1
2
3
Wealth and Want | |||||||
... because democracy alone is not enough to produce widely shared prosperity. | |||||||
Home | Essential Documents | Themes | All Documents | Authors | Glossary | Links | Contact Us |
Mason Gaffney: Henry George 100 Years Later: The Great Reconciler
Neo-classical economists give us only a hard
choice: we may have equity, or efficiency, but not both.
By contrast, George's program reconciles equity and
efficiency. Think of it! George takes two polar
philosophies, collectivism and individualism, and
composes them into one solution. He cuts the Gordian
knot. Like Keynes after him, George inspires us by
saying, "Forget the bitter tradeoffs; we can have it
all!" ... read
the whole article
Mason Gaffney: Neo-classical Economics as a Stratagem Against Henry George
Neoclassical economics is the idiom of most
economic discourse today. It is the paradigm that bends
the twigs of young minds and confines the florescence of
older ones, like mesh wire around a topiary. It took form
a century ago, when Henry George and his reform proposals
were a clear and present political danger and challenge
to the landed and intellectual establishments of the
world. Few people realize to what a degree the founders
of Neoclassical economics changed the discipline for the
express purpose of deflecting George, discomfiting his
followers, and frustrating future students seeking to
follow his arguments. The stratagem was semantic: to
destroy the very words in which he expressed himself.
Simon Patten expounded it succinctly. "Nothing pleases a
... single taxer better than ... to use the well-known
economic theories ... [therefore] economic doctrine must
be recast" (Patten 1908, p.219; Collier, 1979,
p.270).1 ...
Having taken shape in the 1880-1890s, Neo-Classical Economics (henceforth NCE) remained remarkably static. Major texts by Marshall, Seligman, and Richard T. Ely, written in the 1890s, went through many reprintings each over a period of 40 years with few if any changes. "It was for the Chautauqua Literary and Scientific Circle (1884) that I wrote the first edition of my Outlines, under the title Introduction to Political Economy. In this first edition of the Outlines there is to be found the general philosophy and principles that have shaped all future editions, including that of 1937" (Ely, 1938, p.81).2
Not until 1936 was there another major
"revolution," and that was hived off into a separate
compartment, macro-economics, and contained there so as
not to disturb basic tenets of NCE. Compartmentalization,
we will see in several instances, is the common NCE
defense against discordant data and reasoning.
...
Neo-classical economics makes an ideal of "choice." That sounds good, and liberating, and positive. In practice, however, it has become a new dismal science, a science of choice where most of the choices are bad. "TANSTAAFL" (There Ain't No Such Thing As A Free Lunch) is the slogan and shibboleth. Whatever you want, you must give up something good. As an overtone there is even a hint that what one person gains he must take from another. The theory of gains from trade has it otherwise, but that is a heritage from the older classical economists. Henry George, in contrast, had a genius for reconciling-by-synthesizing. Reconciling is far better than merely compromising. He had a way of taking two problems and composing them into one solution, as we lay out in detail infra. He took two polar philosophies, collectivism and individualism, and synthesized a plan to combine the better features, and discard the worse features, of each. He was a problem-solver, who did not suffer incapacitating dilemmas and standoffs.
As policy-makers, neo-classical economists present
us with "choices" that are too often hard dilemmas. They
are in the tradition of Parson Malthus, who preached to
the poor that they must choose between sex or food. That
was getting right down to grim basics, and is the origin
of a well-earned epithet, "the dismal science." Most
modern neo-classicals are more subtle (although the
fascist wing of the otherwise admirable ecology movement
gets progressively less so). Here are some dismal
dilemmas that neo-classicals pose for us today. For
efficiency we must sacrifice equity; to attract business
we must lower taxes so much as to shut the libraries and
starve the schools; to prevent inflation we must keep an
army of unfortunates unemployed; to make jobs we must
chew up land and pollute the world; to motivate workers
we must have unequal wealth; to raise productivity we
must fire people; and so on.
The neo-classical approach is the
"trade-off." A trade-off is a compromise. That has a ring
of reasonableness to it, but it presumes a zero-sum
condition. At the level of public policy, such "trade-offs"
turn into paralyzing stand-offs, where no one gets nearly
what he wants, or could get. It overlooks the possibility
of a reconciliation, or synthesis,
instead. In such a resolution, we are not
limited by trade-offs between fixed A and B: we get more of
both. ... read the
whole essay Mason Gaffney: California's Governor-Elect
Joseph Stiglitz: October, 2002, interview
Frank Stilwell and Kirrily Jordan: The Political Economy of Land: Putting Henry George in His Place
Mason Gaffney: Land as a Distinctive Factor of Production
Another thing libertarian philosophers must paper
over is the rent-seeking that occurs in the creation of
private tenures. They avidly push privatization as
a grand Panacea, but ignore the process of privatization
and its consequences. Private tenure is often
granted under customs that make it a prize for occupying
or fixing some capital on land, and continuing to operate
it with "due diligence" ("use it or lose it").
Premature investment, settlement and development are
frequent results, seriously distorting the allocation of
land, labor and capital and contributing to the
"Congested Frontier" problem (cf.
B-2.)
Some assets that are privatized in this way, dejure or defacto, include
The tolerance of neo-classically-trained
libertarian economists for such distortions knows no
bounds nor shame. A current example in California
is their push to convert conditional water licenses into
permanent property rights. They would give the
present licensees perpetual, alienable property not just
in the water, but in past and ongoing government
subsidies to build and operate the water distribution
system. ... Consuming land means preempting its time To consume most goods and services is to use them up. Land is not used up. "Consuming" land must have some other meaning, therefore, than the intuitive and common idea that consuming means turning-to-waste. To consume land is rather to preempt its service flow without impairing its substance. To consume land is to occupy it for a time-slot, which may be as brief as beating a red light or (rarely) as long as the pyramids last. After us life goes on, on the land once left to us which we then leave to others. "Time-sharing" was not invented by the holiday industry but is inherent in the nature of land and life. How shall we measure land-consumption by owners, where no rent is paid? Is it purely subjective? Does it vary with the owner's mood and health? It is simpler than that, and fully practicable. The essence of consuming land is preempting the time-slot from others. Thus, holding land without using it, or using it below capacity, is a form of consumption. The measure is the market opportunity cost of land, i.e. the price times the interest rate. Holding an urban site has been likened to holding a reserved seat at a play, sporting event, or concert. The ticket holder properly helps pay for the event, whether or not he is there to enjoy it. As a result, very few paid customers fail to show up. Likewise, people who pay cash rent for land seldom leave it vacant. Doubtless if people paid regular cash taxes to hold land, they, too, would consume (preempt) less. Proponents of "consumer taxation" almost universally overlook this point. I am not aware of one who has proposed including land-consumption in the tax base. Aaron and Galper, propounding a "cash-flow tax," explicitly allow for letting each succeeding owner expense land purchase, effectively exempting land rents from taxation 100%. Theirs, and other proposals, and consumer taxes actually imposed now and in the past, bear heavily on the necessities of median families. We deride the salt tax of the French ancien regime, and of pre-Ghandian India. We recognize them as instruments of tyranny and class warfare, even as we tolerate modem legislators who impose comparable burdens on ourselves, and economists who rationalize such taxes by belittling the necessities of life. Doing so, they compound the deception in the label "consumer taxation". Much of what is taxed in the name of taxing consumers is actually used for capital formation: human capital formation. The same economists who say human beings are or contain capital, turn around and tell us to tax the formation and maintenance of such capital, by calling it "consumption'. Coupling this with their proposed exemption of land-consumption we have the ultimate victory and application of semantic cleansing. Inconstancy, thy name is -- neoclassical economist? ... read the whole article Mason Gaffney: Economics in Support of Environmentalism
The Dereliction
of Economists
There is another kind of fundamentalist, the private property kind. The economics profession (my tribe) has, in recent years, largely abdicated its proper role as an arbitrator and gone over mainly to the side of private-property extremism. This is the essential meaning of "Neo-classical Economics," which is the idiom of most discourse in the field today, both in business and in the profession. How did economics get so twisted? Don't blame Adam Smith, or David Ricardo, or John Stuart Mill, or John E. Cairnes, or Knut Wicksell, or Philip Wicksteed, sterling 19th Century writers. Rather, blame J.B. Clark, Karl Marx, Richard T. Ely, Alvin Johnson, Frank Fetter, Frank Knight, George Stigler, and a host of lesser figures who gradually warped economics into its present form. How did they do it? ... Private property: from means to end In a proper view of things, I submit, private property is a means to an end. It is not an end in itself; it needs a functional rationale. The end is to get land put to the best use. All the private land in the world was originally granted by some sovereign public person or body, mainly for that purpose, not as a welfare entitlement. Landowners and their lawyers have slyly, over time, turned the means into an end, a fetish they endow with "sanctity." This is a term they borrowed from absolutist medieval theology. "Sanctity" means the quality or state of being holy or sacred, hence inviolable. It means property may not be challenged, or even questioned. It has become an end in itself, its own voucher. You're not even supposed to think about it, it is above thought. Taboo! Neoclassical economics, historically, marked the final, total surrender of the profession to this fetish. The modern economist's view runs something like this: "I pledge allegiance to the 14th Amendment, and to the overinterpretation of private landowner supremacy for which it has come to stand." It is ironic to recall that Radical Republicans passed that Amendment, at a time when a "Radical Republican" was one who favored freeing the slaves. The 14th Amendment was designed to protect the rights of freedmen. As interpreted now, the 14th Amendment means that The Emancipation Proclamation itself was unconstitutional! Fortunately, no one has brought that case - yet. The Neo-classical economists' view of their proper role is rather like that in The Realtor's Oath, which includes a vow "To protect the individual right of real estate ownership." The word "individual" is construed broadly to include corporations, estates, trusts, anonymous offshore funds, schools, government agencies, institutions, partnerships, cooperatives, the Duke of Westminster, the Sultan of Brunei, the Medellin Cartel, Saddam Hussein, congregations, Archbishops, families (including criminal families) and so on, but "individual" sounds more all-American and subsumes them all. This is a potent chant that stirs people to extremes of self-righteousness and siege mentality when challenged. The resemblance between Neo-classical economics and the Realtor's Oath is easier to understand when you learn that Professor Richard T. Ely, founder of the modern discipline of Land Economics, was heavily subsidized by the National Association of Real Estate Boards, the utilities, the major landowning railroads, and others of like mind and property interests. When it comes to violating property rights, air pollution today is perhaps the greatest invader and confiscator of property. Where do economists stand? Once a few of them tried to say, following A.C. Pigou, "let the polluter pay," and in parts of Europe they still do. In our modern backward thinking here at home, however, it's not the polluter who is invading the property of others, nor the human rights of those not owning property. Rather, when you tell them to stop, the government is invading their rights. The wage-earning taxpayers must pay them to stop, else you are violating both the 14th Amendment and the "Coase Theorem," a rationalization for polluting now dearly beloved by Neo-classical economists. ... read the whole article Bill Batt: How Our Towns Got That Way (1996 speech)
The Corruption of
Economics
As I explained, classical economics emerged from a school of thinkers known as the Scottish moralists in the latter part of the 18th century. There ultimately evolved three major schools of economic thought a century later,
Marxism was never a major force in United States;
the primary challenge to the classical
tradition came from what has since come to be known as
neo-classical economics.
Professor Gaffney has for the first time shown how powerful economic interests in American society essentially bought the leading figures of the newly- established American Economics Association with all the blandishments that can be used to influence academicians. Leading scholars were induced to change definitions of terms so that special interests would be advantaged. What were those interests? Primarily the railroad industry, which at the time was probably the most powerful political force in America. By changing definitions and conflating the land factor into capital, it was no longer essential for land rent to be paid in taxes, and the railroads, holders of some of the most valuable land in the nation, were thereby able to escape their full duty. This is an astonishing story, one never fully spelled out until now, and it explains both how the academic community was beholden to powerful interests and how many of the social problems we see today could have been avoided. The classical tradition of economic thought was ably synthesized and represented by one dominant figure of the age: Henry George. All but forgotten today, perhaps in good part due to the assiduous disparagement of his economic foes, one should note that he was more widely known in his time in America than anyone except Thomas Edison. His 1879 book, Progress and Poverty, sold more copies throughout the world than any book till that time except the Bible. Born in Philadelphia the son of a publisher of religious books, he traveled to California as a young man to make his fortune as a journalist. But what he saw in land speculation and the exploitation of labor soon led him to study the classical economists and to write his ideas down. Upon publication of his book he shortly became known throughout the world, and traveled and lectured widely as a social reformer for the rest of his life. By the time he died he had become so famous that he almost won the mayoralty of the city of New York. He ran twice, losing to Tammany Hall the first time in what was probably a corrupt election (but beating the third-place finisher, Theodore Roosevelt) in 1886, and died four days before a second election he might have won in 1897. As a spellbinding orator and lucid writer, he captivated the world with his vision of societies made more just by a proper understanding of economics. Gaffney shows that it was George, not Marx, that was the primary threat to dominant interests in end-of-century United States. He had to be stopped, and he was. In classical economics, the definition of capital grew out of labor mixed with earlier capital. Land, by conventional definition, was not capital, nor was it a component of wealth. Rather land was its own category. Conflating land into capital allowed land rent to be hidden and diluted in ways so that the unearned increment arising from social improvements fell to speculators rather than being returned to society in rent. The failure of society to recapture the appropriate level of land rent from titleholders led also to depression of labor wages at the margin, creating poverty and artificial scarcity of labor where otherwise it could be relieved. Hence the title of George's book, Progress and Poverty. George recognized that the value of any land parcel arose out of its social activity, not from anything which a titleholder might have done to it. He recognized that many, perhaps most, titleholders in land were speculators, reaping the benefit of others' investments, and selling out at last when their price was met. Hence it made sense that society had a right to a return on what it had brought about, as well as from the fact that those titles could never be other than leaseholds. That land rent, shortly confused by use of the words "single tax," was, to George, the rightful return to society. The railroad barons of the 19th century were not just coincidentally the land barons. They also had strong holds on the founding and growth of the major American universities of the period, some of which carry their names. Johns Hopkins, Andrew Dickson White, Daniel Gilman, John D. Rockefeller, George Leland Stanford, Nicholas Murray Butler were all as attached to various universities in the country as they were to powerful railroad interests. They were able, through their control of universities either as actual presidents or as benefactors, to influence the dominant figures responsible for establishing the American Economic Association in 1885. The actual intrigue is too complex to be recounted here: who got appointed and promoted, who was funded in research, which were given endowed chairs, who got stock options, and so on. The preoccupation with defeating Henry George, Gaffney shows, was a paramount preoccupation of all of these figures. The central figures were:
These figures are even today the honored founders of an esteemed profession. So great was their victory over rival schools of thought that they are a century later seen as paragons of clear thinking and virtue. The intrigue and the inside deals are long forgotten. The lineage to contemporary scholarship continues in a "chain unbroken from Seelye to Clark to Johnson to Knight to Stigler, Friedman, Harberger and now thousands of Chicago-oriented economists." Indeed, when Henry George ran for mayor of New York in 1897, it was against the wealthy patrician Seth Low, President of Columbia University, who had recently recruited Clark to come to Columbia. To really understand the academic tension of the period, one must look at the published papers, the speeches and debates, the newspaper articles, and the citations at the end of those articles. These, even more than the interlocking directorates of faculty appointments, explain how much George was opposed, perhaps more feared. Was it for the falsity of his views? Clearly not, as few critics then or since then have managed to strike a knock-out blow against his theories. Rather, it was the threat George represented to powerful interests that required him to be defeated, and in doing so they succeeded but only in the short run, as they were within decades victims of their very successes. Today we see that the railroads have failed in this country for lack of traffic. It will soon be evident why. There were many arguments to be made for the classical tradition, the result of which would be to rely upon payment of rent of land according to its value to society. George recognized that land value is largely a function of how society has elected to invest in any general neighborhood; there is no argument for any one titleholder to reap the reward of what others have invested. Gaffney points out that, from the standpoint of economic theory, the framework had the following virtues:
Those economists who today still persistently hold to the view that there is something special about land that make it unwise to treat as a form of capital are known as Georgists. They represent a small minority of the economics profession, but, little known as they are, they are among its most esteemed members. Two-factor economics, however, had
advantages to influential individuals and special
interests. Land speculators who were positioned to profit
from knowing where locational values would increase, or
were in a position to cause those increases, could quickly
and easily reap a private gain. Simply by holding title to
parcels of real property, without doing anything at all to
increase their value, one could quickly turn a profit. This
is because the increment of unearned increases resulting
from social investments were left for owners to reap rather
than recovered by society. In three-factor economics, land
rent reverted to society in an automatic and efficient
manner. When a railroad magnate like George Leland Stanford
extended the Southern Pacific track to the east of Los
Angeles on land that he was granted by the government, all
he then needed to do was to sit back and wait for the land
sales to give him a return on that which was made more
valuable by his investment in the line. All across America,
land speculators learned that capturing monopoly titles to
tracts of land allowed them to quickly and easily turn a
"profit" on their investment yet hardly raising a
finger.... read the whole
article Bill Batt: The Compatibility of Georgist Economics and Ecological Economics
There are many indications that the
paradigm that has dominated orthodox economic theory for
the past century, what has come to be called neoclassical
economics, is disintegrating.1 This has led many economics
students, as well as others interested in the power and
promise this discipline holds, to look once more at the
genesis of its theory and to attempt reformulations of
its basic premises. Marxism has also ceased to be a
viable alternative, perhaps more due to the failure of
its institutional applications than to the failings of
the theory itself. Only one other longstanding economics
tradition has survived continuing scrutiny and remains a
recognizable and venerable legacy to the present time.
This is the tradition that has come to be known as
Georgism. The Georgist tradition has seen a profound
revival during the past decade and warrants a comparison
with other upstart economics frameworks that have reached
the level of separate identity.2
...
The next important step in understanding Georgist economics is recognition that each factor of production has its economic price: the price of labor is wages, the price of capital is interest, and the price of land is rent. When any of these prices are unpaid, distortions result in the economic equilibrium and problems become manifest in other realms of nature and society. In neoclassical economics compensation for the use of labor and capital continue to be important in the formulas and calculations employed to explain the economy. But for neoclassical economics, David Ricardo’s “law of rent” is essentially ignored and has be come for all practical purposes an artifact in the history of economics. Rent continues to exist of course; it is simply uncollected, left in the hands of those who maintain monopoly control of certain services of nature, adding to their market value in ways that distort the balance of markets. Failure to recognize the importance of land rent (sometimes called economic rent) is for Georgists critical to an understanding of the problems of contemporary economies and economic analysis.14 ... It is far easier to outline the basic premises of Georgist economics than it is to do so for the emerging field of ecological economics. Georgism is a tradition that grew out of a clearly formed tradition of 19th century classical economics and has been refined further for the past century. It was neoclassical economics that diverged from the reigning orthodoxy. The differences between the classical tradition as represented and defended by Henry George and the emerging neoclassical school were vividly portrayed from their earliest divergence, even to the staging of formal debates between George and the new orthodoxy’s adherents. 75 In contrast, ecological economics along with other emerging heterodox schools is itself very much a reaction to the neoclassical tradition’s insensitivities and failures. The differences between ecological economics and the floundering discipline of neoclassical economics are as much by way of the former’s criticism of the latter as they are an enunciation of clear starting points. To be sure, neoclassical economics emerged gradually over a period of some fifty years, and only reached its heyday, one might argue, with the arrival of Paul Samuelson. Samuelson, the MIT economist whose text has gone through some 16 editions and has outsold all other text combined once said, “I don’t care who writes a nation’s laws . . . if I can write its economics textbooks.” 76 The neoclassical position developed ever greater abstract mathematical applications, with models ever more detached from “real world” market forces. This system of analysis now has reached a point of questionable utility due to its hermetic and Newtonian emulations.77 Little by little, one premise and formula after another have been cast aside, to a point now that there is a broad recognition among economic theorists at least that the discipline faces an intellectual crisis.78
78Economist Albert O. Hirschman of the
Princeton Institute for Advanced Study begins one book,
Essays on Trespassing (New York: Cambridge University
Press, 1981,) page v, with a quote from the Russell
Sage
Foundation’s current view:
. . . the discipline[of economics] became
progressively more narrow at precisely the moment when
the problems demanded broader, more political, and social
insights. (From Russell Sage Foundation, Annual Report,
1979, New York, 1980, p. 12.)
Without enumerating further criticisms that have been levied against neoclassical economic thinking, something that has been done far better elsewhere than is possible here, suffice it to say that some of the most compelling charges have been made by the ecological economists.79 The most trenchant one as explicated by economist Nicholas Georgescu-Roegen is its violation of the basic laws of physics.80 It assumes a continuing draw-down of the earth’s store of energy, of which there is, of course, only a finite amount. If the economy continues to expand to include all elements of the earth, it will consume so many resources, particularly energy resources, that ultimately life itself is destroyed. One study calculated that if everyone in the world lived at the level of the average American, three “earths” would be necessary to accommodate us all. 81 The challenge, argue the ecological economists, is to structure economic analysis and the economy itself in such a way that markets are contained and that existence outside economic reach is respected and preserved. Whereas other studies of the environment within the framework of conventional neoclassical economics attempt to price nature in a way that its value is assured, ecological economists work from the conviction that such an approach is questionable if not futile, as it can never achieve any accurate and reliable market values for such existence.82 ... read the whole article Mason Gaffney: Interview: Is There a Conspiracy in the Teaching of Economics and History within the American Education System? TPR - For an economics professor, you're said to be quite an expert on the environment, what's the connection? MG - Economic analysis, properly used, can serve the cause of environmentalism. The neo-classical economists abused both economics and the environment badly, as a byproduct of their drive to discredit classical political economy, and Henry George. John Bates Clark wrote that land is not scarce, that mankind can convert capital into land without limit, and create as much as we please. He wrote that natural resources have no value to mankind until and unless they are privatized; that privatization itself is what creates value. Our universities churn out thousands of new economists yearly, imbued with such attitudes. When Rachel Carson kicked off the new environmentalism in 1962 with her "Silent Spring," most economists trashed or disdained her: they 'd been trained that way. Faced with the obvious growth of environmental sentiment, economists dealt with it as they have with other problems: they absorbed it in the discipline, then marginalized it. Now they can say it is part of economics, while they proceed to ignore or trivialize it in their major policy pronouncements, wherein endless territorial expansion continues to be not just a goal, but a necessity to make the system work. The legitimate goals of environmentalists, they coopt and distort. Here are two examples.
Thank you, John B. Clark; thank you,
neo-classical economics. It all follows from Clark's
efforts to avoid any recognition that natural resources are
common property: in this case, the air itself is turned
into private property. Your very right to breathe, you have
to buy from major owners of the air. And how did they
establish that ownership? By their track records of dumping
their crud in the air in the past. It beggars belief, but
there it is: it shows what the war against Henry George has
made of the discipline of economics.... read the
whole article
Mason Gaffney: Introduction: The Power
of Neo-classical Economics
Neoclassical economics is the idiom of most
economic discourse today. It is the paradigm that bends
the twigs of young minds and confines the florescence of
older ones, like mesh wire around a topiary. It took form
a century ago, when Henry George and his reform proposals
were a clear and present political danger and challenge
to the landed and intellectual establishments of the
world. Few people realize to what a degree the founders
of Neoclassical economics changed the discipline for the
express purpose of deflecting George, discomfiting his
followers, and frustrating future students seeking to
follow his arguments. The stratagem was semantic: to
destroy the very words in which he expressed himself.
Simon Patten expounded it succinctly. "Nothing pleases a
... single taxer better than ... to use the well-known
economic theories ... [therefore] economic doctrine must
be recast."
George believed economists were recasting the discipline to refute him. He states so, as though in the third person, in his last book, The Science of Political Economy (George, 1898, pp.200-209). George's self-importance was immodest, it is true. However, immodesty may be objectivity, as many great talents from Frank Lloyd Wright to Muhammed Ali and Frank Sinatra have displayed. George had good reasons, which we are to demonstrate. George's view may even strike some as paranoid. That was this writer's first impression, many years ago. I have changed my view, however, after learning more about the period, the literature, and later events.
Having taken shape in the 1880-1890s,
Neo-Classical Economics (henceforth NCE) remained
remarkably static. Major texts by Marshall, Seligman, and
Richard T. Ely, written in the 1890s, went through many
reprintings each over a period of 40 years with few if
any changes. "It was for the Chautauqua Literary and
Scientific Circle (1884) that I wrote the first edition
of my Outlines, under the title
Introduction to Political
Economy. In this first edition of the Outlines there is to be found the general
philosophy and principles that have shaped all future
editions, including that of 1937" (Ely, 1938,
p.81).2
Not until 1936 was there another major "revolution," and that was hived off into a separate compartment, macro-economics, and contained there so as not to disturb basic tenets of NCE. Compartmentalization, we will see in several instances, is the common NCE defense against discordant data and reasoning. After that came another 40 years of Samuelson's "neoclassical synthesis." J.B. Clark's treatment of rent, dating originally from his obvious efforts to refute Henry George (see below), "has been followed by an admiring Paul Samuelson in all of the many editions of his Economics" (Dewey, p.430). Clark's capital theory "... gives the appearance of being specially tailored to lead to arguments for use against George" (Collier, 1979, p.270). "The probable source from which immediate stimulation came to Clark was the contemporary single tax discussion" (Fetter, 1927, p.142). "To date, capital theory in the Clark tradition has provided the basis for virtually all empirical work on wealth and income" (Dewey, 1987, p.429; cf. Tobin, 1985). Later writers have added fretworks, curlicues and arabesques beyond counting, and achieved more isolation from history, and from the ground under their feet, than in Patten's dreams, but all without disturbing the basic strategy arrived at by 1899, tailored to lead to arguments against Henry George. To most modern readers, probably George seems too minor a figure to have warranted such an extreme reaction. This impression is a measure of the neo-classicals' success: it is what they sought to make of him. It took a generation, but by 1930 they had succeeded in reducing him in the public mind. In the process of succeeding, however, they emasculated the discipline, impoverished economic thought, muddled the minds of countless students, rationalized free-riding by landowners, took dignity from labor, rationalized chronic unemployment, hobbled us with today's counterproductive tax tangle, marginalized the obvious alternative system of public finance, shattered our sense of community, subverted a rising economic democracy for the benefit of rent-takers, and led us into becoming an increasingly nasty and dangerously divided plutocracy. The present paper purports to identify the elements of Neo-Classical Economics (NCE) that were planted there to sap and confound George, and show how they continue to warp, debase and vitiate much of the discipline called economics. Once a paradigm is well-ensconced it becomes a power in itself, a set of reflexes to sort the true and false. Any exception spoils the web of interpretation through which art seeks to make human experience intelligible. Only the young, the brave, the energetic, the sincere and the skeptical can break off such fetters. This work is addressed and dedicated to them. ... Thus, to the rent-taker, the typical college trustee or regent, George's ideas remained a real and present danger over several decades: the very decades when neo-classical economics was spreading through the academic clerisy.16 With the development of direct democracy, open primaries, the secret ballot, direct election of U.S. Senators, the Initiative, Referendum, and Recall, and the like, crude vote-buying such as prevailed in the late 19th Century would no longer dominate the electorate. Mind-control became the urgent need; NCE was the tool. ... Read the whole article Bill Batt: Comment on Parts of the NYS Legislative Tax Study Commission's 1985 study “Who Pays New York Taxes?”
Bill Batt: Fallacies of the Slippery Slope Argument
Some explanations reflect downright
corruption. The earliest cars manufactured in this
country and in Europe were electric; streetcars also were
largely electric powered until a conspiracy of the
automobile and petroleum industry exerted its force to
ensure that fossil fuel powered motor vehicles would
dominate our transportation and land use
patterns.15 Our
motor-vehicle-dependent and urban sprawl configurations
can be explained by powerful interests continually
pressing for policies to make us so. One might even
conclude that the decision to drive on the right side of
the road was equally as much a defining
moment.
15 This is an untold story. A trial was
held in a Chicago federal court in 1949, resulting in an
indictment of GM, Firestone, Standard Oil, Phillips
Petroleum, and Mack Trucks among others. Their crime was
in forming a holding company called National City Lines
which proceeded in the preceding decade to buy up the
public transportation services in dozens of US cities,
and then scrapping them so that people would then become
more automobile dependent. The corporations were fined
$5,000 each, and the CEOs of each one $1. See United
States Senate, Committee on the Judiciary, 93rd Congress,
2nd Session, “American Ground Transport: A Proposal
for Restructuring the Automobile, Truck, Bus, and Rail
Industries,” by Bradford C. Snell, February 26,
1974 (Washington: US Government Printing Office, 1974);
and Jonathan Kwitney, “The Great Transportation
Conspiracy,” Harper’s Magazine, February,
1981.
And I hope that you will forgive me for mentioning another great conspiracy in American history, the subject of my Torch presentation about four years ago. That story recounted how the American railroad industry, in collusion with the banks, induced the founders of the American economics profession to change definitions and formulas so that they would be relieved of taxation on their land holdings and speculation would be rewarded.16 This dividing line between classical and neoclassical economics is responsible I believe for many of our economic problems today — economic cycles, an inequitable tax structure, poverty and unemployment, urban sprawl and the gutting of urban centers. Only now is this economic ideology, almost sacrosanct for a century, falling apart and seen for what it is. ... read the whole article |
|
to email this page to a friend: right click, choose
"send"
|
||||||
Wealth and Want
|
www.wealthandwant.com
|
|||||
... because democracy alone hasn't yet led to a society
in which all can prosper
|