huge capital
gains resulting from decisions by local governments to
rezone land from rural to urban acts as an incentive for
landowners on the fringes of built-up areas to lobby for
changes that will allow increased development. Hence,
landowners push for rights to subdivision, irrespective
of whether or not there is actual demand (Day, 1995: 3).
By creaming off the gains from windfall increases in land
values, land tax obviates this bias towards relentless
urban expansion.
However, the question remains: would a uniform land
tax be sufficient to produce more efficient patterns of
urban development? Or would there still be a need for
direct land use controls? Land tax can certainly be a
tool for discouraging the wasteful use of land. It tends
to discourage people from purchasing excessive amounts of
land or leaving it idle. However, it may also encourage
the overdevelopment of land in order to produce the
income stream necessary to pay the higher rate of
tax.
Critics of urban consolidation such as Patrick Troy
(1996) have examined the potential problems of such
overdevelopment, including a range of environmental
impacts such as altered hydrological processes. It seems
to be an overly bold claim that a Georgist land tax alone
would be sufficient to achieve optimal urban development
patterns. Land use controls a necessary adjunct to land
tax - in setting minimum requirements for green space,
for example.
Local government planning controls are also important
to prevent incompatibility of land uses, such the
development of hazardous or unhealthy industrial
activities adjacent to residential areas. Targeted
decentralisation policies are a means of encouraging the
further development of regional centres. Such policies
can work in conjunction with land taxes to ease growth
pressures in the larger cities, while addressing
long-standing spatial, social and economic inequalities
(Stilwell, 2000: 254-260). The desirability of promoting
more decentralised regional development is consistent
with a Georgist perspective, but not altogether
compatible with the claim that land tax would facilitate
urban consolidation. It seems clear that it
‘overburdens’ land tax to expect it alone to
produce the best spatial outcomes, taking account of all
the economic, social and environmental issues involved in
urban and regional policy. The various other policy
instruments – including regulations relating to
green space, zoning, and the provision of public
infrastructure to pave the way for decentralisation
– are important complements to land taxation. In
other words, land tax is best regarded as a necessary but
not sufficient condition for more effective spatial
policy. ... read the
whole article
Peter Barnes:
Capitalism 3.0 — Chapter 2: A Short History of
Capitalism (pages 15-32)
Why did this happen? There are many
explanations. One is that welfare kept the poor poor;
this was argued by Charles Murray in his 1984 book
Losing Ground. Welfare, he contended,
encouraged single mothers to remain unmarried,
increased the incidence of out-of-wedlock births, and
created a parasitic underclass. In other words, Murray
(and others) blamed victims or particular policies for
perpetuating poverty, but paid scant attention to why
poverty exists in the first place.
There are, of course, many roots, but my own
hypothesis is this: much of what we label private
wealth is taken from, or coproduced with, the commons.
However, these takings from the commons are far from
equal. To put it bluntly, the rich are rich
because (through corporations) they get the
lion’s share of common wealth; the poor are poor
because they get very little.
Another way to say this is that, just as
water flows downhill to the sea, so money flows uphill
to property. Capitalism by its very design
maximizes returns to existing wealth owners. It
benefits, in particular, those who own stock when a
successful company is young; they can receive hundreds,
even thousands of times their initial investments when
the company matures. Moreover, once such stockholders
accumulate wealth, they can increase it through
reinvestment, pass it on to their heirs, and use their
inevitable influence over politicians to gain extra
advantages — witness the steady lowering of taxes
on capital gains, dividends, and inheritances.
On top of this, in the last few decades, has been the
phenomenon called globalization. The whole point of
globalization is to increase the return to capital by
enabling its owners to find the lowest costs on the
planet. Hence the stagnation at the bottom alongside
the surging wealth at the top.
A critical piece of this analysis is that
very few new shares of corporate stock are
issued. As author Marjorie Kelly has pointed
out, most established corporations finance growth
through retained earnings and debt. They’re just
as likely to buy back outstanding shares as to issue
new ones. Consequently, old wealth is rarely diluted.
When new money flows into the stock market, its
main effect is to increase the wealth of existing
stockholders and their fortunate heirs. Thus, of the
total gain in marketable wealth that occurred in the
United States between 1983 and 1998, more than half
went to the top 1 percent.
The companies that do issue new stock are the young
ones — the Microsofts, Apples, and Googles.
Entertainers and athletes aside, most new
multimillionaires are early stockholders in
corporations like these. In these cases, however, the
distribution of gains is so tilted in favor of these
early stockholders that the skewed pattern of wealth
distribution is replicated. New wealth joins old
wealth, but the concentration remains the same.
There’s no mechanism for dispensing wealth
— even new wealth — more evenhandedly. ...
read the whole chapter
|
To share this page with a friend:
right click, choose "send," and add your
comments.
|
|
Red links have not been
visited; .
Green links are pages you've seen
|
Essential Documents pertinent
to this theme:
|
|