Rent and Wages
When an employer is paying a large amount
to his bank or to his landlord for the use of the
location (land) — as opposed to the building
(capital) — he doesn't have much left to pay wages
to employees or to himself, particularly if he is also
being taxed on any profits he makes.
Is there a better way? Yes! Pay the
landlord for the use of his building, and pay the commons
for the use of the site, knowing that the payment for the
use of the site will be used for our common spending,
instead of lodging in the landlord's private or corporate
or family trust's portfolio.
Henry George: Ode to
Liberty (1877 speech)
In the very centers of our civilization today are
want and suffering enough to make sick at heart whoever
does not close his eyes and steel his nerves.
Dare we turn to the Creator and ask Him
to relieve it? Supposing the prayer were heard,
and at the behest with which the universe sprang into
being there should glow in the sun a greater power; new
virtue fill the air; fresh vigor the soil; that for every
blade of grass that now grows two should spring up, and
the seed that now increases fifty-fold should increase a
hundredfold! Would poverty be abated or
want relieved? Manifestly no! Whatever benefit
would accrue would be but temporary. The new powers streaming through the material
universe could be utilized only through land. And land,
being private property, the classes that now monopolize
the bounty of the Creator would monopolize all the new
bounty. Land owners would alone be benefited.
Rents would increase, but wages would
still tend to the starvation
point!
This is not merely a deduction of political
economy; it is a fact of experience. We know it because
we have seen it. ... read the
whole speech
H.G. Brown: Significant
Paragraphs from Henry George's Progress & Poverty,
Chapter 5: The Basic Cause of Poverty (in the
unabridged:
Book V: The Problem Solved)
The truth is self-evident. Put to any one capable of
consecutive thought this question:
"Suppose there should arise from the English Channel
or the German Ocean a no man's land on which common labor
to an unlimited amount should be able to make thirty
shillings a day and which should remain unappropriated
and of free access, like the commons which once comprised
so large a part of English soil. What would be the effect
upon wages in England?"
He would at once tell you that common wages throughout
England must soon increase to thirty shillings a day.
And in response to another question, "What would be
the effect on rents?" he would at a moment's reflection
say that rents must necessarily fall; and if he thought
out the next step he would tell you that all this would
happen without any very large part of English labor being
diverted to the new natural opportunities, or the forms
and direction of industry being much changed; only that
kind of production being abandoned which now yields to
labor and to landlord together less than labor could
secure on the new opportunities. The great rise in wages
would be at the expense of rent.
Take now the same man or another — some
hardheaded business man, who has no theories, but knows
how to make money. Say to him: "Here is a little village;
in ten years it will be a great city — in ten years
the railroad will have taken the place of the stage
coach, the electric light of the candle; it will abound
with all the machinery and improvements that so
enormously multiply the effective power of labor. Will,
in ten years, interest be any higher?"
He will tell you, "No!"
"Will the wages of common labor be any higher; will it
be easier for a man who has nothing but his labor to make
an independent living?"
He will tell you, "No; the wages of common labor will
not be any higher; on the contrary, all the chances are
that they will be lower; it will not be easier for the
mere laborer to make an independent living; the chances
are that it will be harder."
"What, then, will be higher?"
"Rent; the value of land. Go, get yourself a piece of
ground, and hold possession."
And if, under such circumstances, you take his advice,
you need do nothing more. You may sit down and smoke your
pipe; you may lie around like the lazzaroni of Naples or
the leperos of Mexico; you may go up in a balloon, or
down a hole in the ground; and without doing one stroke
of work, without adding one iota to the wealth of the
community, in ten years you will be rich! In the new city
you may have a luxurious mansion; but among its public
buildings will be an almshouse.
For land is the habitation of man, the storehouse upon
which be must draw for all his needs, the material to
which his labor must be applied for the supply of all his
desires; for even the products of the sea cannot be
taken, the light of the sun enjoyed, or any of the forces
of nature utilized, without the use of land or its
products. On the land we are born, from it we live, to it
we return again — children of the soil as truly as
is the blade of grass or the flower of the field. Take
away from man all that belongs to land, and he is but a
disembodied spirit. Material progress cannot rid
us of our dependence upon land; it can but add to the
power of producing wealth from land; and hence, when
land is monopolized, it might go on to infinity
without increasing wages or improving the condition of
those who have but their labor. It can but add
to the value of land and the power which its possession
gives. Everywhere, in all times, among all peoples, the
possession of land is the base of aristocracy, the
foundation of great fortunes, the source of power. ...
read the
whole chapter
Henry George: The Great Debate: Single
Tax vs Social Democracy (1889)
In “Progress and
Poverty,” I attempted to do what is
indispensable and necessary to anyone who would think
clearly upon these subjects, to define my terms. I have,
in the first place, never stated anything more than that
the increase of rent produces a tendency
to the decrease of wages, and by wages in all such parts
as that, I mean that proportion which goes to the
labourer. Money wages may increase or decrease
without the proportion being affected. In the United
States as a fact, with the rise of land values everywhere
we have most exactly seen the decrease of wages as a
proportion. ... Read
the entire article
Louis Post: Outlines
of Louis F. Post's Lectures, with Illustrative Notes and
Charts (1894)
a. Explanation of Wages and
Rent
Differences in the desirableness of land divide Wealth
into the two funds, Wages and Rent. Labor naturally
applies its forces to that land from which, considering
all the existing and known circumstances, most Wealth can
be produced with least expenditure of labor force. Such
land is the best. So long as the best land exceeds demand
for it, laborers are upon an equality of opportunity, and
the entire product goes to them as Wages in proportion to
the labor force they respectively expend. But when the
supply of the best land falls below demand for it, some
laborers must resort to land where with an equal
expenditure of labor force they produce less wealth than
those who use the best land. The laborers thus excluded
from the best land naturally offer a premium for it, or
what is the same thing, offer to work for its owners for
what they might obtain by working for themselves upon the
poorer land. This condition differentiates Rent from
Wages. Rent goes to land-owners as such,
irrespective of whether they labor or not; Wages go to
laborers as such, irrespective of whether they own land
or not.85
85. Land of every kind may vary in
desirableness from other land of the same kind. Certain
farming land, for example, is so fertile that it will
yield to a given application of labor two bushels of
wheat to every bushel that certain other farming land
will yield; and it is obvious that, other things being
equal, farmers would prefer the more fertile land. But
some fertile land lies so far away from market that
less fertile land lying nearer is more productive,
because it costs less to exchange its products for what
their producer demands; in such cases farmers would
prefer the less fertile land. The same principle
applies to all kinds of land. Building lots at or near
a center of residence or business are preferable for
most purposes of residence or business to lots equally
good in other respects which are far away.
Now, the land that is preferable is of
course most in demand; and if it be all in use, with
demand for it unsatisfied, competition for the
preference sets in, and gives value to it.
All land cannot be equally desirable.
Some excels in fertility. Some is rich with mineral
deposits, a species of fertility. On some, towns and
cities settle, thereby adding to the productiveness of
the labor that uses it, because these sites are thus
made centers of co-operation or trade. And yet
production in the civilized state requires that the
producer shall have exclusive possession of the land
lie needs. This necessity inevitably gives to some
people more desirable land than others have, even
though all should have an abundance. Consequently the
returns to equal labor are unequal. The man who has
land that is more fertile or better located than that
of another gets more wealth than the other in return
for a given expenditure of labor. If, for example, one
with given labor produces 10 bushels of corn from
fertile land, equal, say, to $5 worth of any kind of
wealth in the market, and the other with the same labor
produces 8 bushels of corn, or $4 worth of any kind of
wealth in the market, the first receives 2 bushels (or
$1) more for his labor than the other receives for his,
though each labors with equal effort, skill, and
intelligence. Or, if the fertility of the land be the
same, but its situation in reference to the market be
such that the cost of transportation still preserves
the relation of $5 to $4, the same inequality of wages
results. It is this phenomenon that gives rise to Rent.
Rent is the market value of just such differences in
opportunity as are here illustrated. It is a premium
for choice land, for preferential locations, for site,
for space.
This premium is a very different thing
from compensation for labor. Nor is the difference
modified when premium owners first obtain Wages for
work and with them buy the premium-commanding land.
Rent can no more be turned into compensation for labor
by exchanging labor products for the power to exact it,
than a man can be turned into Wealth by exchanging
Wealth for him. Whether the fruits of purchase or of
conquest, or of fraud, Rent always constitutes that
part of Wealth which is deducted from current
production as premiums for superior opportunities for
production.
Wages and Rent are both drawn from
Wealth, and both go often to the same individual and in
the same form of payment, as when a freehold farmer
enjoys the use of the grain he raises from more fertile
land than his neighbors have, or a city freeholder
occupies or receives hire from his house and lot: but
Wages flow from Wealth to labor as compensation for
production, while Rent flows from Wealth to land-owners
in premiums for allowing labor to produce Wealth from
superior locations. Wages are appurtenant to Labor;
Rent is appurtenant to Land. It is as laborer that the
individual takes Wages, but as land-owner that he takes
Rent.
b. Normal Effect of Social Progress upon
Wages and Rent
In the foregoing charts the effect of social growth is
ignored, it being assumed that the given expenditure of
labor force does not become more productive.93 Let us now
try to illustrate that effect, upon the supposition that
social growth increases the productive power of the given
expenditure of labor force as applied to the first closed
space, to 100; as applied to the second, to 50; as
applied to the third, to 10; as applied to the fourth, to
3, and as applied to the open space, to 1. 94 If there
were no increased demand for land the chart would then be
like this: [chart]
93. "The effect of increasing population
upon the distribution of wealth is to increase rent ..
. in two ways: First, By lowering the margin of
cultivation. Second, By bringing out in land special
capabilities otherwise latent, and by attaching special
capabilities to particular lands.
"I am disposed to think that the latter
mode, to which little attention has been given by
political economists, is really the more important."
— Progress and Poverty, book iv, ch. iii.
"When we have inquired what it is that
marks off land from those material things which we
regard as products of the land, we shall find that the
fundamental attribute of land is its extension. The
right to use a piece of land gives command over a
certain space — a certain part of the earth's
surface. The area of the earth is fixed; the geometric
relations in which any particular part of it stands to
other parts are fixed. Man has no control over them;
they are wholly unaffected by demand; they have no cost
of production; there is no supply price at which they
can be produced.
"The use of a certain area of the
earth's surface is a primary condition of anything that
man can do; it gives him room for his own actions, with
the enjoyment of the heat and the light, the air and
the rain which nature assigns to that area; and it
determines his distance from, and in great measure his
relations to, other things and other persons. We shall
find that it is this property of land, which, though as
yet insufficient prominence has been given to it, is
the ultimate cause of the distinction which all writers
are compelled to make between land and other things."
— Marshall's Prin., book iv, ch. ii, sec. i.
94. Of course social growth does not go
on in this regular way; the charts are merely
illustrative. They are intended to illustrate the
universal fact that as any land becomes a center of
trade or other social relationship its value rises.
Though Rent is now increased, so are Wages. Both
benefit by social growth. But if we consider the fact
that increase in the productive power of labor increases
demand for land we shall see that the tendency of Wages
(as a proportion of product if not as an absolute
quantity) is downward, while that of Rent is upward. 95
And this conclusion is confirmed by observation. 96
95. "Perhaps it may be well to remind
the reader, before closing this chapter, of what has
been before stated — that I am using the word
wages not in the sense of a quantity, but in the sense
of a proportion. When I say that wages fall as rent
rises, I do not mean that the quantity of wealth
obtained by laborers as wages is necessarily less, but
that the proportion which it bears to the whole produce
is necessarily less. The proportion may diminish while
the quantity remains the same or increases." —
Progress and Poverty, book iii, ch. vi.
96. The condition illustrated in the
last chart would be the result of social growth if all
land but that which was in full use were common land.
The discovery of mines, the development of cities and
towns, and the construction of railroads, the
irrigation of and places, improvements in government,
all the infinite conveniences and laborsaving devices
that civilization generates, would tend to abolish
poverty by increasing the compensation of labor, and
making it impossible for any man to be in involuntary
idleness, or underpaid, so long as mankind was in want.
If demand for land increased, Wages would tend to fall
as the demand brought lower grades of land into use;
but they would at the same time tend to rise as social
growth added new capabilities to the lower grades. And
it is altogether probable that, while progress would
lower Wages as a proportion of total product, it would
increase them as an absolute quantity.
c. Significance of the Upward Tendency of
Rent
Now, what is the meaning of this tendency of Rent to
rise with social progress, while Wages tend to fall? Is
it not a plain promise that if Rent be treated as common
property, advances in productive power shall be steps in
the direction of realizing through orderly and natural
growth those grand conceptions of both the socialist and
the individualist, which in the present condition of
society are justly ranked as Utopian? Is it not likewise
a plain warning that if Rent be treated as private
property, advances in productive power will be steps in
the direction of making slaves of the many laborers, and
masters of a few land-owners? Does it not mean that
common ownership of Rent is in harmony with natural law,
and that its private appropriation is disorderly and
degrading? When the cause of Rent and the tendency
illustrated in the preceding chart are considered in
connection with the self-evident truth that God made the
earth for common use and not for private monopoly, how
can a contrary inference hold? Caused and increased by
social growth, 97 the benefits of which should be common,
and attaching to land, the just right to which is equal,
Rent must be the natural fund for public expenses. 98
97. Here, far away from civilization, is
a solitary settler. Getting no benefits from
government, he needs no public revenues, and none of
the land about him has any value. Another settler
comes, and another, until a village appears. Some
public revenue is then required. Not much, but some.
And the land has a little value, only a little; perhaps
just enough to equal the need for public revenue. The
village becomes a town. More revenues are needed, and
land values are higher. It becomes a city. The public
revenues required are enormous, and so are the land
values.
98. Society, and society alone, causes
Rent. Rising with the rise, advancing with the growth,
and receding with the decline of society, it measures
the earning power of society as a whole as
distinguished from that of the individuals. Wages, on
the other hand, measure the earning power of the
individuals as distinguished from that of society as a
whole. We have distinguished the parts into which
Wealth is distributed as Wages and Rent; but it would
be correct, indeed it is the same thing, to regard all
wealth as earnings, and to distinguish the two kinds as
Communal Earnings and Individual Earnings. How, then,
can there be any question as to the fund from which
society should be supported? How can it be justly
supported in any other way than out of its own
earnings?
If there be at all such a thing as design in the
universe — and who can doubt it? — then has
it been designed that Rent, the earnings of the
community, shall be retained for the support of the
community, and that Wages, the earnings of the
individual, shall be left to the individual in proportion
to the value of his service. This is the divine law,
whether we trace it through complex moral and economic
relations, or find it in the eighth commandment.
d. Effect of Confiscating Rent to Private
Use.
By giving Rent to individuals society ignores this
most just law, 99 thereby creating social disorder and
inviting social disease. Upon society alone, therefore,
and not upon divine Providence which has provided
bountifully, nor upon the disinherited poor, rests the
responsibility for poverty and fear of poverty.
99. "Whatever dispute arouses the
passions of men, the conflict is sure to rage, not so
much as to the question 'Is it wise?' as to the
question 'Is it right?'
"This tendency of popular discussions to
take an ethical form has a cause. It springs from a law
of the human mind; it rests upon a vague and
instinctive recognition of what is probably the deepest
truth we can grasp. That alone is wise which is just;
that alone is enduring which is right. In the narrow
scale of individual actions and individual life this
truth may be often obscured, but in the wider field of
national life it everywhere stands out.
"I bow to this arbitrament, and accept
this test." — Progress and Poverty, book vii, ch.
i.
The reader who has been deceived into
believing that Mr. George's proposition is in any
respect unjust, will find profit in a perusal of the
entire chapter from which the foregoing extract is
taken.
Let us try to trace the connection by means of a
chart, beginning with the white spaces on page 68. As
before, the first-comers take possession of the best
land. But instead of leaving for others what they do not
themselves need for use, as in the previous
illustrations, they appropriate the whole space, using
only part, but claiming ownership of the rest. We may
distinguish the used part with red color, and that which
is appropriated without use with blue. Thus: [chart]
But what motive is there for appropriating more of the
space than is used? Simply that the appropriators may
secure the pecuniary benefit of future social growth.
What will enable them to secure that? Our system of
confiscating Rent from the community that earns it, and
giving it to land-owners who, as such, earn
nothing.100
100. It is reported from Iowa that a few
years ago a workman in that State saw a meteorite fall,
and. securing possession of it after much digging, he
was offered $105 by a college for his "find." But the
owner of the land on which the meteorite fell claimed
the money, and the two went to law about it. After an
appeal to the highest court of the State, it was
finally decided that neither by right of discovery, nor
by right of labor, could the workman have the money,
because the title to the meteorite was in the man who
owned the land upon which it fell.
Observe the effect now upon Rent and Wages. When other
men come, instead of finding half of the best land still
common and free, as in the corresponding chart on page
68, they find all of it owned, and are obliged either to
go upon poorer land or to buy or rent from owners of the
best. How much will they pay for the best? Not more than
1, if they want it for use and not to hold for a higher
price in the future, for that represents the full
difference between its productiveness and the
productiveness of the next best. But if the first-comers,
reasoning that the next best land will soon be scarce and
theirs will then rise in value, refuse to sell or to rent
at that valuation, the newcomers must resort to land of
the second grade, though the best be as yet only partly
used. Consequently land of the first grade commands Rent
before it otherwise would.
As the sellers' price, under these circumstances, is
arbitrary it cannot be stated in the chart; but the
buyers' price is limited by the superiority of the best
land over that which can be had for nothing, and the
chart may be made to show it: [chart]
And now, owing to the success of the appropriators of
the best land in securing more than their fellows for the
same expenditure of labor force, a rush is made for
unappropriated land. It is not to use it that it is
wanted, but to enable its appropriators to put Rent into
their own pockets as soon as growing demand for land
makes it valuable.101 We may, for illustration, suppose
that all the remainder of the second space and the whole
of the third are thus appropriated, and note the effect:
[chart]
At this point Rent does not increase nor Wages fall,
because there is no increased demand for land for use.
The holding of inferior land for higher prices, when
demand for use is at a standstill, is like owning lots in
the moon — entertaining, perhaps, but not
profitable. But let more land be needed for use, and
matters promptly assume a different appearance. The new
labor must either go to the space that yields but 1, or
buy or rent from owners of better grades, or hire out.
The effect would be the same in any case. Nobody for the
given expenditure of labor force would get more than 1;
the surplus of products would go to landowners as Rent,
either directly in rent payments, or indirectly through
lower Wages. Thus: [chart]
101. The text speaks of Rent only as a
periodical or continuous payment — what would be
called "ground rent." But actual or potential Rent may
always be, and frequently is, capitalized for the
purpose of selling the right to enjoy it, and it is to
selling value that we usually refer when dealing in
land.
Land which has the power of yielding
Rent to its owner will have a selling value, whether it
be used or not, and whether Rent is actually derived
from it or not. This selling value will be the
capitalization of its present or prospective power of
producing Rent. In fact, much the larger proportion of
laud that has a selling value is wholly or partly
unused, producing no Rent at all, or less than it would
if fully used. This condition is expressed in the chart
by the blue color.
"The capitalized value of land is the
actuarial 'discounted' value of all the net incomes
which it is likely to afford, allowance being made on
the one hand for all incidental expenses, including
those of collecting the rents, and on the other for its
mineral wealth, its capabilities of development for any
kind of business, and its advantages, material, social,
and aesthetic, for the purposes of residence." —
Marshall's Prin., book vi, ch. ix, sec. 9.
"The value of land is commonly expressed
as a certain number of times the current money rental,
or in other words, a certain 'number of years'
purchase' of that rental; and other things being equal,
it will be the higher the more important these direct
gratifications are, as well as the greater the chance
that they and the money income afforded by the land
will rise." — Id., note.
"Value . . . means not utility, not any
quality inhering in the thing itself, but a quality
which gives to the possession of a thing the power of
obtaining other things, in return for it or for its
use. . . Value in this sense — the usual sense
— is purely relative. It exists from and is
measured by the power of obtaining things for things by
exchanging them. . . Utility is necessary to value, for
nothing can be valuable unless it has the quality of
gratifying some physical or mental desire of man,
though it be but a fancy or whim. But utility of itself
does not give value. . . If we ask ourselves the reason
of . . . variations in . . . value . . . we see that
things having some form of utility or desirability, are
valuable or not valuable, as they are hard or easy to
get. And if we ask further, we may see that with most
of the things that have value this difficulty or ease
of getting them, which determines value, depends on the
amount of labor which must be expended in producing
them ; i.e., bringing them into the place, form and
condition in which they are desired. . . Value is
simply an expression of the labor required for the
production of such a thing. But there are some things
as to which this is not so clear. Land is not produced
by labor, yet land, irrespective of any improvements
that labor has made on it, often has value. . . Yet a
little examination will show that such facts are but
exemplifications of the general principle, just as the
rise of a balloon and the fall of a stone both
exemplify the universal law of gravitation. . . The
value of everything produced by labor, from a pound of
chalk or a paper of pins to the elaborate structure and
appurtenances of a first-class ocean steamer, is
resolvable on analysis into an equivalent of the labor
required to produce such a thing in form and place;
while the value of things not produced by labor, but
nevertheless susceptible of ownership, is in the same
way resolvable into an equivalent of the labor which
the ownership of such a thing enables the owner to
obtain or save." —
Perplexed Philosopher, ch. v.
The figure 1 in parenthesis, as an item of Rent,
indicates potential Rent. Labor would give that much for
the privilege of using the space, but the owners hold out
for better terms; therefore neither Rent nor Wages is
actually produced, though but for this both might be.
In this chart, notwithstanding that but little space
is used, indicated with red, Wages are reduced to the
same low point by the mere appropriation of space,
indicated with blue, that they would reach if all the
space above the poorest were fully used. It thereby
appears that under a system which confiscates Rent to
private uses, the demand for land for speculative
purposes becomes so great that Wages fall to a minimum
long before they would if land were appropriated only for
use.
In illustrating the effect of confiscating Rent to
private use we have as yet ignored the element of social
growth. Let us now assume as before (page 73), that
social growth increases the productive power of the given
expenditure of labor force to 100 when applied to the
best land, 50 when applied to the next best, 10 to the
next, 3 to the next, and 1 to the poorest. Labor would
not be benefited now, as it appeared to be when on page
73 we illustrated the appropriation of land for use only,
although much less land is actually used. The prizes
which expectation of future social growth dangles before
men as the rewards of owning land, would raise demand so
as to make it more than ever difficult to get land. All
of the fourth grade would be taken up in expectation of
future demand; and "surplus labor" would be crowded out
to the open space that originally yielded nothing, but
which in consequence of increased labor power now yields
as much as the poorest closed space originally yielded,
namely, 1 to the given expenditure of labor force.102
Wages would then be reduced to the present productiveness
of the open space. Thus: [chart]
102. The paradise to which the youth of
our country have so long been directed in the advice,
"Go West, young man, go West," is truthfully described
in "Progress and Poverty," book iv, ch. iv, as follows
:
"The man who sets out from the eastern
seaboard in search of the margin of cultivation,
where he may obtain land without paying rent, must,
like the man who swam the river to get a drink, pass
for long distances through half-titled farms, and
traverse vast areas of virgin soil, before he reaches
the point where land can be had free of rent —
i.e., by homestead entry or preemption."
If we assume that 1 for the given expenditure of labor
force is the least that labor can take while exerting the
same force, the downward movement of Wages will be here
held in equilibrium. They cannot fall below 1; but
neither can they rise above it, no matter how much
productive power may increase, so long as it pays to hold
land for higher values. Some laborers would continually
be pushed back to land which increased productive power
would have brought up in productiveness from 0 to 1, and
by perpetual competition for work would so regulate the
labor market that the given expenditure of labor force,
however much it produced, could nowhere secure more than
1 in Wages.103 And this tendency would persist until some
labor was forced upon land which, despite increase in
productive power, would not yield the accustomed living
without increase of labor force. Competition for work
would then compel all laborers to increase their
expenditure of labor force, and to do it over and over
again as progress went on and lower and lower grades of
land were monopolized, until human endurance could go no
further.104 Either that, or they would be obliged to
adapt themselves to a lower scale of living.105
103. Henry Fawcett, in his work on
"Political Economy," book ii, ch. iii, observes with
reference to improvements in agricultural implements
which diminish the expense of cultivation, that they do
not increase the profits of the farmer or the wages of
his laborers, but that "the landlord will receive in
addition to the rent already paid to him, all that is
saved in the expense of cultivation." This is true not
alone of improvements in agriculture, but also of
improvements in all other branches of industry.
104. "The cause which limits speculation
in commodities, the tendency of increasing price to
draw forth additional supplies, cannot limit the
speculative advance in land values, as land is a fixed
quantity, which human agency can neither increase nor
diminish; but there is nevertheless a limit to the
price of land, in the minimum required by labor and
capital as the condition of engaging in production. If
it were possible to continuously reduce wages until
zero were reached, it would be possible to continuously
increase rent until it swallowed up the whole produce.
But as wages cannot be permanently reduced below the
point at which laborers will consent to work and
reproduce, nor interest below the point at which
capital will be devoted to production, there is a limit
which restrains the speculative advance of rent. Hence,
speculation cannot have the same scope to advance rent
in countries where wages and interest are already near
the minimum, as in countries where they are
considerably above it. Yet that there is in all
progressive countries a constant tendency in the
speculative advance of rent to overpass the limit where
production would cease, is, I think, shown by recurring
seasons of industrial paralysis." — Progress and
Poverty, book iv, ch. iv.
105. As Puck once put it, "the man who
makes two blades of grass to grow where but one grew
before, must not be surprised when ordered to 'keep off
the grass.' "
They in fact do both, and the incidental disturbances
of general readjustment are what we call "hard times."
106 These culminate in forcing unused land into the
market, thereby reducing Rent and reviving industry. Thus
increase of labor force, a lowering of the scale of
living, and depression of Rent, co-operate to bring on
what we call "good times." But no sooner do "good times"
return than renewed demands for land set in, Rent rises
again, Wages fall again, and "hard times" duly reappear.
The end of every period of "hard times" finds Rent higher
and Wages lower than at the end of the previous
period.107
106. "That a speculative advance in rent
or land values invariably precedes each of these
seasons of industrial depression is everywhere clear.
That they bear to each other the relation of cause and
effect, is obvious to whoever considers the necessary
relation between land and labor." — Progress and
Poverty, book v, ch. i.
107. What are called "good times" reach
a point at which an upward land market sets in. From
that point there is a downward tendency of wages (or a
rise in the cost of living, which is the same thing) in
all departments of labor and with all grades of
laborers. This tendency continues until the fictitious
values of land give way. So long as the tendency is
felt only by that class which is hired for wages, it is
poverty merely; when the same tendency is felt by the
class of labor that is distinguished as "the business
interests of the country," it is "hard times." And
"hard times" are periodical because land values, by
falling, allow "good times" to set it, and by rising
with "good times" bring "hard times" on again. The
effect of "hard times" may be overcome, without much,
if any, fall in land values, by sufficient increase in
productive power to overtake the fictitious value of
land.
The dishonest and disorderly system under which
society confiscates Rent from common to individual uses,
produces this result. That maladjustment is the
fundamental cause of poverty. And progress, so long as
the maladjustment continues, instead of tending to remove
poverty as naturally it should, actually generates and
intensifies it. Poverty persists with increase of
productive power because land values, when Rent is
privately appropriated, tend to even greater increase.
There can be but one outcome if this continues: for
individuals suffering and degradation, and for society
destruction. ... read
the book
Louis Post: Outlines
of Louis F. Post's Lectures, with Illustrative Notes and
Charts (1894) — Appendix: FAQ
Q6. If a land-owner builds, does not that increase
the value of his land and consequently the amount of the
tax he would have to pay? If so, would not he be taxed
for his improvement?
A. No. Upon the value of the building he would never pay
any tax. It is true that his improvement might attract
others to the locality in such numbers as to make land
there scarcer and consequently dearer. His own lot would
in that case rise in value with the other land and be
taxed more, just as the rest would be. But that would not
take any of his labor in taxes; he would still have his
building free of taxation. Thus: If on a lot worth $1000
a building worth $1000 were erected, making the whole
worth $2000, the tax would fall only upon the $1000 which
represents the value of the lot. If land then became so
scarce that the lot rose in value to $1500 the tax would
be raised. But the owner's improvement would be still
exempt. When his property was worth $2000 he was taxed on
$1000, the value of the lot, leaving $1000, the value of
the building, free; and now, though he is taxed on $1500,
the value of the lot, $1000, the value of the building,
is still free. ... read the book
Winston Churchill: The People's Land
Every form of enterprise only
undertaken after the land monopolist has skimmed the
cream off for himself It does not
matter where you look or what examples you select, you
will see that every form of enterprise, every step in
material progress, is only undertaken after the land
monopolist has skimmed the cream off for himself, and
everywhere today the man or the public body who wishes to
put land to its highest use is forced to pay a
preliminary fine in land values to the man who is putting
it to an inferior use, and in some cases to no use at
all. All comes back to the land value, and its owner for
the time being is able to levy his toll upon all other
forms of wealth and upon every form of industry.
A portion, in some cases the whole, of
every benefit which is laboriously acquired by the
community is represented in the land value, and finds its
way automatically into the landlord's
pocket.If there is a rise in
wages, rents are able to move forward, because the
workers can afford to pay a little more. If the
opening of a new railway or a new tramway or the
institution of an improved service of workmen's trains or
a lowering of fares or a new invention or any other
public convenience affords a benefit to the workers in
any particular district, it becomes easier for them to
live, and therefore the landlord and the
ground landlord, one on top of the other, are able to
charge them more for the privilege of living
there. ... Read the
whole piece
|
To share this page with a friend:
right click, choose "send," and add your
comments.
|
|
Red links have not been
visited; .
Green links are pages you've seen
|
Essential Documents pertinent
to this theme:
|
|