Wedge
The term "wedge" is used in at least two ways in the
documents on this website. George speaks of an immense
wedge
early in Progress & Poverty:
It is as though an immense wedge were being
forced, not underneath society, but through society.
Those who are above the point of separation are
elevated, but those who are below are crushed
down.
(One is led to question whether our efforts should be
devoted to moving a few million more people from below
the wedge to above it, or whether our efforts should be
devoted to causing the wedge to be removed. This site
argues the latter, of course! See fences and small
bandages.)
Mark Twain, in Archimedes, speaks of
a great screw, which, as you might recall from grade
school science, is a related "simple machine." (Perhaps
this is a better explanation for how the word entered the
vernacular in one of its popular uses!)
I know of a mechanical force more powerful than
anything the vaunting engineer of Syracuse ever dreamed
of. It is the force of land monopoly; it is a screw and
lever all in one; it will screw the last penny out of a
man's pocket, and bend everything on earth to its own
despotic will. Give me the private ownership of
all the land, and will I move the earth? No; but I will
do more. I will undertake to make slaves of all the
human beings on the face of it. Not chattel
slaves exactly, but slaves nevertheless. What an idiot
I would be to make chattel slaves of them. I would have
to find them salts and senna when they were sick, and
whip them to work when they were lazy.
Nic Tideman writes of a different kind of wedge when
describing why most other taxes are far less desirable
than a tax on land values:
A tax creates a difference, a
‘wedge’, between the price that a buyer
pays and the price that the seller receives.
Sometimes the wedge generated by a tax is enough to
inhibit a transaction that would otherwise
occur.
Fred Foldvary writes relatedly:
Taxes on wages create a
wedge between the cost of labor to employers and the
take-home pay of the worker. More costly labor results
in less employment. Taxes on the income
from capital goods and on the sale of
goods has the same effect. There are unemployment
taxes, disability taxes, and payroll taxes that
increase the tax wedge. On top of that, there are
minimum-wage laws that prevent the least productive
workers from getting hired. There are permits, zoning,
and other rules and costs that also prevent some
workers from becoming self-employed.
and Mason Gaffney:
Georgist policy improves the
structure of the economy in at least five
ways.
a. It erases the
"wedge effect" of indirect taxes, while maintaining
tax revenues. This might be called a "True
Laffer Curve effect" - what Laffer and Reagan
promised in 1980, but Reagan could not deliver. The
wedge effect is both warping, and, in the aggregate,
anti-incentive.
b. It actually
lubricates the land market in the very process of
extracting more tax revenues from it. It is
better than "neutral" (lacking in wedge effects). It
subjects landowners to a cash drain that is more
potent than mere "opportunity cost" in prompting
landowners to put land to its "highest and best use,"
i.e. to allocate it optimally in the manner
prescribed by economic theory. ...
None of these wedges are desirable — and each
can be remedied by the same reform.
Henry George:
Progress & Poverty:
Introductory: The Problem
Now, however, we are coming into collision with facts
which there can be no mistaking. From all parts of the
civilized world come complaints;
- of industrial depression;
- of labor condemned to involuntary idleness;
- of capital massed and wasting;
- of pecuniary distress among business men;
- of want and suffering and anxiety among the working
classes.
All the dull, deadening pain, all the keen, maddening
anguish, that to great masses of men are involved in the
words "hard times," afflict the world today. This
state of things, common to communities differing so
widely in situation, in political institutions, in fiscal
and financial systems, in density of population and in
social organization can hardly be accounted for by local
causes.
- There is distress where large standing armies are
maintained, but there is also distress where the
standing armies are nominal;
- there is distress where protective tariffs stupidly
and wastefully hamper trade, but there is also distress
where trade is nearly free;
- there is distress where autocratic government yet
prevails, but there is also distress where political
power is wholly in the hands of the people;
- in countries where paper is money, and
- in countries where gold and silver are the only
currency.
Evidently, beneath all such things as these, we must
infer a common cause.
That there is a common cause, and that it is either
what we call material progress or something closely
connected with material progress, becomes more than an
inference when it is noted that the phenomena we class
together and speak of as industrial depression, are but
intensifications of phenomena which always accompany
material progress, and which show themselves more clearly
and strongly as material progress goes on. Where
the conditions to which material progress everywhere
tends are most fully realized--that is to say, where
population is densest, wealth greatest, and the machinery
of production and exchange most highly developed--we find
the deepest poverty, the sharpest struggle for existence,
and the most enforced idleness.
It is to the newer countries--that is, to the
countries where material progress is yet in its earlier
stages--that laborers emigrate in search of higher wages,
and capital flows in search of higher interest. It is in
the older countries--that is to say, the countries where
material progress has reached later stages--that
widespread destitution is found in the midst of the
greatest abundance. Go into one of the new communities
where Anglo-Saxon vigor is just beginning the race of
progress;
- where the machinery of production and exchange is
yet rude and inefficient;
- where the increment of wealth is not yet great
enough to enable any class to live in ease and
luxury;
- where the best house is but a cabin of logs or a
cloth and paper shanty, and the richest man is forced
to daily work
and though you will find an absence of wealth and all
its concomitants, you will find no beggars. There is no
luxury, but there is no destitution. No one makes an easy
living, nor a very good living; but every one can make a
living, and no one able and willing to work is oppressed
by the fear of want.
But just as such a community realizes the
conditions which all civilized communities are striving
for, and advances in the scale of material progress--just
as closer settlement and a more intimate connection with
the rest of the world, and greater utilization of
labor-saving machinery, make possible greater economies
in production and exchange, and wealth in consequence
increases, not merely in the aggregate, but in proportion
to population--so does poverty take a darker
aspect. Some get an infinitely better and easier
living, but others find it hard to get a living at. The
"tramp" comes with the locomotive, and alms houses and
prisons areas surely the marks of "material progress" as
are costly dwellings, rich warehouses, and magnificent
churches. Upon streets lighted with gas and controlled by
uniformed policemen, beggars wait for the passer-by, and
in the shadow of college, and library, and museum, are
gathering the more hideous Huns and fiercer Vandals of
whom Macaulay prophesied.
This fact--the great fact that poverty and
all its concomitants show themselves in communities just
as they develop into the conditions towards which
material progress tends--proves that the social
difficulties existing wherever a certain stage of
progress has been reached, do not arise from local
circumstances, but are, in some way or another,
engendered by progress itself.
And, unpleasant as it may be to admit it, it is at
last becoming evident that the enormous increase in
productive power which has marked the present century and
is still going on with accelerating ratio, has no
tendency to extirpate poverty or to lighten the burdens
of those compelled to toil. It simply widens the gulf
between Dives
and Lazarus, and makes the struggle for existence
more intense. The march of invention has clothed mankind
with powers of which a century ago the boldest
imagination could not have dreamed. But
- in factories where labor-saving machinery has
reached its most wonderful development, little children
are at work;
- wherever the new forces are anything like fully
utilized, large classes are maintained by charity or
live on the verge of recourse to it;
- amid the greatest accumulations of wealth, men die
of starvation, and puny infant suckle dry breasts;
- while everywhere the greed of gain, the worship of
wealth, shows the force of the fear of want.
The promised land flies before us like the mirage. The
fruit of the tree of knowledge turn as we grasp them to
apples of Sodom that crumble at the touch.
It is true that wealth has been greatly increased, and
that the average of comfort, leisure, and refinement has
been raised; but these gains are not general. In them the
lowest class do not share.* I do not mean that the
condition of the lowest class has nowhere nor in anything
been improved; but that there is nowhere any improvement
which can be credited to increased productive power. I
mean that the tendency of what we call material progress
is in no wise to improve the condition of the lowest
class in the essentials of healthy, happy human life.
Nay, more, that it is to still further depress the
condition of the lowest class. The new forces,
elevating in their nature though they be, do not act upon
the social fabric from underneath, as was for a long time
hoped and believed, but strike it at a point intermediate
between top and bottom. It is as though
an immense wedge were being forced, not underneath
society, but through society. Those who are above the
point of separation are elevated, but those who are below
are crushed down.
[* It is true that the poorest may now
in certain ways enjoy what the richest a century ago
could not have commanded, but this does not show
improvement of condition so long as the ability to
obtain the necessaries of life is not increased. The
beggar in a great city may enjoy many things from
which the backwoods farmer is debarred, but that does
not prove the condition of the city beggar better
than that of the independent farmer.]
This depressing effect is not generally realized, for
it is not apparent where there has long existed a class
just able to live. Where the lowest class barely lives,
as has been the case for a long time in many parts of
Europe, it is impossible for it to get any lower, for the
next lowest step is out of existence, and no tendency to
further depression can readily show itself. But in the
progress of new settlements to the conditions of older
communities it may clearly be seen that material progress
does not merely fail to relieve poverty--it actually
produces it. In the United States it is clear that
squalor and misery, and the vices and crimes that spring
from them, everywhere increase as the village grows to
the city, and the march of development brings the
advantages of the improved methods of production and
exchange. It is in the older and richer sections of
the Union that pauperism and distress among the working
classes are becoming most painfully apparent. If there
is less deep poverty in San Francisco than in New York,
is it not because San Francisco is yet behind New York in
all that both cities are striving for? When San Francisco
reaches the point where New York now is, who can doubt
that there will also be ragged and barefooted children on
her streets? ...
read the entire chapter
Henry George: The Condition of Labor
— An Open Letter to Pope Leo XIII in response to
Rerum Novarum (1891)
That it does mean this and nothing else is confirmed
if we look deeper still, and inquire not merely as to the
intent, but as to the purpose of the intent. If we do so
we may see in this natural law by which land values
increase with the growth of society not only such a
perfectly adapted provision for the needs of society as
gratifies our intellectual perceptions by showing us the
wisdom of the Creator, but a purpose with regard to the
individual that gratifies our moral perceptions by
opening to us a glimpse of his beneficence.
Consider: Here is a natural law by which as society
advances the one thing that increases in value is land
— a natural law by virtue of which all growth of
population, all advance of the arts, all general
improvements of whatever kind, add to a fund that both
the commands of justice and the dictates of expediency
prompt us to take for the common uses of society.
Now, since increase in the fund available for the
common uses of society is increase in the gain that goes
equally to each member of society, is it not clear that
the law by which land values increase with social advance
while the value of the products of labor does not
increase, tends with the advance of civilization to make
the share that goes equally to each member of society
more and more important as compared with what goes to him
from his individual earnings, and thus to make the
advance of civilization lessen relatively the differences
that in a ruder social state must exist between the
strong and the weak, the fortunate and the
unfortunate? Does it not show the purpose of the
Creator to be that the advance of man in civilization
should be an advance not merely to larger powers but to a
greater and greater equality, instead of what we, by our
ignoring of his intent, are making it, an advance toward
a more and more monstrous inequality? ... read the whole
letter
Nic Tideman: The Case for Taxing Land
I. Taxing Land as Ethics and
Efficiency
II. What is Land?
III. The simple efficiency argument for
taxing land
IV. Taxing Land is Better Than
Neutral
V. Measuring the Economic Gains from
Shifting Taxes to Land
VI. The Ethical Case for Taxing Land
VII. Answer to Arguments against Taxing
Land
There is a case for taxing land based on ethical
principles and a case for taxing land based on efficiency
principles. As a matter of logic, these two cases
are separate. Ethical conclusions follow from
ethical premises and efficiency conclusions from
efficiency principles. However, it is natural for
human minds to conflate the two cases. It is easier
to believe that something is good if one knows that it is
efficient, and it is easier to see that something is
efficient if one believes that it is good.
Therefore it is important for a discussion of land
taxation to address both question of efficiency and
questions of ethics.
This monograph will first address the efficiency case for taxing land, because that
is the less controversial case. The efficiency case
for taxing land has two main parts.
...
To estimate the magnitudes of the impacts that
additional taxes on land would have on an economy, one
must have a model of the economy. I report on
estimates of the magnitudes of impacts on the U.S.
economy of shifting taxes to land, based on a
mathematical model that is outlined in the
Appendix.
The ethical case for
taxing land is based on two ethical premises:
...
The ethical case for taxing land ends with a
discussion of the reasons why recognition of the equal
rights of all to land may be essential for world
peace.
After developing the efficiency argument and the
ethical argument for taxing land, I consider a variety of
counter-arguments that have been offered against taxing
land. For a given level of other taxes, a rise in
the rate at which land is taxed causes a fall in the
selling price of land. It is sometimes argued that
only modest taxes on land are therefore feasible, because
as the rate of taxation on land increases and the selling
price of land falls, market transactions become
increasingly less reliable as indicators of the value of
land. ...
Another basis on which it is argued that greatly
increased taxes on land are infeasible is that if land
values were to fall precipitously, the financial system
would collapse.
...
Apart from questions of feasibility, it is
sometimes argued that erosion of land values from taxing
land would harm economic efficiency, because it would
reduce opportunities for entrepreneurs to use land as
collateral for loans to finance their
ideas. ...
.
Another ethical argument that is made against
taxing land is that the return to unusual ability is
“rent” just as the return to land is
rent.
...
But before developing any of these arguments, I
must discuss what land is.
...
The simple efficiency argument
for taxing land
A tax creates a difference, a ‘wedge’,
between the price that a buyer pays and the price that
the seller receives. Sometimes the wedge generated
by a tax is enough to inhibit a transaction that would
otherwise occur. If the tax that must be paid on a
transaction is greater than the gains from trade that
would accrue in the absence of a tax, then the tax
precludes any mutually advantageous trade. Thus
taxes often reduce economic efficiency. ...
Read the
whole article
Fred Foldvary: Underprivileged or
Rights-Deprived?
Poor folk are often labeled "underprivileged" and
richer folk are called "privileged." For example, there
is a book titled "One Nation,
Underprivileged: Why American Poverty Affects Us
All." But "privileged" and "underprivileged" are
confused and misleading expressions. If you think the
poor are "underprivileged," then you don't really
understand poverty.
What is a "privilege?" The term originally meant
"private law." A privilege is a special advantage or
prerogative or immunity or benefit given only to some
people only because they have power or are favored by
those with power. If everyone is entitled to something,
like freedom of expression, or if everyone may obtain an
item such as a passport with the same rules applying to
all, then it is not a privilege but a
right.
Whether a rich person is "privileged" depends on
how he got the money.
...
So if a person is poor, it is not because he is
lacking in special protections, subsidies, and other
privileges. A person is usually poor because he has been
deprived of the natural right to work. Governments
world-wide impose barriers between labor and productive
resources, keeping some workers deprived of labor and
others who do work deprived of their earnings from
labor.
Taxes on wages create a wedge
between the cost of labor to employers and the take-home
pay of the worker. More costly labor results in less
employment. Taxes on the income from capital goods
and on the sale of goods has the same effect. There are
unemployment taxes, disability taxes, and payroll taxes
that increase the tax wedge. On top of that, there are
minimum-wage laws that prevent the least productive
workers from getting hired. There are permits, zoning,
and other rules and costs that also prevent some workers
from becoming self-employed.
Deprived of the full natural right to peaceful
enterprise and labor, and the natural right to fully keep
one's earnings, the poor have little or no income, and
depend on charity and governmental assistance. To call
them "underprivileged" is a lie. The rights-deprived poor
do not need privileges. They just need government to stop
interfering with their right to work and
save!
The biggest privilege world-wide is subsidies to
landowners. ...
There has been confusion about what is a right and
what is a privilege. ...
Some consider a patent a privilege, but it too is
a right. ...
Some also consider a corporation to be a
privilege, since the firm has a charter from a
government. ...
Real privileges are favors arbitrarily given to
some groups and not others.
...
The really underprivileged folks are all
consumers, taxpayers and those who are restricted from
peaceful and honest practices or have to pay extra to the
government while others are unrestricted and non-taxed.
These people lack privileges which others have.
The proper remedy is not to expand
privileges, but to eliminate all governmental privileges.
That is why libertarians and geoists alike have the
motto: "Equal rights for all; privileges for
none!" Read the whole
article
Kris Feder: Progress and Poverty
Today
As this book was written, the Industrial
Revolution was transforming America and Europe at a
breathless pace. In just a century, an economy that
worked on wind, water, and muscular effort had become
supercharged by steam, coal, and electricity. Canals,
railroads, steamships and the telegraph were linking
regional economies into a national and global network of
exchange. The United States had stretched from coast to
coast; the western frontier was evaporating.
American journalist and editor Henry George
marveled at the stunning advance of technology, yet was
alarmed by ominous trends. Why had not this unprecedented
increase in productivity banished want and starvation
from civilized countries, and lifted the working classes
from poverty to prosperity? Instead, George saw that the
division of labor, the widening of markets, and rapid
urbanization had increased the dependence of the
working poor upon forces beyond their control. The
working poor were always, of course, the most vulnerable
in depressions, and last to recover from them.
Unemployment and pauperism had appeared in America, and
indeed, were more prevalent in the developed East than in
the aspiring West. It was "as though a great wedge were
being forced, not underneath society, but through
society. Those who are above the point of separation are
elevated, but those who are below are crushed down."
This, the "great enigma of our times," was the problem
George set out to solve in Progress and
Poverty. Read the
whole article
Mason Gaffney: Introduction: The Power
of Neo-classical Economics (Introduction to
The Corruption of Economics,
London: Shepheard-Walwyn, 1994)
Voters faced with two candidates, each coached
by a neo-classical economist, also face a hard choice.
They often appear apathetic and take a third choice,
staying home. However, history denies that voters are
intrinsically apathetic. They have gotten turned on by
candidates who try to lead up and away from dismal
trade-offs.
In 1980 it was Ronald Reagan.
Instead of the dismal Phillips Curve ("choose inflation
or unemployment") he offered the happy Laffer Curve:
lower tax rates would lead to higher supplies, higher
revenues, and lower deficits, he promised. Lowering
taxes, said Laffer, would eliminate the "wedge effect."3 He often cited Henry George in support of
his position.4
Thus he would unleash supply, and collect more taxes
while applying lower tax rates. The voters were sick of
2nd-generation Keynesians who had been reduced to
preaching austerity, so they were game (if not wise) to
buy into Reaganomics as advertised.
Unfortunately, the Laffer Curve turned
out to be wildly overoptimistic, and Reaganomics partly
fraudulent and hypocritical5 in application. The voters again
tuned out and seemed apathetic. They are not saying,
however, they don't care. They are saying "come back
when you have something better, mean what you say, and
deliver what you promise." ...
A state, provincial, or local government can
finance generous public services without driving away
business or population. The
formula is simple: tax land, which cannot migrate,
instead of capital and people, which can. By
eliminating the destructive "Wedge Effect," the land
tax lets us support schools and parks and libraries and
water purification and police and fire protection,
etc., as generously as you please, without suppressing
or distorting useful work, and without taxing investors
in real capital. ...
Read
the whole
article
Mason Gaffney: George's Economics of
Abundance: Replacing dismal choices with practical
resolutions and synergies
Micro "structural" reform coupled with
macro reform
A weakness of Keynesian policy is its scorn for
structural reform, e.g. combating monopolies and sticky
markets. It relies solely on Federal fiscal policy. Its
focus is so narrow that even monetary policy, which seems
so closely allied in spirit, is regarded as rival rather
than complementary. Thus, when inflation pricked the
Keynesian bubble, there was little left to offer except
the dismal Phillips Curve trade-off.
Georgist policy improves the structure
of the economy in at least five ways.
a. It erases the "wedge effect"
of indirect taxes, while maintaining tax revenues.
This might be called a "True Laffer Curve effect" - what
Laffer and Reagan promised in 1980, but Reagan could not
deliver. The wedge effect is both warping, and, in the
aggregate, anti-incentive.
b. It actually lubricates the
land market in the very process of extracting more tax
revenues from it. It is better than "neutral"
(lacking in wedge effects). It subjects landowners to a
cash drain that is more potent than mere "opportunity
cost" in prompting landowners to put land to its "highest
and best use," i.e. to allocate it optimally in the
manner prescribed by economic theory. The writer has
developed this point elsewhere.
c. It combats monopoly restriction of output by
making it costlier to withhold land from use. Likewise,
it combats monopsonistic exploitation of
workers.
d. It unlocks urban land
markets that are frozen up by the tendency of firms to
buy and hold land for possible future expansion.
This is a form of vertical integration which, like all
withholding actions, is self-reinforcing and
self-validating, hence cumulative in its impact. That is,
if A and B are tying up surplus land for their possible
future needs, that forces C, D, and E to do the same
because they cannot rely on the open market to supply the
land when and if needed. A fortiori, speculative
preemptors who hold key parcels to profit from others
attempts to assemble buildable parcels, or to compete in
key markets, force others to do likewise in self-defense.
The pooling function of the free market is impaired.
Conversely, the gains from correcting such market
failures are also self-reinforcing and cumulative,
providing us with many "free lunches."
e. It makes landownership more
available to small business, and new businesses, by
lowering the market price of land. It substitutes
a deferred annual charge for a high price up front. This
has the same effect as extending credit to all market
agents on identical terms, thus offsetting the otherwise
overpowering bias of credit rationing and discrimination
in lending. Large surpluses of land are released to the
market as the tax cost of withholding land forces it to
be sold.
It should be apparent that each of those effects
helps markets work they way competitive theory says they
should. Their aggregate effect is overwhelming.
Some Georgists have made their case on
structural grounds alone. We have seen, however, that these
are in addition to the macro effects. ...
10. Making labor cheaper to hire
without lowering wage rates
Georgist policy removes the many big
tax wedges between worker and employer, and employer and
customer, and worker and consumable goods. Thus labor can
cost the employer less, while the worker gets more
disposable income after-tax. Many economists inveigh
against the minimum wage, claiming it overprices labor. It
is a matter of suspicion that they are then silent on the
deadly effects of the payroll tax, which affects workers at
all levels. Sales taxes, too, cut into real wages, yet many
of these same economists would raise sales taxes and
introduce VAT. President and Mrs. Clinton now speak
seriously of raising payroll taxes even more, to finance
the new health plan.
There is a high elasticity of demand
for labor. This may be observed in farming, for example,
where landowners have avoided union wage rates simply by
shifting their land from fresh fruits and vegetables to
labor-sparing uses like small grains or cotton. Conversely,
removing the payroll tax burden will move owners to shift
land back into labor-using enterprises.... read the whole article
Mason Gaffney: Rent, Taxation,
Dissipation and Federalism
Dissipating rent via public
spending
A. Taxes and lease provisions need not
twist incentives.
1. At worst taxes destroy incentives only at the
margins: the "wedge
effect."
2. Taxes may be structured to zero in on
taxable surplus while sparing the margins. An obvious
and well-discussed case is a tax based on land value,
or putative rent, imposed as a flat charge unaffected
by landowner production.
3. Taxes in excess of benefits received have
positive incentive effects on landowners.
a. The wealth effect
b. The liquidity or cash-drain
effect.
c. The effect of offsetting credit
discrimination and rationing (land is cheaper to buy,
hence less credit is needed, and taxes are or may be
non-discriminatory among potential
owners.)
So it is not taxation per se that dissipates
rent, even though ill-structured taxes do destroy some
rent. ...
Read the
whole
article
|
To share this page with a friend:
right click, choose "send," and add your
comments.
|
|
Red links have not been
visited; .
Green links are pages you've seen
|
Essential Documents pertinent
to this theme:
|
|