Three-Factor Economics
Louis Post: Outlines
of Louis F. Post's Lectures, with Illustrative Notes and
Charts (1894)
Wealth is produced solely by the application of Labor
to Land.51
50. It may at first seem like a great
waste of time and space to have gone through this long
analysis for no other purpose at last than to
demonstrate the self-evident fact that land and labor
are the sole original factors in the production of
Wealth. But it will have been no waste if it enables
the reader to firmly grasp the fact. Nothing is more
obvious, to be sure. Nothing is more readily assented
to. Yet by layman and college professor and economic
author alike, this simple truth is cast adrift at the
very threshold of argument or investigation, with
results akin to what might be expected in physics if
after recognizing the law of gravitation its effects
should be completely ignored.
51. There is ample authority among
economic writers for this conclusion.
Professor Ely enumerates Nature, Labor,
and Capital as the factors of production, but he
describes Capital as a combination of Nature and Labor
— Ely's Introduction, part ii, ch. iii.
Say describes industry as " nothing more
or less than human employment of natural agents."
— Say's Trea., book i, ch. ii.
And though John Stuart Mill and numerous
others speak of Land, Labor, and Capital as the three
factors of production, as does Professor Jevons, most
of them, like Jevons, recognize the fact, though in
their reasoning they often fail to profit by it, that
Capital is not a primary but a secondary requisite. See
Jevons's Pol. Ec., secs. 16, 19.
Henry George says: "Land, labor, and
capital are the factors of production. The term land
includes all natural opportunities or forces; the term
labor, all human exertion; and the term capital, all
wealth used to produce more wealth. . . Capital is not
a necessary factor in production. Labor exerted upon
land can produce wealth without the aid of capital, and
in the necessary genesis of things must so produce
wealth before capital can exist." — Progress and
Poverty, book iii, ch. i.
Also : "The complexities of production in
the civilized state, in which so great a part is borne
by exchange, and so much labor is bestowed upon
materials after they have been separated from the land,
though they may to the unthinking disguise, do not
alter the fact that all production is still the union
of the two factors, land and labor."— Id., ch.
viii.
This is the final analysis. In the union of Labor,
which includes all human effort,52 with Land, which
includes the whole material universe outside of man,53 we
discover the ultimate source of Wealth, which includes
all the material things that satisfy want.54 And that is
the first great truth upon which the single tax
philosophy is built.
52. The term labor includes all human
exertion in the production of wealth." — Progress
and Poverty, book i, ch. ii.
53. "The term land necessarily includes,
not merely the surface of the earth as distinguished
from the water and the air, but the whole material
universe outside of man himself, for it is only by
having access to land, from which his very body is
drawn, that man can come in contact with or use
nature." — Progress and Poverty, book i, ch.
ii.
54. "As commonly used the word 'wealth '
is applied to anything having exchange value. But ...
wealth, as alone the term can be used in political
economy, consists of natural products that have been
secured, moved, combined, separated, or in other ways
modified by human exertion, so as to fit them for the
gratification of human desires." — Progress and
Poverty, book i, ch ii.
... read the
book
Bill Batt: Painless
Taxation
Abstract Real tax reform could
do away with those taxes that are resented by the large
proportion of our population. We could replace all taxes
on wages and on interest by instead taxing economic rent.
Rent is windfall income; it is income that arises not
from the efforts of any person or corporation; it comes
about as a surplus gain from common social enterprise.
There is ample moral warrant for society to lay claim to
that which it has created, as well as to that which no
individual or party has earned. Analysis increasingly
makes clear that economic rent in all its forms is far
larger than official government figures indicate; in fact
it is likely sufficient to supplant all current taxes on
labor and capital (wages and interest) which are
acknowledged to have so many negative effects. Recovering
economic rent in all its manifestations by taxing its
various bases actually can foster economic performance
and yield other benefits that make it the natural source
of revenue for governments. Such a tax is essentially
painless. ...
The Tax Base
The next concern should be upon what base to impose a
tax — not about taxing whom but taxing what. There
are only three possibilities, as all revenue streams
necessarily come from one of three factors of economic
production —
1) upon resources found raw in nature (what was
classically called land),
2) upon our labor, or
3) upon things created by human hands or minds
(capital).
No other source exists; every possible tax must be on
one or some combination of these parts. Each of these
factors has its price: the price of land is counted in
economic rent; the price of labor is in wages, and the
price of capital (its liquid form) is in interest.
Any tax on capital has its downside effects, so that
taxing savings causes people to save less, taxing
consumption causes people to buy less, and taxing
buildings causes people to build less. The result is that
economists as well as businessmen usually frown upon
taxing capital. Another alternative is to tax labor, but
it is even more widely understood that taxing labor
normally discourages people from working as much as they
would in the absence of a tax. From this comes sentiment
against taxing labor, even though for want of any
alternative, people have today commonly come to accept it
as a necessity. But electing to tax labor, just as for
taxing capital, forecloses a discussion of the virtues of
taxing land — not necessarily land as earth, but
rather land as location. Yet land rent is the most
attractive tax base of all, as rent is not earned; it is
windfall income, entirely the result of being well
situated in any market of scarce natural resources and
where community demand (rather than one's own efforts)
leads to an appreciation of that land's price. To be sure
many people have learned to position themselves in
situations where a land's market value is likely to rise
— indeed these people come to think of themselves
as astute investors. But the fact is that that market
gain is not of their own doing at all; it is the result
of common enterprise creating a surplus that comes to
settle on land sites. An investment in land, in any form
it might take, is speculation in greater or lesser
degree.
Land in all its forms is a tax base that also conforms
well to all the classic principles of sound tax theory as
enumerated above. Land is classically taken to mean not
just surfaces of the earth but places in time, in space,
in any medium whether it be solid, liquid or gas, and
even as a form of light, in the electromagnetic spectrum,
and in life forms. One needs to return to 19th century
classical economic definitions of the factors of
production to appreciate the separate significance of
land as it was understood in its manifold forms. One
should ask how it is that land, so important to 19th
century classical economic theory, has been given so
little attention today in neoclassical economics. This is
a story only now recovered from the dusty archives of
academic economic history. Once understood and
appreciated, it may be one of the greatest, if very
silent, political revolutions of world
history.[4] ... read the whole
article
Bill Batt: The
Compatibility of Georgist Economics and Ecological
Economics
The starting point of the Georgist framework is
rigorous definition of the three factors of production
— land, labor, and capital, as in classical
economics. It should be further pointed out that these
factors are mutually exclusive and jointly exhaustive of
all things of economic value. Something must necessarily
be in one category or another; there is nothing
outside this total
classification. Understanding of what constitutes labor
differs little from definitions given elsewhere,
regardless of which theory is used. But definitions of
land and capital differ somewhat from common practice as
well as sometimes in theory. Therefore, it is helpful to
spend time explicating the definitions of each as they
are used in Georgism, and to point out where these
definitions diverge from those most often employed in
neoclassical economics applications. Many contemporary
economics texts begin by taking note of the
land-labor-capital distinction, but then make little use
of it later. These distinctions will make apparent why
Georgist economics leads to very different explanations
of economic phenomena as well as to different policy
solutions.
Critical to an understanding of Georgist economics
is its recognition of land as a special and unique factor
of production. “Land,” to Georgists, as true
for classical economists throughout the 19th century, is
taken to mean not just the surface of the earth and
locational space; it means also any and all those natural
resources and non-human works that today can exact a
market price. It includes the wealth of the earth in all
its natural forms, the air and water as well as material
elements. It includes phenomena of value like the
electromagnetic spectrum used to transmit communications
signals, and landing time slots such as have value at
airports. As the world economies enter a new age of high
technology, these radio spectrums and time allotments
have gained ever increasing value. So also with
geosychronous satellite orbits and most recently the
genetic codes of all the biota on
earth.10 ...
read the
whole article
Bill Batt: How Our
Towns Got That Way (1996 speech)
As recently as a century ago classical economic
thought still regarded land for the most part as the
common heritage of mankind. From Adam Smith, through
Thomas Malthus, David Ricardo, and finally with John
Stuart Mill economic productivity was regarded as a
function of three interacting factors: land, labor, and
capital. John Locke also accepted these premises. To
achieve optimal economic productivity, one had to exact
the appropriate price from each of those factors. The
price of labor was in wages; the price of capital was
interest; and the price of land, particularly following
the thinking of David Ricardo, was rent. Rent in its
classical sense means payment for the use of something in
fixed supply, or, more generally, payments above the
costs incurred for its creation. Disequilibriums and
inefficiencies in economic development resulted if the
appropriate prices were not paid for each factor. But, as
we shall see, there were powerful interests in this
country, bent on not seeing any rent extracted from land
use, that persuaded the nascent economics profession at
the end of the 19th century no longer to regard land as a
separate factor and to redefine the terms of production
instead in two-factor theory. This was concurrent with
the inclusion of land as property, since called "real
property."
As land came to be transferred to other nobility
and usurped under title in fee simple rather than in
usufruct, it came to be regarded as a private financial
asset. Earlier it was regarded as part of nature, much
like air, water, wind and weather. Accounting practices
now listed land as an asset "owned" in fee simple, and as
a liability on the other side of balance sheets in money
"owed" to banks. This tendency has been extended today so
that we have privatized much of our air, water, wind, and
even sunlight. Land came to be simply one kind of
capital, nothing special, nothing requiring further
treatment. Ricardo's Law of Rent became an artifact of
intellectual history. The conflation of land into capital
to create two-factor economics is one of the greatest
paradigm shifts in the evolution of social philosophy.
How the premises and terms of economic discourse have
been changed has been documented for the first time in a
new book by a California professor of economics, Mason
Gaffney. The account is put forth in fascinating detail
entitled, The Corruption of
Economics. It was indeed a corruption of a
discipline, a deliberate putsch by powerful economic
forces with an interest in seeing such definitions
changed, and we have all been paying the price since that
time. This revealing thesis is what I really want to
relate to you, and to explain the dire consequences it
has had for us in our contemporary world. I have come to
believe it; it makes sense to me, both historically and
in contemporary analysis, from several
perspectives.
The Corruption of
Economics
As I explained, classical economics emerged from a
school of thinkers known as the Scottish moralists in the
latter part of the 18th century. There ultimately evolved
three major schools of economic thought a century later,
one the continuing tradition of Adam Smith through J.S.
Mill, a second being the aggressive and emerging school
of Marxism, and the third a proposal for two-factor
economics being pressed largely by interests in America.
Marxism was never a major force in United States; the
primary challenge to the classical tradition came from
what has since come to be known as neo-classical
economics.
Professor Gaffney has for the first
time shown how powerful economic interests in American
society essentially bought the leading figures of the
newly- established American Economics Association with all
the blandishments that can be used to influence
academicians. Leading scholars were induced to change
definitions of terms so that special interests would be
advantaged. What were those interests? Primarily the
railroad industry, which at the time was probably the most
powerful political force in America. By changing
definitions and conflating the land factor into capital, it
was no longer essential for land rent to be paid in taxes,
and the railroads, holders of some of the most valuable
land in the nation, were thereby able to escape their full
duty. This is an astonishing story, one never fully spelled
out until now, and it explains both how the academic
community was beholden to powerful interests and how many
of the social problems we see today could have been
avoided.
The classical tradition of economic
thought was ably synthesized and represented by one
dominant figure of the age: Henry George. All but forgotten
today, perhaps in good part due to the assiduous
disparagement of his economic foes, one should note that he
was more widely known in his time in America than anyone
except Thomas Edison. His 1879 book, Progress and
Poverty, sold more copies throughout the world than
any book till that time except the Bible. Born in
Philadelphia the son of a publisher of religious books, he
traveled to California as a young man to make his fortune
as a journalist. But what he saw in land speculation and
the exploitation of labor soon led him to study the
classical economists and to write his ideas down. Upon
publication of his book he shortly became known throughout
the world, and traveled and lectured widely as a social
reformer for the rest of his life. By the time he died he
had become so famous that he almost won the mayoralty of
the city of New York. He ran twice, losing to Tammany Hall
the first time in what was probably a corrupt election (but
beating the third-place finisher, Theodore Roosevelt) in
1886, and died four days before a second election he might
have won in 1897. As a spellbinding orator and lucid
writer, he captivated the world with his vision of
societies made more just by a proper understanding of
economics. Gaffney shows that it was George, not Marx, that
was the primary threat to dominant interests in
end-of-century United States. He had to be stopped, and he
was.
In classical economics, the
definition of capital grew out of labor mixed with earlier
capital. Land, by conventional definition, was not capital,
nor was it a component of wealth. Rather land was its own
category. Conflating land into capital allowed land rent to
be hidden and diluted in ways so that the unearned
increment arising from social improvements fell to
speculators rather than being returned to society in rent.
The failure of society to recapture the appropriate level
of land rent from titleholders led also to depression of
labor wages at the margin, creating poverty and artificial
scarcity of labor where otherwise it could be relieved.
Hence the title of George's book, Progress
and Poverty. George recognized that the value of any
land parcel arose out of its social activity, not from
anything which a titleholder might have done to it. He
recognized that many, perhaps most, titleholders in land
were speculators, reaping the benefit of others'
investments, and selling out at last when their price was
met. Hence it made sense that society had a right to a
return on what it had brought about, as well as from the
fact that those titles could never be other than
leaseholds. That land rent, shortly confused by use of the
words "single tax," was, to George, the rightful return to
society.
The railroad barons of the 19th
century were not just coincidentally the land barons. They
also had strong holds on the founding and growth of the
major American universities of the period, some of which
carry their names. Johns Hopkins, Andrew Dickson White,
Daniel Gilman, John D. Rockefeller, George Leland Stanford,
Nicholas Murray Butler were all as attached to various
universities in the country as they were to powerful
railroad interests. They were able, through their control
of universities either as actual presidents or as
benefactors, to influence the dominant figures responsible
for establishing the American Economic Association in 1885.
The actual intrigue is too complex to be recounted here:
who got appointed and promoted, who was funded in research,
which were given endowed chairs, who got stock options, and
so on. The preoccupation with defeating Henry George,
Gaffney shows, was a paramount preoccupation of all of
these figures. The central figures were:
- Francis Walker, first president of the AEA,
then President of MIT and Director of the Census
Bureau.
- Richard Ely, also founder of the AEA, and
professor of economics at University of Wisconsin and
later Northwestern, there granted his own Institute with
railroad money.
- John Bates Clark, Professor of Economics at
Columbia University, and whose patron was Julius Seelye,
President of Amherst College and then Smith
College.
- E.R.A. Seligman, Chairman of the Economics
Department at Columbia University and scion of a wealthy
banking family.
These figures are even today the
honored founders of an esteemed profession. So great was
their victory over rival schools of thought that they are a
century later seen as paragons of clear thinking and
virtue. The intrigue and the inside deals are long
forgotten. The lineage to contemporary scholarship
continues in a "chain unbroken from Seelye to Clark to
Johnson to Knight to Stigler, Friedman, Harberger and now
thousands of Chicago-oriented economists." Indeed, when
Henry George ran for mayor of New York in 1897, it was
against the wealthy patrician Seth Low, President of
Columbia University, who had recently recruited Clark to
come to Columbia. To really understand the academic tension
of the period, one must look at the published papers, the
speeches and debates, the newspaper articles, and the
citations at the end of those articles. These, even more
than the interlocking directorates of faculty appointments,
explain how much George was opposed, perhaps more feared.
Was it for the falsity of his views? Clearly not, as few
critics then or since then have managed to strike a
knock-out blow against his theories. Rather, it was the
threat George represented to powerful interests that
required him to be defeated, and in doing so they
succeeded but only in the short run, as they were within
decades victims of their very successes. Today we see that
the railroads have failed in this country for lack of
traffic. It will soon be evident why.
There were many arguments to be made
for the classical tradition, the result of which would be
to rely upon payment of rent of land according to its value
to society. George recognized that land value is largely a
function of how society has elected to invest in any
general neighborhood; there is no argument for any one
titleholder to reap the reward of what others have
invested. Gaffney points out that, from the standpoint of
economic theory, the framework had the following
virtues:
- It reconciled common land rights with private
tenure, free markets and modern capitalism, a growing and
persistent problem as the industrial society took
hold.
- It enabled the lowering of taxes on labor
without raising taxes on capital.
- It reconciled equity and efficiency. It
constituted a progressive tax because land is
concentrated so much among the wealthy and because the
tax cannot be shifted. It was efficient because it is
neutral among different land-use options.
- It constituted no disincentive to business
location or population settlement. In this way it
encouraged the most efficient land use and discouraged
sprawl.
- It created jobs without inflation, and raised
government revenue without any penalty upon its
base.
- It strengthened public revenues and at the
same time promotes economy in government.
Those economists who today still
persistently hold to the view that there is something
special about land that make it unwise to treat as a form
of capital are known as Georgists. They represent a small
minority of the economics profession, but, little known as
they are, they are among its most esteemed
members.
Two-factor
economics, however, had advantages to influential
individuals and special interests. Land speculators
who were positioned to profit from knowing where locational
values would increase, or were in a position to cause those
increases, could quickly and easily reap a private gain.
Simply by holding title to parcels of real property,
without doing anything at all to increase their value, one
could quickly turn a profit. This is because the increment
of unearned increases resulting from social investments
were left for owners to reap rather than recovered by
society. In three-factor economics, land
rent reverted to society in an automatic and efficient
manner. When a railroad magnate like George Leland Stanford
extended the Southern Pacific track to the east of Los
Angeles on land that he was granted by the government, all
he then needed to do was to sit back and wait for the land
sales to give him a return on that which was made more
valuable by his investment in the line. All across America,
land speculators learned that capturing monopoly titles to
tracts of land allowed them to quickly and easily turn a
"profit" on their investment yet hardly raising a
finger.... read the whole article
Bill Batt: Who Says Cities
are Poor? They Just Don't Know How to Tax Their
Wealth!
The premises of discourse
What is most called for today is a return to basic
analysis. Elementary economics starts with the
recognition that there are three factors of production in
the creation of social wealth. Each of those factors are
mutually exclusive and, taken together, are jointly
exhaustive of all sources of market value. The first of
these is what classical economics from Adam Smith on
called land. Land meant every aspect of nature to which
industry can be applied; it meant not just locations of
space but air, water, and mineral wealth. Today sunlight,
radio waves, and even time, on occasion, would be added.
The second factor of production is labor, referring quite
simply to the effort applied by people's minds or bodies
to land. The third factor is the product of past
application of land and labor to current production:
capital. Each factor in classical economics has its
price, the product of which is the creation of wealth as
we commonly understand it. The price of labor is wages;
the price of capital is interest, and the price of land
is rent. Rent, as understood in economics, is not payment
for the use of property owned by others; it has, rather,
a more technical meaning, one which will require greater
explication below.
We have largely lost sight of these basic premises of
economic thought, and it has led to our general inability
to address the urban challenge of taxation with a
perspective that offers an easy solution. Returning to
these fundamental building blocks makes things much
simpler and more comprehensible. Labor continues to be
easily understood; its meaning has not changed in the
course of a shift from classical to neoclassical economic
thought. But capital, which had earlier encompassed only
those creations that were the result of human
enterprise— the product of labor and land, has now
been redefined to include land. Land by itself in
contemporary neoclassical economics has dropped out of
the equation altogether, and so for the most part has the
concept of economic rent.[4] Mathematical
formulas in neoclassical economics are entirely
changed.
There is good reason, however, to recover the use of
the terms land and rent as they were employed in 19th
century classical economics: rent is the surplus produced
by the collective enterprise that can provide the
necessary revenue to easily support public services, if
it were only collected in the form of taxes.[5] In fact, by
shifting taxes off labor and capital and onto land rent,
the performance of markets would be made fully efficient
and would be essentially painless to taxpayers. This is
the thesis I am arguing here, and which is now possible
to demonstrate with the advent of computer power and
available data. It amplifies and validates what has been
for a century only a plausible theoretical claim. We can
now show that collecting economic rent can provide for
all the services demanded of cities and avail themselves
of the proper tax base that exceeds all
others.[6] And unlike
other taxes there is no downside impact; in fact it's
positive. Economic rent is the surplus created by the
community, and it circulates through the markets until it
ultimately comes to settle on land sites.[7] The result of
its accretion to land sites is to raise their market
price. Economic rent is sometimes called land rent or
ground rent for this reason, and comes about not through
any titleholder's individual enterprise but by the
consequence rather of society's collective effort.
British political economist David Ricardo first conceived
of land rent in terms of its relationship to agricultural
production in the early 1800s, but its applicability
today is understood far more easily with regard to the
site values in cities. Whereas ground rent to Ricardo
reflected the differential gifts of nature inherent in
various land sites, it is today better understood as
reflective of locational differentials in the capacities
of communities. ... read
the whole article
|
To share this page with a friend:
right click, choose "send," and add your
comments.
|
|
Red links have not been
visited; .
Green links are pages you've seen
|
Essential Documents pertinent
to this theme:
essential_documents
|
|