The Causes of Poverty
Twice a week, I receive an e-mail from an
institute at a major ("public ivy") university
devoted to poverty research. It provides links
to articles in newspapers all over the U.S. about the
effects of poverty and various attempts to ease its
effects, particularly on children. I search it
in vain for any awareness that poverty is largely
caused by how we structure our economy — the
privatization of land value and natural
resources. All the little bandages our society
thinks to apply to try to reduce poverty's
effects are far less
effective than striking at the root of poverty.
But then again, maybe a major university —
public or private — wouldn't want to be caught
rocking the boat. Their funding could be hurt. (See
Upton Sinclair.)
And if we can't correctly and accurately identify
the causes of poverty, the measures we adopt to
reduce it are doomed to fail.
Place one hundred men on an island from which
there is no escape, and whether you make one of
these men the absolute owner of the other
ninety-nine, or the absolute owner of the soil of
the island, will make no difference either to him
or to them. In the one case, as the other, the one
will be the absolute master of the ninety-nine
— his power extending even to life and death,
for simply to refuse them permission to live upon
the island would be to force them into the sea.
Upon a larger scale, and through more complex
relations, the same cause must operate in the same
way and to the same end — the ultimate
result, the enslavement of laborers, becoming
apparent just as the pressure increases which
compels them to live on and from land which is
treated as the exclusive property of others ...
read the
whole chapter
Henry George: Salutatory, from
the first issue of The Standard (1887)
I begin the publication of this paper in response to
many urgent requests, and because I believe that there
is a field for a journal that shall serve as a focus
for news and opinions relating to the great movement,
now beginning, for the emancipation of labor by the
restoration of natural rights.
The generation that abolished chattel slavery is
passing away, and the political distinctions that grew
out of that contest are becoming meaningless. The work
now before us is the abolition of industrial slavery.
What God created for the use of all should be
utilized for the benefit of all; what is produced by
the individual belongs rightfully to the individual.
The neglect of these simple principles has brought upon
us the curse of widespread poverty and all the evils
that flow from it. Their recognition will abolish
poverty, will secure to the humblest independence and
leisure, and will lay abroad and strong foundation on
which all other reforms may be based. To secure the
full recognition of these principles is the most
important task to which any man can address himself
today. It is in the hope of aiding in this work that I
establish this paper.
I believe that the Declaration of Independence is not a
mere string of glittering generalities. I believe that
all men are really created equal, and that the securing
of those equal natural rights is the true purpose and
test of government. And against whatever law, custom or
device that restrains men in the exercise of their
natural rights to life, liberty, and the pursuit of
happiness I shall raise my voice. ... read the whole
column
Henry George: The Crime of
Poverty (1885 speech)
There is a cause for this poverty; and, if you
trace it down, you will find its root in a primary
injustice. Look over the world today — poverty
everywhere. The cause must be a common one. You cannot
attribute it to the tariff, or to the form of
government, or to this thing or to that in which
nations differ; because, as deep poverty is common to
them all the cause that produces it must be a common
cause. What is that common cause? There is one sufficient cause that is common to all
nations; and that is the appropriation as the property
of some of that natural element on which and from which
all must live. ...
Why, look all over this country —
look at this town or any other town. If men only took
what they wanted to use we should all have enough; but
they take what they do not want to use at all. Here are
a lot of Englishmen coming over here and getting titles
to our land in vast tracts; what do they want with our
land? They do not want it at all; it is not the land
they want; they have no use for American land. What
they want is the income that they know they can in a
little while get from it. Where does that income come
from? It comes from labour, from the labour of American
citizens. What we are selling to these people is our
children, not land.
Poverty! Can there be any doubt of its cause?
Go, into the old countries — go into western
Ireland, into the highlands of Scotland — these
are purely primitive communities. There you will find
people as poor as poor can be — living year after
year on oatmeal or on potatoes, and often going hungry.
I could tell you many a pathetic story. Speaking to a
Scottish physician who was telling me how this diet was
inducing among these people a disease similar to that
which from the same cause is ravaging Italy (the
Pellagra), I said to him: "There is plenty of fish; why
don't they catch fish? There is plenty of game; I know
the laws are against it, but cannot they take it on the
sly?" "That," he said, "never enters their heads. Why,
if a man was even suspected of having a taste for trout
or grouse he would have to leave at
once."
There is no difficulty in discovering what makes
those people poor. They have no right to anything that
nature gives them. All they can make above a living
they must pay to the landlord. They not only have to
pay for the land that they use, but they have to pay
for the seaweed that comes ashore and for the turf they
dig from the bogs. They dare not improve, for any
improvements they make are made an excuse for putting
up the rent. These people who work hard live in hovels,
and the landlords, who do not work at all — oh!
they live in luxury in London or Paris. If they have
hunting boxes there, why they are magnificent castles
as compared with the hovels in which the men live who
do the work. Is there any question as to the cause of
poverty there?
Now go into the cities and what do you see! Why,
you see even a lower depth of poverty; aye, if I would
point out the worst of the evils of land monopoly I
would not take you to Connemara; I would not take you
to Skye or Kintire — I would take you to Dublin
or Glasgow or London. There is something worse than
physical deprivation, something worse than starvation;
and that is the degradation of the mind, the death of
the soul. That is what you will find in those
cities.
Now, what is the cause of that? Why, it is
plainly to be seen; the people driven off the land in
the country are driven into the slums of the cities.
For every man that is driven off the land the demand
for the produce of the workmen of the cities is
lessened; and the man himself with his wife and
children, is forced among those workmen to compete upon
any terms for a bare living and force wages down. Get
work he must or starve — get work he must or do
that which those people, so long as they maintain their
manly feelings, dread more than death, go to the
alms-houses. That is the reason, here as in Great
Britain, that the cities are overcrowded. Open the land
that is locked up, that is held by dogs in the manger,
who will not use it themselves and will not allow
anybody else to use it, and you would see no more of
tramps and hear no more of over-production. ...
read the whole speech
H.G. Brown: Significant
Paragraphs from Henry George's Progress & Poverty,
Chapter 5: The Basic Cause of Poverty (in the
unabridged:
Book V: The Problem Solved)
The truth is self-evident. Put to any one capable of
consecutive thought this question:
"Suppose there should arise from the English Channel
or the German Ocean a no man's land on which common
labor to an unlimited amount should be able to make
thirty shillings a day and which should remain
unappropriated and of free access, like the commons
which once comprised so large a part of English soil.
What would be the effect upon wages in England?"
He would at once tell you that common wages throughout
England must soon increase to thirty shillings a day.
And in response to another question, "What would be
the effect on rents?" he would at a moment's reflection
say that rents must necessarily fall; and if he thought
out the next step he would tell you that all this would
happen without any very large part of English labor
being diverted to the new natural opportunities, or the
forms and direction of industry being much changed;
only that kind of production being abandoned which now
yields to labor and to landlord together less than
labor could secure on the new opportunities. The great
rise in wages would be at the expense of rent.
Take now the same man or another — some
hardheaded business man, who has no theories, but knows
how to make money. Say to him: "Here is a little
village; in ten years it will be a great city —
in ten years the railroad will have taken the place of
the stage coach, the electric light of the candle; it
will abound with all the machinery and improvements
that so enormously multiply the effective power of
labor. Will, in ten years, interest be any higher?"
"Will the wages of common labor be any higher; will it
be easier for a man who has nothing but his labor to
make an independent living?"
He will tell you, "No; the wages of common labor
will not be any higher; on the contrary, all the
chances are that they will be lower; it will not be
easier for the mere laborer to make an independent
living; the chances are that it will be harder."
"What, then, will be higher?"
"Rent; the value of land. Go, get yourself a piece of
ground, and hold possession."
And if, under such circumstances, you take his
advice, you need do nothing more. You may sit down and
smoke your pipe; you may lie around like the lazzaroni
of Naples or the leperos of Mexico; you may go up in a
balloon, or down a hole in the ground; and without
doing one stroke of work, without adding one iota to
the wealth of the community, in ten years you will be
rich! In the new city you may have a luxurious mansion;
but among its public buildings will be an
almshouse.
In all our long investigation we have been advancing to
this simple truth: That as land is necessary to the
exertion of labor in the production of wealth, to
command the land which is necessary to labor, is to
command all the fruits of labor save enough to enable
labor to exist. ...
...For land is the habitation of man, the storehouse
upon which he must draw for all his needs, the material
to which his labor must be applied for the supply of
all his desires; for even the products of the sea
cannot be taken, the light of the sun enjoyed, or any
of the forces of nature utilized, without the use of
land or its products. On the land we are born, from it
we live, to it we return again — children of the
soil as truly as is the blade of grass or the flower of
the field. Take away from man all that belongs to land,
and he is but a disembodied spirit. Material
progress cannot rid us of our dependence upon land; it
can but add to the power of producing wealth from land;
and hence, when land is monopolized, it might
go on to infinity without increasing wages or improving
the condition of those who have but their
labor. It can but add to the value of land and
the power which its possession gives. Everywhere, in
all times, among all peoples, the possession of land is
the base of aristocracy, the foundation of great
fortunes, the source of power. ... read the whole
chapter
Henry George: Thou
Shalt Not Steal (1887 speech)
Poverty attributed to
overproduction; poverty in the midst of wealth; poverty
in the midst of enlightenment; poverty, when steam and
electricity and a thousand laborsaving inventions that
never existed in the world before have been called to
the aid of humanity. There is manifestly no good reason
for its existence, and it is time that we should do
something to abolish it.
There are not charitable
institutions enough to supply the demand for charity;
that demand seems incapable of being supplied. But
there are enough, at least, to show every thinking woman
and every thinking man that it is utterly impossible to
eradicate poverty by charity; to show everyone who will
trace to its root the cause of the disease that what is
needed is not charity, but justice — the conforming
of human institutions to the eternal laws of
right.
But when we propose this, when we
say that poverty exists because of the violation of
God’s laws, we are taunted with pretending to
know more than humans ought to know about the designs of
Omnipotence. They have set up for
themselves a god who rather likes poverty, since it
affords the rich a chance to show their goodness and
benevolence; and they point to the existence of poverty
as a proof that God wills it. Our reply is that
poverty exists not because of God’s will, but
because of humanity’s disobedience. We say that we
do know that it is God’s will that there should be
no poverty on earth, and that we know it as we may know
any other natural fact. ...
Crowded! Is it any wonder that people are
crowded together as they are in this city, when we see
other people taking up far more land than they can by
any possibility use, and holding it for enormous
prices? Why, what would have happened if, when these
doors were opened, the first people who came in had
claimed all the seats around them, and demanded a price
of others who afterwards came in by the same equal
right? Yet that is precisely the way we are treating
this continent.
That is the reason why people are huddled
together in tenement houses; that is the reason why
work is difficult to get; the reason that there seems,
even in good times, a surplus of labor, and that in
those times that we call bad, the times of industrial
depression, there are all over the country thousands
and hundreds of thousands of men tramping from place to
place, unable to find employment.
Not work enough! Why, what is work? Productive
work is simply the application of human labor to land,
it is simply the transforming, into shapes adapted to
gratify human desires, of the raw material that the
Creator has placed here. Is there not opportunity
enough for work in this country? Supposing that, when
thousands of men are unemployed and there are hard
times everywhere, we could send a committee up to the
high court of heaven to represent the misery and the
poverty of the people here, consequent on their not
being able to find employment.
What answer would we get? "Are your lands all in
use? Are your mines all worked out? Are there no
natural opportunities for the employment of labor?"
What could we ask the Creator to furnish us with that
is not already here in abundance? He has given us the
globe amply stocked with raw materials for our needs.
He has given us the power of working up this raw
material.
If there seems scarcity, if there is want, if
there are people starving in the midst of plenty, is it
not simply because what the Creator intended for all
has been made the property of the few? And in moving against this giant wrong, which
denies to labor access to the natural opportunities for
the employment of labor, we move against the cause of
poverty. ...
And is it not theft of the same kind
when people go ahead in advance of population and get
land they have no use whatever for, and then, as people
come into the world and population increases, will not
let this increasing population use the land until they
pay an exorbitant price?
That is the sort of theft on which
our first families are founded. Do that under the false
code of morality which exists here today and people will
praise your forethought and your enterprise, and will say
you have made money because you are a very superior
person, and that all can make money if they will only
work and be industrious! But is it not as clearly a
violation of the command: "Thou shalt not steal," as
taking the money out of a person’s
pocket?
"Thou shalt not steal."
That means, of course, that we ourselves must not steal.
But does it not also mean that we must not suffer anybody
else to steal if we can help it?
"Thou shalt not steal."
Does it not also mean: "Thou shalt not suffer thyself or
anybody else to be stolen from?" If it does, then we, all
of us, rich and poor alike, are responsible for this
social crime that produces poverty. Not merely the people
who monopolize the land — they are not to blame
above anyone else, but we who permit them to monopolize
land are also parties to the theft. ...
Supposing we are confronted with
those souls, what will it avail us to say that we
individually were not responsible for their earthly
conditions? What, in the spirit of the parable of
Matthew, would be the reply from the Judgment seat?
Would it not be: "I provided for them all. The earth
that I made was broad enough to give them room. The
materials that are placed in it were abundant enough
for all their needs. Did you or did you not lift up
your voice against the wrong that robbed them of their
fair share in the provision made for
all?"
"Thou shalt not steal!" It is theft, it is
robbery that is producing poverty and disease and vice
and crime among us. It is by virtue of laws that we
uphold; and those who do not raise their voices against
that crime, they are accessories.
There is no need for poverty in
this world, and in our civilization. There is a provision
made by the laws of the Creator which would secure to the
helpless all that they require, which would give enough
and more than enough for all social purposes. These
little children that are dying in our crowded districts
for want of room and fresh air, they are the disinherited
heirs of a great estate.
Did you ever consider the full
meaning of the significant fact that as progress goes on,
as population increases and civilization develops, the
one thing that ever increases in value is land?
Speculators all over the country appreciate that fact.
Wherever there is a chance for population coming;
wherever railroads meet or a great city seems destined to
grow; wherever some new evidence of the bounty of the
Creator is discovered, in a rich coal or iron mine, or an
oil well, or a gas deposit, there the speculator jumps
in, land rises in value, and a great boom takes place,
and people find themselves enormously rich without ever
having done a single thing to produce wealth.
... read the whole article
Henry George:
Progress & Poverty:
The Current Doctrine of Wages — Its
Insufficiency
Reducing to its most compact form the problem we
have set out to investigate, let us examine, step by
step, the explanation which political economy, as now
accepted by the best authority, gives of it.
The cause which produces poverty in the midst of
advancing wealth is evidently the cause which exhibits
itself in the tendency, everywhere recognized, of wages
to a minimum. Let us, therefore, put our inquiry into
this compact form:
Why, in spite of increase in productive
power, do wages tend to a minimum which will give
but a bare living? ...
read the entire chapter
Henry George: The Condition of Labor
— An Open Letter to Pope Leo XIII in response to
Rerum Novarum (1891)
... Your use, in so many passages of your
Encyclical, of the inclusive term
“property” or “private”
property, of which in morals nothing can be either
affirmed or denied, makes your meaning, if we take
isolated sentences, in many places ambiguous. But
reading it as a whole, there can be no doubt of your
intention that private property in land shall be
understood when you speak merely of private property.
With this interpretation, I find that the reasons you
urge for private property in land are eight. Let us
consider them in order of presentation. You urge:
1. That what is bought with rightful property is
rightful property. (RN, paragraph 5) ...
2. That private property in land proceeds from
man’s gift of reason. (RN, paragraphs 6-7.)
...
3. That private property in land deprives no one of the
use of land. (RN, paragraph 8.) ...
4. That Industry expended on land gives ownership in
the land itself. (RN, paragraphs 9-10.) ...
5. That private property in land has the support of the
common opinion of mankind, and has conduced to peace
and tranquillity, and that it is sanctioned by Divine
Law. (RN, paragraph 11.) ...
6. That fathers should provide for their children and
that private property in land is necessary to enable
them to do so. (RN, paragraphs 14-17.) ...
7. That the private ownership of land stimulates
industry, increases wealth, and attaches men to the
soil and to their country. (RN, paragraph 51.)
...
8. That the right to possess private property in land
is from nature, not from man; that the state has no
right to abolish it, and that to take the value of
landownership in taxation would be unjust and cruel to
the private owner. (RN, paragraph 51.) ...
1. That what is bought with rightful
property is rightful property. (5.)*
Clearly, purchase and sale cannot give, but can only
transfer ownership. Property that in itself has no
moral sanction does not obtain moral sanction by
passing from seller to buyer.
If right reason does not make the slave the property
of the slave-hunter it does not make him the property
of the slave-buyer. Yet your reasoning as to private
property in land would as well justify property in
slaves. To show this it is only needful to change in
your argument the word land to the word slave. It would
then read:
It is surely undeniable that, when a man engages in
remunerative labor, the very reason and motive of his
work is to obtain property, and to hold it as his own
private possession.
If one man hires out to another his strength or his
industry, he does this for the purpose of receiving in
return what is necessary for food and living; he
thereby expressly proposes to acquire a full and legal
right, not only to the remuneration, but also to the
disposal of that remuneration as he pleases.
Thus, if he lives sparingly, saves money, and
invests his savings, for greater security, in a slave,
the slave in such a case is only his wages in another
form; and consequently, a working-man’s slave
thus purchased should be as completely at his own
disposal as the wages he receives for his labor.
Nor in turning your argument for private property in
land into an argument for private property in men am I
doing a new thing. In my own country, in my own time,
this very argument, that purchase gave ownership, was
the common defense of slavery. It was made by
statesmen, by jurists, by clergymen, by bishops; it was
accepted over the whole country by the great mass of
the people. By it was justified the separation of wives
from husbands, of children from parents, the compelling
of labor, the appropriation of its fruits, the buying
and selling of Christians by Christians. In language
almost identical with yours it was asked, “Here
is a poor man who has worked hard, lived sparingly, and
invested his savings in a few slaves. Would you rob him
of his earnings by liberating those slaves?” Or
it was said: “Here is a poor widow; all her
husband has been able to leave her is a few negroes,
the earnings of his hard toil. Would you rob the widow
and the orphan by freeing these negroes?” And
because of this perversion of reason, this confounding
of unjust property rights with just property rights,
this acceptance of man’s law as though it were
God’s law, there came on our nation a judgment of
fire and blood.
The error of our people in thinking that what in
itself was not rightfully property could become
rightful property by purchase and sale is the same
error into which your Holiness falls. It is not merely
formally the same; it is essentially the same. Private
property in land, no less than private property in
slaves, is a violation of the true rights of property.
They are different forms of the same robbery; twin
devices by which the perverted ingenuity of man has
sought to enable the strong and the cunning to escape
God’s requirement of labor by forcing it on
others.
What difference does it make whether I merely own
the land on which another man must live or own the man
himself? Am I not in the one case as much his master as
in the other? Can I not compel him to work for me? Can
I not take to myself as much of the fruits of his
labor; as fully dictate his actions? Have I not over
him the power of life and death?
For to deprive a man of land is as certainly to kill
him as to deprive him of blood by opening his veins, or
of air by tightening a halter around his neck.
The essence of slavery is in empowering one man to
obtain the labor of another without recompense. Private
property in land does this as fully as chattel slavery.
The slave-owner must leave to the slave enough of his
earnings to enable him to live. Are there not in
so-called free countries great bodies of working-men
who get no more? How much more of the fruits of their
toil do the agricultural laborers of Italy and England
get than did the slaves of our Southern States? Did not
private property in land permit the landowner of Europe
in ruder times to demand the jus primae noctis? Does
not the same last outrage exist today in diffused form
in the immorality born of monstrous wealth on the one
hand and ghastly poverty on the other?
In what did the slavery of Russia consist but in
giving to the master land on which the serf was forced
to live? When an Ivan or a Catherine enriched their
favorites with the labor of others they did not give
men, they gave land. And when the appropriation of land
has gone so far that no free land remains to which the
landless man may turn, then without further violence
the more insidious form of labor robbery involved in
private property in land takes the place of chattel
slavery, because more economical and convenient. For
under it the slave does not have to be caught or held,
or to be fed when not needed. He comes of himself,
begging the privilege of serving, and when no longer
wanted can be discharged. The lash is unnecessary;
hunger is as efficacious. This is why the Norman
conquerors of England and the English conquerors of
Ireland did not divide up the people, but divided the
land. This is why European slave-ships took their
cargoes to the New World, not to Europe.
Slavery is not yet abolished. Though in all
Christian countries its ruder form has now gone, it
still exists in the heart of our civilization in more
insidious form, and is increasing. There is work to be
done for the glory of God and the liberty of man by
other soldiers of the cross than those warrior monks
whom, with the blessing of your Holiness, Cardinal
Lavigerie is sending into the Sahara. Yet, your
Encyclical employs in defense of one form of slavery
the same fallacies that the apologists for chattel
slavery used in defense of the other!
The Arabs are not wanting in acumen. Your Encyclical
reaches far. What shall your warrior monks say, if when
at the muzzle of their rifles they demand of some Arab
slave-merchant his miserable caravan, he shall declare
that he bought them with his savings, and producing a
copy of your Encyclical, shall prove by your reasoning
that his slaves are consequently “only his wages
in another form,” and ask if they who bear your
blessing and own your authority propose to
“deprive him of the liberty of disposing of his
wages and thus of all hope and possibility of
increasing his stock and bettering his condition in
life”? ...
5. That private property in land has the
support of the common opinion of mankind, and has
conduced to peace and tranquillity, and that it is
sanctioned by Divine Law. (11.)
Even were it true that the common opinion of mankind
has sanctioned private property in land, this would no
more prove its justice than the once universal practice
of the known world would have proved the justice of
slavery.
But it is not true. Examination will show that
wherever we can trace them the first perceptions of
mankind have always recognized the equality of right to
land, and that when individual possession became
necessary to secure the right of ownership in things
produced by labor some method of securing equality,
sufficient in the existing state of social development,
was adopted. Thus, among some peoples, land used for
cultivation was periodically divided, land used for
pasturage and wood being held in common. Among others,
every family was permitted to hold what land it needed
for a dwelling and for cultivation, but the moment that
such use and cultivation stopped any one else could
step in and take it on like tenure. Of the same nature
were the land laws of the Mosaic code. The land, first
fairly divided among the people, was made inalienable
by the provision of the jubilee, under which, if sold,
it reverted every fiftieth year to the children of its
original possessors.
Private property in land as we know it, the
attaching to land of the same right of ownership that
justly attaches to the products of labor, has never
grown up anywhere save by usurpation or force. Like
slavery, it is the result of war. It comes to us of the
modern world from your ancestors, the Romans, whose
civilization it corrupted and whose empire it
destroyed.
It made with the freer spirit of the northern
peoples the combination of the feudal system, in which,
though subordination was substituted for equality,
there was still a rough recognition of the principle of
common rights in land. A fief was a trust, and to
enjoyment was annexed some obligation. The sovereign,
the representative of the whole people, was the only
owner of land. Of him, immediately or mediately, held
tenants, whose possession involved duties or payments,
which, though rudely and imperfectly, embodied the idea
that we would carry out in the single tax, of taking
land values for public uses. The crown lands maintained
the sovereign and the civil list; the church lands
defrayed the cost of public worship and instruction, of
the relief of the sick, the destitute and the wayworn;
while the military tenures provided for public defense
and bore the costs of war. A fourth and very large
portion of the land remained in common, the people of
the neighborhood being free to pasture it, cut wood on
it, or put it to other common uses.
In this partial yet substantial recognition of
common rights to land is to be found the reason why, in
a time when the industrial arts were rude, wars
frequent, and the great discoveries and inventions of
our time unthought of, the condition of the laborer was
devoid of that grinding poverty which despite our
marvelous advances now exists. Speaking of
England, the highest authority on such subjects, the
late Professor Therold Rogers, declares that in the
thirteenth century there was no class so poor, so
helpless, so pressed and degraded as are millions of
Englishmen in our boasted nineteenth century; and that,
save in times of actual famine, there was no laborer so
poor as to fear that his wife and children might come
to want even were he taken from them. Dark and
rude in many respects as they were, these were the
times when the cathedrals and churches and religious
houses whose ruins yet excite our admiration were
built; the times when England had no national debt, no
poor law, no standing army, no hereditary
paupers, no thousands and thousands of human beings
rising in the morning without knowing where they might
lay their heads at night.
With the decay of the feudal system, the system of
private property in land that had destroyed Rome was
extended. As to England, it may briefly be said that
the crown lands were for the most part given away to
favorites; that the church lands were parceled among
his courtiers by Henry VIII., and in Scotland grasped
by the nobles; that the military dues were finally
remitted in the seventeenth century, and taxation on
consumption substituted; and that by a process
beginning with the Tudors and extending to our own time
all but a mere fraction of the commons were inclosed by
the greater landowners; while the same private
ownership of land was extended over Ireland and the
Scottish Highlands, partly by the sword and partly by
bribery of the chiefs. Even the military dues, had they
been commuted, not remitted, would today have more than
sufficed to pay all public expenses without one penny
of other taxation.
Of the New World, whose institutions but continue
those of Europe, it is only necessary to say that to
the parceling out of land in great tracts is due the
backwardness and turbulence of Spanish America; that to
the large plantations of the Southern States of the
Union was due the persistence of slavery there, and
that the more northern settlements showed the earlier
English feeling, land being fairly well divided and the
attempts to establish manorial estates coming to little
or nothing. In this lies the secret of the more
vigorous growth of the Northern States. But the idea
that land was to be treated as private property had
been thoroughly established in English thought before
the colonial period ended, and it has been so treated
by the United States and by the several States. And
though land was at first sold cheaply, and then given
to actual settlers, it was also sold in large
quantities to speculators, given away in great tracts
for railroads and other purposes, until now the public
domain of the United States, which a generation ago
seemed illimitable, has practically gone. And this, as
the experience of other countries shows, is the natural
result in a growing community of making land private
property. When the possession of land means the gain of
unearned wealth, the strong and unscrupulous will
secure it. But when, as we propose, economic rent, the
“unearned increment of wealth,” is taken by
the state for the use of the community, then land will
pass into the hands of users and remain there, since no
matter how great its value, its possession will be
profitable only to users.
As to private property in land having conduced to
the peace and tranquillity of human life, it is not
necessary more than to allude to the notorious fact
that the struggle for land has been the prolific source
of wars and of lawsuits, while it is the poverty
engendered by private property in land that makes the
prison and the workhouse the unfailing attributes of
what we call Christian civilization.
Your Holiness intimates that the Divine Law gives
its sanction to the private ownership of land, quoting
from Deuteronomy, “Thou shalt not covet thy
neighbor’s wife, nor his house, nor his field,
nor his man-servant, nor his maid-servant, nor his ox,
nor his ass, nor anything which is his.”
If, as your Holiness conveys, this inclusion of the
words, “nor his field,” is to be taken as
sanctioning private property in land as it exists
today, then, but with far greater force, must the
words, “his man-servant, nor his
maid-servant,” be taken to sanction chattel
slavery; for it is evident from other provisions of the
same code that these terms referred both to bondsmen
for a term of years and to perpetual slaves. But the
word “field” involves the idea of use and
improvement, to which the right of possession and
ownership does attach without recognition of property
in the land itself. And that this reference to the
“field” is not a sanction of private
property in land as it exists today is proved by the
fact that the Mosaic code expressly denied such
unqualified ownership in land, and with the
declaration, “the land also shall not be sold
forever, because it is mine, and you are strangers and
sojourners with me,” provided for its reversion
every fiftieth year; thus, in a way adapted to the
primitive industrial conditions of the time, securing
to all of the chosen people a foothold in the soil.
Nowhere in fact throughout the Scriptures can the
slightest justification be found for the attaching to
land of the same right of property that justly attaches
to the things produced by labor. Everywhere is it
treated as the free bounty of God, “the land
which the Lord thy God giveth thee.”
6. That fathers should provide for their
children and that private property in land is necessary
to enable them to do so. (14-17.)
With all that your Holiness has to say of the
sacredness of the family relation we are in full
accord. But how the obligation of the father to the
child can justify private property in land we cannot
see. You reason that private property in land is
necessary to the discharge of the duty of the father,
and is therefore requisite and just, because
—
It is a most sacred law of nature that a father must
provide food and all necessaries for those whom he has
begotten; and, similarly, nature dictates that a
man’s children, who carry on, as it were, and
continue his own personality, should be provided by him
with all that is needful to enable them honorably to
keep themselves from want and misery in the
uncertainties of this mortal life. Now, in no other way
can a father effect this except by the ownership of
profitable property, which he can transmit to his
children by inheritance. (14.)
Thanks to Him who has bound the generations of men
together by a provision that brings the tenderest love
to greet our entrance into the world and soothes our
exit with filial piety, it is both the duty and the joy
of the father to care for the child till its powers
mature, and afterwards in the natural order it becomes
the duty and privilege of the child to be the stay of
the parent. This is the natural reason for that
relation of marriage, the groundwork of the sweetest,
tenderest and purest of human joys, which the Catholic
Church has guarded with such unremitting vigilance.
We do, for a few years, need the providence of our
fathers after the flesh. But how small, how transient,
how narrow is this need, as compared with our constant
need for the providence of Him in whom we live, move
and have our being — Our Father who art in
Heaven! It is to him, “the giver of every good
and perfect gift,” and not to our fathers after
the flesh, that Christ taught us to pray, “Give
us this day our daily bread.” And how true it is
that it is through him that the generations of men
exist! Let the mean temperature of the earth rise or
fall a few degrees, an amount as nothing compared with
differences produced in our laboratories, and mankind
would disappear as ice disappears under a tropical sun,
would fall as the leaves fall at the touch of frost.
Or, let for two or three seasons the earth refuse her
increase, and how many of our millions would remain
alive?
The duty of fathers to transmit to their children
profitable property that will enable them to keep
themselves from want and misery in the uncertainties of
this mortal life! What is not possible cannot be a
duty. And how is it possible for fathers to do that?
Your Holiness has not considered how mankind really
lives from hand to mouth, getting each day its daily
bread; how little one generation does or can leave
another. It is doubtful if the wealth of the civilized
world all told amounts to anything like as much as one
year’s labor, while it is certain that if labor
were to stop and men had to rely on existing
accumulation, it would be only a few days ere in the
richest countries pestilence and famine would
stalk.
The profitable property your Holiness refers to, is
private property in land. Now profitable land, as all
economists will agree, is land superior to the land
that the ordinary man can get. It is land that will
yield an income to the owner as owner, and therefore
that will permit the owner to appropriate the products
of labor without doing labor, its profitableness to the
individual involving the robbery of other individuals.
It is therefore possible only for some fathers to leave
their children profitable land. What therefore your
Holiness practically declares is, that it is the duty
of all fathers to struggle to leave their children what
only the few peculiarly strong, lucky or unscrupulous
can leave; and that, a something that involves the
robbery of others — their deprivation of the
material gifts of God.
This anti-Christian doctrine has been long in
practice throughout the Christian world. What are its
results?
Are they not the very evils set forth in your
Encyclical? Are they not, so far from enabling men to
keep themselves from want and misery in the
uncertainties of this mortal life, to condemn the great
masses of men to want and misery that the natural
conditions of our mortal life do not entail; to want
and misery deeper and more wide-spread than exist among
heathen savages? Under the régime of private
property in land and in the richest countries not five
per cent of fathers are able at their death to leave
anything substantial to their children, and probably a
large majority do not leave enough to bury them! Some
few children are left by their fathers richer than it
is good for them to be, but the vast majority not only
are left nothing by their fathers, but by the system
that makes land private property are deprived of the
bounty of their Heavenly Father; are compelled to sue
others for permission to live and to work, and to toil
all their lives for a pittance that often does not
enable them to escape starvation and pauperism.
What your Holiness is actually, though of course
inadvertently, urging, is that earthly fathers should
assume the functions of the Heavenly Father. It is not
the business of one generation to provide the
succeeding generation “with all that is needful
to enable them honorably to keep themselves from want
and misery.” That is God’s business. We no
more create our children than we create our fathers. It
is God who is the Creator of each succeeding generation
as fully as of the one that preceded it. And, to recall
your own words (7), “Nature [God], therefore,
owes to man a storehouse that shall never fail, the
daily supply of his daily wants. And this he finds only
in the inexhaustible fertility of the earth.”
What you are now assuming is, that it is the duty of
men to provide for the wants of their children by
appropriating this storehouse and depriving other
men’s children of the unfailing supply that God
has provided for all.
The duty of the father to the child — the duty
possible to all fathers! Is it not so to conduct
himself, so to nurture and teach it, that it shall come
to manhood with a sound body, well-developed mind,
habits of virtue, piety and industry, and in a state of
society that shall give it and all others free access
to the bounty of God, the providence of the
All-Father?
In doing this the father would be doing more to
secure his children from want and misery than is
possible now to the richest of fathers — as much
more as the providence of God surpasses that of man.
For the justice of God laughs at the efforts of men to
circumvent it, and the subtle law that binds humanity
together poisons the rich in the sufferings of the
poor. Even the few who are able in the general struggle
to leave their children wealth that they fondly think
will keep them from want and misery in the
uncertainties of this mortal life — do they
succeed? Does experience show that it is a benefit to a
child to place him above his fellows and enable him to
think God’s law of labor is not for him? Is not
such wealth oftener a curse than a blessing, and does
not its expectation often destroy filial love and bring
dissensions and heartburnings into families? And how
far and how long are even the richest and strongest
able to exempt their children from the common lot?
Nothing is more certain than that the blood of the
masters of the world flows today in lazzaroni and that
the descendants of kings and princes tenant slums and
workhouses.
But in the state of society we strive for, where the
monopoly and waste of God’s bounty would be done
away with and the fruits of labor would go to the
laborer, it would be within the ability of all to make
more than a comfortable living with reasonable labor.
And for those who might be crippled or incapacitated,
or deprived of their natural protectors and
breadwinners, the most ample provision could be made
out of that great and increasing fund with which God in
his law of rent has provided society — not as a
matter of niggardly and degrading alms, but as a matter
of right, as the assurance which in a Christian state
society owes to all its members.
Thus it is that the duty of the father, the
obligation to the child, instead of giving any support
to private property in land, utterly condemns it,
urging us by the most powerful considerations to
abolish it in the simple and efficacious way of the
single tax.
This duty of the father, this obligation to
children, is not confined to those who have actually
children of their own, but rests on all of us who have
come to the powers and responsibilities of manhood.
For did not Christ set a little child in the midst
of the disciples, saying to them that the angels of
such little ones always behold the face of his Father;
saying to them that it were better for a man to hang a
millstone about his neck and plunge into the uttermost
depths of the sea than to injure such a little one?
And what today is the result of private property in
land in the richest of so-called Christian countries?
Is it not that young people fear to marry; that married
people fear to have children; that children are driven
out of life from sheer want of proper nourishment and
care, or compelled to toil when they ought to be at
school or at play; that great numbers of those who
attain maturity enter it with under-nourished bodies,
overstrained nerves, undeveloped minds — under
conditions that foredoom them, not merely to suffering,
but to crime; that fit them in advance for the prison
and the brothel?
If your Holiness will consider these things we are
confident that instead of defending private property in
land you will condemn it with anathema! ...
... The explanation of this and of similar paradoxes
that in our time perplex on every side may be easily
seen. The effect of all inventions and improvements
that increase productive power, that save waste and
economize effort, is to lessen the labor required for a
given result, and thus to save labor, so that we speak
of them as labor-saving inventions or improvements.
Now, in a natural state of society where the rights of
all to the use of the earth are acknowledged,
labor-saving improvements might go to the very utmost
that can be imagined without lessening the demand for
men, since in such natural conditions the demand for
men lies in their own enjoyment of life and the strong
instincts that the Creator has implanted in the human
breast. But in that unnatural state of society where
the masses of men are disinherited of all but the power
to labor when opportunity to labor is given them by
others, there the demand for them becomes simply the
demand for their services by those who hold this
opportunity, and man himself becomes a commodity.
Hence, although the natural effect of labor-saving
improvement is to increase wages, yet in the unnatural
condition which private ownership of the land begets,
the effect, even of such moral improvements as the
disbandment of armies and the saving of the labor that
vice entails, is, by lessening the commercial demand,
to lower wages and reduce mere laborers to starvation
or pauperism. If labor-saving inventions and
improvements could be carried to the very abolition of
the necessity for labor, what would be the result?
Would it not be that landowners could then get all the
wealth that the land was capable of producing, and
would have no need at all for laborers, who must then
either starve or live as pensioners on the bounty of
the landowners?
Thus, so long as private property in land
continues — so long as some men are treated as
owners of the earth and other men can live on it only
by their sufferance — human wisdom can devise no
means by which the evils of our present condition may
be avoided.
Nor yet could the wisdom of God.
By the light of that right reason of which St.
Thomas speaks we may see that even he, the Almighty, so
long as his laws remain what they are, could do nothing
to prevent poverty and starvation while property in
land continues.
How could he? Should he infuse new vigor into the
sunlight, new virtue into the air, new fertility into
the soil, would not all this new bounty go to the
owners of the land, and work not benefit, but rather
injury, to mere laborers? Should he open the minds of
men to the possibilities of new substances, new
adjustments, new powers, could this do any more to
relieve poverty than steam, electricity and all the
numberless discoveries and inventions of our time have
done? Or, if he were to send down from the heavens
above or cause to gush up from the subterranean depths,
food, clothing, all the things that satisfy man’s
material desires, to whom under our laws would all
these belong? So far from benefiting man, would not
this increase and extension of his bounty prove but a
curse, enabling the privileged class more riotously to
roll in wealth, and bringing the disinherited class to
more wide-spread starvation or pauperism? ...
Believing that the social question is at bottom a
religious question, we deem it of happy augury to the
world that in your Encyclical the most influential of
all religious teachers has directed attention to the
condition of labor.
But while we appreciate the many wholesome truths
you utter, while we feel, as all must feel, that you
are animated by a desire to help the suffering
and oppressed, and to put an end to any idea
that the church is divorced from the aspiration for
liberty and progress, yet it is painfully obvious to us
that one fatal assumption hides from you the
cause of the evils you see, and makes it impossible for
you to propose any adequate remedy. This assumption is,
that private property in land is of the same nature and
has the same sanctions as private property in things
produced by labor. In spite of its undeniable
truths and its benevolent spirit, your Encyclical shows
you to be involved in such difficulties as a physician
called to examine one suffering from disease of the
stomach would meet should he begin with a refusal to
consider the stomach.
Prevented by this assumption from seeing the true
cause, the only causes you find it possible to assign
for the growth of misery and wretchedness are the
destruction of working-men’s guilds in the last
century, the repudiation in public institutions and
laws of the ancient religion, rapacious usury, the
custom of working by contract, and the concentration of
trade.
Such diagnosis is manifestly inadequate to account
for evils that are alike felt in Catholic countries, in
Protestant countries, in countries that adhere to the
Greek communion and in countries where no religion is
professed by the state; that are alike felt in old
countries and in new countries; where industry is
simple and where it is most elaborate; and amid all
varieties of industrial customs and relations.
But the real cause will be clear if you will
consider that since labor must find its workshop and
reservoir in land, the labor question is but another
name for the land question, and will reexamine your
assumption that private property in land is necessary
and right.
See how fully adequate is the cause I have pointed
out. The most important of all the material relations
of man is his relation to the planet he inhabits, and
hence, the “impious resistance to the benevolent
intentions of his Creator,” which, as Bishop Nulty says, is
involved in private property in land, must produce
evils wherever it exists. But by virtue of the law,
“unto whom much is given, from him much is
required,” the very progress of civilization
makes the evils produced by private property in land
more wide-spread and intense.
What is producing throughout the civilized
world that condition of things you rightly describe as
intolerable is not this and that local error or minor
mistake. It is nothing less than the progress of
civilization itself; nothing less than the intellectual
advance and the material growth in which our century
has been so preeminent, acting in a state of society
based on private property in land; nothing less than
the new gifts that in our time God has been showering
on man, but which are being turned into scourges by
man’s “impious resistance to the benevolent
intentions of his Creator.”
The discoveries of science, the gains of invention,
have given to us in this wonderful century more than
has been given to men in any time before; and, in a
degree so rapidly accelerating as to suggest
geometrical progression, are placing in our hands new
material powers. But with the benefit comes the
obligation. In a civilization beginning to pulse with
steam and electricity, where the sun paints pictures
and the phonograph stores speech, it will not do to be
merely as just as were our fathers. Intellectual
advance and material advance require corresponding
moral advance. Knowledge and power are neither good nor
evil. They are not ends but means — evolving
forces that if not controlled in orderly relations must
take disorderly and destructive forms. The deepening
pain, the increasing perplexity, the growing discontent
for which, as you truly say, some remedy must be found
and quickly found, mean nothing less than that forces
of destruction swifter and more terrible than those
that have shattered every preceding civilization are
already menacing ours — that if it does not
quickly rise to a higher moral level; if it does not
become in deed as in word a Christian civilization, on
the wall of its splendor must flame the doom of
Babylon: “Thou art weighed in the balance and
found wanting!” ...
It seems to us that your Holiness misses its real
significance in intimating that Christ, in becoming the
son of a carpenter and himself working as a carpenter,
showed merely that “there is nothing to be
ashamed of in seeking one’s bread by
labor.” To say that is almost like saying that by
not robbing people he showed that there is nothing to
be ashamed of in honesty. If you will consider how true
in any large view is the classification of all
men into working-men, beggar-men and thieves,
you will see that it was morally impossible that Christ
during his stay on earth should have been anything else
than a working-man, since he who came to fulfil the law
must by deed as well as word obey God’s law of
labor.
See how fully and how beautifully Christ’s
life on earth illustrated this law. Entering our
earthly life in the weakness of infancy, as it is
appointed that all should enter it, he lovingly took
what in the natural order is lovingly rendered, the
sustenance, secured by labor, that one generation owes
to its immediate successors. Arrived at maturity, he
earned his own subsistence by that common labor in
which the majority of men must and do earn it. Then
passing to a higher — to the very highest —
sphere of labor, he earned his subsistence by the
teaching of moral and spiritual truths, receiving its
material wages in the love-offerings of grateful
hearers, and not refusing the costly spikenard with
which Mary anointed his feet. So, when he chose his
disciples, he did not go to landowners or other
monopolists who live on the labor of others, but to
common laboring-men. And when he called them to a
higher sphere of labor and sent them out to teach moral
and spiritual truths, he told them to take, without
condescension on the one hand or sense of degradation
on the other, the loving return for such labor, saying
to them that “the laborer is worthy of his
hire,” thus showing, what we hold, that all labor
does not consist in what is called manual labor, but
that whoever helps to add to the material,
intellectual, moral or spiritual fullness of life is
also a laborer.*
* Nor should it be forgotten that the
investigator, the philosopher, the teacher, the
artist, the poet, the priest, though not engaged in
the production of wealth, are not only engaged in the
production of utilities and satisfactions to which
the production of wealth is only a means, but by
acquiring and diffusing knowledge, stimulating mental
powers and elevating the moral sense, may greatly
increase the ability to produce wealth. For man does
not live by bread alone. . . . He who by any exertion
of mind or body adds to the aggregate of enjoyable
wealth, increases the sum of human knowledge, or
gives to human life higher elevation or greater
fullness — he is, in the large meaning of the
words, a “producer,” a
“working-man,” a “laborer,”
and is honestly earning honest wages. But he who
without doing aught to make mankind richer, wiser,
better, happier, lives on the toil of others —
he, no matter by what name of honor he may be called,
or how lustily the priests of Mammon may swing their
censers before him, is in the last analysis but a
beggar-man or a thief. — Protection or Free
Trade, pp. 74-75.
In assuming that laborers, even ordinary manual
laborers, are naturally poor, you ignore the fact that
labor is the producer of wealth, and attribute to the
natural law of the Creator an injustice that comes from
man’s impious violation of his benevolent
intention. In the rudest stage of the arts it is
possible, where justice prevails, for all well men to
earn a living. With the labor-saving appliances of our
time, it should be possible for all to earn much more.
And so, in saying that poverty is no disgrace, you
convey an unreasonable implication. For poverty
ought to be a disgrace, since in a condition of social
justice, it would, where unsought from religious
motives or unimposed by unavoidable misfortune, imply
recklessness or laziness.... read the whole
letter
Rev. A. C. Auchmuty: Gems from George, a themed
collection of excerpts from the writings of Henry
George (with links to sources)
THE general subjection of the many to the few, which
we meet with wherever society has reached a certain
development, has resulted from the appropriation of
land as individual property. It is the ownership of the
soil that everywhere gives the ownership of the men
that live upon it. It is slavery of this kind to which
the enduring pyramids and the colossal monuments of
Egypt yet bear witness, and of the institution of which
we have, perhaps, a vague tradition in the biblical
story of the famine during which the Pharaoh purchased
up the lands of the people. It was slavery of this kind
to which, in the twilight of history, the conquerors of
Greece reduced the original inhabitants of that
peninsula, transforming them into helots by making them
pay rent for their lands. It was the growth of the
latifundia, or great landed
estates, which transmuted the population of ancient
Italy from a race of hardy husbandmen, whose robust
virtues conquered the world, into a race of cringing
bondsmen; it was the appropriation of the land as the
absolute property of their chieftains which gradually
turned the descendants of free and equal Gallic,
Teutonic and Hunnish warriors into colonii and
villains, and which changed the independent burghers of
Sclavonic village communities into the boors of Russia
and the serfs of Poland; which instituted the feudalism
of China and Japan, as well as that of Europe, and
which made the High Chiefs of Polynesia the all but
absolute masters of their fellows. How it came to pass
that the Aryan shepherds and warriors who, as
comparative philology tells us, descended from the
common birth-place of the Indo-Germanic race into the
lowlands of India, were turned into the suppliant and
cringing Hindoo, the Sanscrit verse which I have before
quoted gives us a hint. The white parasols and the
elephants mad with pride of the Indian Rajah are the
flowers of grants of land. —
Progress & Poverty
— Book VII, Chapter 1, Justice of the Remedy:
Injustice of private property in land
TRACE to their root the causes that are thus producing
want in the midst of plenty, ignorance in the midst of
intelligence, aristocracy in democracy, weakness in
strength — that are giving to our civilization a
one-sided and unstable development, and you will find
it something which this Hebrew statesman three thousand
years ago perceived and guarded against. Moses saw that
the real cause of the enslavement of the masses of
Egypt was, what has everywhere produced enslavement,
the possession by a class of the land upon which, and
from which, the whole people must live. He saw that to
permit in land the same unqualified private ownership
that by natural right attaches to the things produced
by labor, would be inevitably to separate the people
into the very rich and the very poor, inevitably to
enslave labor — to make the few the masters of.
the many, no matter what the political forms, to bring
vice and degradation, no matter what the
religion.
And with the foresight of the philosophic statesman who
legislates not for the need of a day, but for all the
future, he sought, in ways suited to his times and
conditions, to guard against this error. —
Moses
THE women who by the thousands are bending over their
needles or sewing machines, thirteen, fourteen, sixteen
hours a day; these widows straining and striving to
bring up the little ones deprived of their natural
bread-winner; the children that are growing up in
squalor and wretchedness, under-clothed, under-fed,
under-educated, even in this city without any place to
play — growing up under conditions in which only
a miracle can keep them pure — under conditions
which condemn them in advance to the penitentiary or
the brothel — they suffer, they die, because
we permit them to be robbed, robbed of their
birthright, robbed by a system which disinherits the
vast majority of the children that come into the world.
There is enough and to spare for them. Had they the
equal rights in the estate which their Creator has
given them, there would be no young girls forced to
unwomanly toil to eke out a mere existence, no widows
finding it such a bitter, bitter struggle to put bread
in the mouths of their little children; no such misery
and squalor as we may see here in the greatest of
American cities; misery and squalor that are deepest in
the largest and richest centers of our civilization
today. — Thou
Shalt Not Steal
... go to "Gems
from George"
Louis Post: Outlines of Louis F. Post's
Lectures, with Illustrative Notes and Charts
(1894)
But it is not alone to objects of charity that the
question of poverty calls our attention. There is a
keener poverty, which pinches and goes hungry, but is
beyond the reach of charity because it never complains.
And back of all and over all is fear of poverty, which
chills the best instincts of men of every social grade,
from recipients of out-door relief who dread the
poorhouse, to millionaires who dread the possibility of
poverty for their children if not for themselves.38
38. A well known millionaire is quoted
as saying: "I would rather leave my children
penniless in a world in which they could at all times
obtain employment for wages equal to the value of
their work as measured by the work of others, than to
leave them millions of dollars in a world like this,
where if thy lose their inheritance, they may have no
chance of earning am decent living."
It is poverty and fear of poverty that prompt men of
honest instincts to steal, to bribe, to take bribes, to
oppress, either under color of law or against law, and
— what is worst than all, because it is not
merely a depraved act, but a course of conduct that
implies a state of depravity — to enlist their
talents in crusades against their convictions. 39 Our
civilization cannot long resist such enemies as poverty
and fear of poverty breed; to intelligent observers it
already seems to yield. 40
39. "From whence springs this lust for
gain, to gratify which men tread everything pure and
noble under their feet; to which they sacrifice all
the higher possibilities of life; which converts
civility into a hollow pretense, patriotism into a
sham, and religion into hypocrisy; which makes so
much of civilized existence an Ishmaelitish warfare,
of which the weapons are cunning and fraud? Does it
not spring from the existence of want? Carlyle
somewhere says that poverty is the hell of which the
modern Englishman is most afraid. And he is right.
Poverty is the openmouthed, relentless hell which
yawns beneath civilized society. And it is hell
enough. The Vedas declare no truer thing than when
the wise crow Bushanda tells the eagle-bearer of
Vishnu that the keenest pain is in poverty. For
poverty is not merely deprivation; it means shame,
degradation; the searing of the most sensitive parts
of our moral and mental nature as with hot irons; the
denial of the strongest impulses and the sweetest
affections; the wrenching of the most vital nerves.
You love your wife, you love your children; but would
it not be easier to see them die than to see them
reduced to the pinch of want in which large classes
in every highly civilized community live? ... From
this hell of poverty, it is but natural that men
should make every effort to escape. With the impulse
to self-preservation and self-gratification combine
nobler feelings, and love as well as fear urges in
the struggle. Many a man does a mean thing, a
dishonest thing, a greedy and grasping and unjust
thing, in the effort to place above want, or the fear
of want, mother or wife or children." —
Progress and Poverty, book ix, ch iv.
40. "There is just now a disposition
to scoff at any implication that we are not in all
respects progressing ... Yet it is evident that there
have been times of decline, just as there have been
times of advance; and it is further evident that
these epochs of decline could not at first have been
generally recognized.
"He would have been a rash man who,
when Augustus was changing the Rome of brick to the
Rome of marble, when wealth was augmenting and
magnificence increasing, when victorious legions were
extending the frontier, when manners were becoming
more refined, language more polished, and literature
rising to higher splendors — he would have been
a rash man who then would have said that Rome was
entering her decline. Yet such was the case.
"And whoever will look may see that
though our civilization is apparently advancing with
greater rapidity than ever, the same cause which
turned Roman progress into retrogression is operating
now.
"What has destroyed every previous
civilization has been the tendency to the unequal
distribution of wealth and power. This same tendency,
operating with increasing force, is observable in our
civilization today, showing itself in every
progressive community, and with greater intensity the
more progressive the community. ... The conditions of
social progress, as we have traced the law, are
association and equality. The general tendency of
modern development, since the time when we can first
discern the gleams of civilization in the darkness
which followed the fall of the Western Empire, has
been toward political and legal equality ... This
tendency has reached its full expression in the
American Republic, where political and legal rights
are absolutely equal ... it is the prevailing
tendency, and how soon Europe will be completely
republican is only a matter of time, or rather of
accident. The United States are therefore in this
respect, the most advanced of all the great nations,
in a direction in which all are advancing, and in the
United States we see just how much this tendency to
personal and political freedom can of itself
accomplish. ... It is now ... evident that political
equality, coexisting with an increasing tendency to
the unequal distribution of wealth, must ultimately
beget either the despotism of organized tyranny or
the worse despotism of anarchy.
"To turn a republican government into
a despotism the basest and most brutal, it is not
necessary formally to change its constitution or
abandon popular elections. It was centuries after
Cæsar before the absolute master of the Roman
world pretended to rule other than by authority of a
Senate that trembled before him.
"But forms are nothing when substance
has gone, and the forms of popular government are
those from which the substance of freedom may most
easily go. Extremes meet, and a government of
universal suffrage and theoretical equality may,
under conditions which impel the change, most readily
become a despotism. For there despotism advances in
the name and with the might of the people. ... And
when the disparity of condition increases, so does
universal suffrage make it easy to seize the source
of power, for the greater is the proportion of power
in the hands of those who feel no direct interest in
the conduct of government; who, tortured by want and
embruted by poverty, are ready to sell their votes to
the highest bidder or follow the lead of the most
blatant demagogue; or who, made bitter by hardships,
may even look upon profligate and tyrannous
government with the satisfaction we may imagine the
proletarians and slaves of Rome to have felt, as they
saw a Caligula or Nero raging among the rich
patricians. ... Now this transformation of popular
government into despotism of the vilest and most
degrading kind, which must inevitably result from the
unequal distribution of wealth, is not a thing of the
far future. It has already begun in the United
States, and is rapidly going on under our eyes. ...
The type of modern growth is the great city. Here are
to be found the greatest wealth and the deepest
poverty. And it is here that popular government has
most clearly broken down. ... In theory we are
intense democrats. ... But is there not growing up
among us a class who have all the power without any
of the virtues of aristocracy? ... Industry
everywhere tends to assume a form in which one is
master and many serve. And when one is master and the
others serve, the one will control the others, even
in such matters as votes. ... There is no mistaking
it — the very foundations of society are being
sapped before our eyes ... It is shown in greatest
force where the inequalities in the distribution of
wealth are greatest, and it shows itself as they
increase. ... Though we may not speak it openly, the
general faith in republican institutions is, where
they have reached their fullest development,
narrowing and weakening. It is no longer that
confident belief in republicanism as the source of
national blessings that it once was. Thoughtful men
are beginning to see its dangers, without seeing how
to escape them; are beginning to accept the view of
Macaulay and distrust that of Jefferson. And the
people at large are becoming used to the growing
corruption. The most ominous political sign in the
United States today is the growth of a sentiment
which either doubts the existence of an honest man in
public office or looks on him as a fool for not
seizing his opportunities. That is to say, the people
themselves are becoming corrupted. Thus in the United
States to-day is republican government running the
course it must inevitably follow under conditions
which cause the unequal distribution of wealth."
— Progress and Poverty, book x, ch. iv.
But how is the development of these social enemies
to be arrested? Only by tracing poverty to its cause,
and, having found the cause, deliberately removing it.
Poverty cannot be traced to its cause, however, without
serious thought; not mere reading and school study and
other tutoring, but thought. 41 To jump at a conclusion
is very likely to jump over the cause, at which no
class is more apt than the tutored class.42 We must
proceed step by step from familiar and indisputable
premises. ...
d. Dependence of Labor upon
Land
We have now seen that division of labor and trade,
the distinguishing characteristics of civilization, not
only increase labor power, but grow out of a law of
human nature which tends, by maintaining a perpetual
revolution of the circle of trade, to cause
opportunities for mutual employment to correspond to
desire for wealth. Surely there could be no lack of
employment if the circle flowed freely in accordance
with the principle here illustrated; work would abound
until want was satisfied. There must therefore be some
obstruction. That indirect taxes hamper trade, we have
already seen;78 but there is a more fundamental
obstruction. As we learned at the outset, all the
material wants of men are satisfied by Labor from Land.
Even personal services cannot be rendered without the
use of appropriate land.79 Let us then introduce into
the preceding chart, in addition to the different
classes of Labor, the corresponding classes of
Land-owning interests, indicating them by black
balls:
78. See ante, pp. 9, 6 and 16.
79. Demand for food is not only demand
for all kinds and grades of Food-makers, but also for
as many different kinds of land as there are
different kinds of labor set at work. So a demand for
clothing is not only a demand for Clothing-makers, a
demand for shelter is not only one for
Shelter-makers, a demand for luxuries is not only one
for Luxury-makers, a demand for services is not only
one for Personal Servants, but those demands are also
demands for appropriate land — pasture land for
wool, cotton land for cotton, factory land, water
fronts and rights of way, store sites, residence
sites, office sites, theater sites, and so on to the
end of an almost endless catalogue.
Every class of Labor has now its own
parasite.
The arrows which run from one kind of Labor to
another, indicating an out-flow of service, are
respectively offset by arrows that indicate a
corresponding in-flow of service; but the
arrows that flow from the various classes of Labor to
the various Land-owning interests are offset by nothing
to indicate a corresponding return. What possible
return could those interests make?
- They do not produce the land which they charge
laborers for using; nature provides that.
- They do not give value to it; Labor as a whole
does that.
- They do not protect the community through the
police, the courts, or the army, nor assist it
through schools and post offices; organized society
does that to the extent to which it is done, and the
Land-owning interests contribute nothing toward it
other than a part of what they exact from
Labor.80
As between Labor interests and Land-owning interests
the arrows can be made to run only in the one
direction.
80 See ante, pp. 12, 13, and 14.
Now, suppose that as productive methods
improve, the exactions of the Land-owning interests so
expand — so enlarge the drain from Labor —
as to make it increasingly difficult for any of the
workers to obtain the Land they need in order to
satisfy the demands made upon them for the kind of
Wealth they produce. Would it then be much of a problem
to determine the cause of poverty or to explain hard
times? Assuredly not. It would be plain that
poverty and hard times are due to obstacles placed by
Land-owning interests in the way of Labor's access to
Land.
We thus see that in the civilized state as well as
in the primitive, the fundamental cause of poverty is
the divorce of Labor from Land. 81 But the manner in
which that divorce is accomplished in the civilized
state remains to be explained. ...
c. Significance of the Upward Tendency
of Rent
Now, what is the meaning of this tendency of Rent to
rise with social progress, while Wages tend to fall? Is
it not a plain promise that if Rent be treated as
common property, advances in productive power shall be
steps in the direction of realizing through orderly and
natural growth those grand conceptions of both the
socialist and the individualist, which in the present
condition of society are justly ranked as Utopian?
Is it not likewise a plain warning that if Rent
be treated as private property, advances in productive
power will be steps in the direction of making slaves
of the many laborers, and masters of a few land-owners?
Does it not mean that common ownership of Rent is in
harmony with natural law, and that its private
appropriation is disorderly and degrading?
When the cause of Rent and the tendency illustrated in
the preceding chart are considered in connection with
the self-evident truth that God made the earth for
common use and not for private monopoly, how can a
contrary inference hold? Caused and increased by social
growth, 97 the benefits of which should be common, and
attaching to land, the just right to which is equal,
Rent must be the natural fund for public expenses.
98
97. Here, far away from civilization,
is a solitary settler. Getting no benefits from
government, he needs no public revenues, and none of
the land about him has any value. Another settler
comes, and another, until a village appears. Some
public revenue is then required. Not much, but some.
And the land has a little value, only a little;
perhaps just enough to equal the need for public
revenue. The village becomes a town. More revenues
are needed, and land values are higher. It becomes a
city. The public revenues required are enormous, and
so are the land values.
98. Society, and society alone, causes
Rent. Rising with the rise, advancing with the
growth, and receding with the decline of society, it
measures the earning power of society as a whole as
distinguished from that of the individuals. Wages, on
the other hand, measure the earning power of the
individuals as distinguished from that of society as
a whole. We have distinguished the parts into which
Wealth is distributed as Wages and Rent; but it would
be correct, indeed it is the same thing, to regard
all wealth as earnings, and to distinguish the two
kinds as Communal Earnings and Individual Earnings.
How, then, can there be any question as to the fund
from which society should be supported? How can it be
justly supported in any other way than out of its own
earnings?
If there be at all such a thing as design in the
universe — and who can doubt it? — then has
it been designed that Rent, the earnings of the
community, shall be retained for the support of the
community, and that Wages, the earnings of the
individual, shall be left to the individual in
proportion to the value of his service. This is the
divine law, whether we trace it through complex moral
and economic relations, or find it in the eighth
commandment.
d. Effect of Confiscating Rent to
Private Use.
By giving Rent to individuals society ignores this
most just law, 99 thereby creating social disorder and
inviting social disease. Upon society alone, therefore,
and not upon divine Providence which has provided
bountifully, nor upon the disinherited poor, rests the
responsibility for poverty and fear of poverty.
99. "Whatever dispute arouses the
passions of men, the conflict is sure to rage, not so
much as to the question 'Is it wise?' as to the
question 'Is it right?'
"This tendency of popular discussions
to take an ethical form has a cause. It springs from
a law of the human mind; it rests upon a vague and
instinctive recognition of what is probably the
deepest truth we can grasp. That alone is wise which
is just; that alone is enduring which is right. In
the narrow scale of individual actions and individual
life this truth may be often obscured, but in the
wider field of national life it everywhere stands
out.
"I bow to this arbitrament, and accept
this test." — Progress and Poverty, book vii,
ch. i.
The reader who has been deceived into
believing that Mr. George's proposition is in any
respect unjust, will find profit in a perusal of the
entire chapter from which the foregoing extract is
taken.
Let us try to trace the connection by means of a
chart, beginning with the white spaces on page 68. As
before, the first-comers take possession of the best
land. But instead of leaving for others what they do
not themselves need for use, as in the previous
illustrations, they appropriate the whole space, using
only part, but claiming ownership of the rest. We may
distinguish the used part with red color, and that
which is appropriated without use with blue. Thus:
[chart]
But what motive is there for appropriating more of
the space than is used? Simply that the appropriators
may secure the pecuniary benefit of future social
growth. What will enable them to secure that? Our
system of confiscating Rent from the community that
earns it, and giving it to land-owners who, as such,
earn nothing.100
100. It is reported from Iowa that a
few years ago a workman in that State saw a meteorite
fall, and. securing possession of it after much
digging, he was offered $105 by a college for his
"find." But the owner of the land on which the
meteorite fell claimed the money, and the two went to
law about it. After an appeal to the highest court of
the State, it was finally decided that neither by
right of discovery, nor by right of labor, could the
workman have the money, because the title to the
meteorite was in the man who owned the land upon
which it fell.
Observe the effect now upon Rent and Wages. When
other men come, instead of finding half of the best
land still common and free, as in the corresponding
chart on page 68, they find all of it owned, and are
obliged either to go upon poorer land or to buy or rent
from owners of the best. How much will they pay for the
best? Not more than 1, if they want it for use and not
to hold for a higher price in the future, for that
represents the full difference between its
productiveness and the productiveness of the next best.
But if the first-comers, reasoning that the next best
land will soon be scarce and theirs will then rise in
value, refuse to sell or to rent at that valuation, the
newcomers must resort to land of the second grade,
though the best be as yet only partly used.
Consequently land of the first grade commands Rent
before it otherwise would.
As the sellers' price, under these circumstances, is
arbitrary it cannot be stated in the chart; but the
buyers' price is limited by the superiority of the best
land over that which can be had for nothing, and the
chart may be made to show it: [chart]
And now, owing to the success of the appropriators
of the best land in securing more than their fellows
for the same expenditure of labor force, a rush is made
for unappropriated land. It is not to use it that it is
wanted, but to enable its appropriators to put Rent
into their own pockets as soon as growing demand for
land makes it valuable.101 We may, for illustration,
suppose that all the remainder of the second space and
the whole of the third are thus appropriated, and note
the effect: [chart]
At this point Rent does not increase nor Wages fall,
because there is no increased demand for land for use.
The holding of inferior land for higher prices, when
demand for use is at a standstill, is like owning lots
in the moon — entertaining, perhaps, but not
profitable. But let more land be needed for use, and
matters promptly assume a different appearance. The new
labor must either go to the space that yields but 1, or
buy or rent from owners of better grades, or hire out.
The effect would be the same in any case. Nobody for
the given expenditure of labor force would get more
than 1; the surplus of products would go to landowners
as Rent, either directly in rent payments, or
indirectly through lower Wages. Thus: [chart]
101. The text speaks of Rent only as a
periodical or continuous payment — what would
be called "ground rent." But actual or potential Rent
may always be, and frequently is, capitalized for the
purpose of selling the right to enjoy it, and it is
to selling value that we usually refer when dealing
in land.
Land which has the power of yielding
Rent to its owner will have a selling value, whether
it be used or not, and whether Rent is actually
derived from it or not. This selling value will be
the capitalization of its present or prospective
power of producing Rent. In fact, much the larger
proportion of laud that has a selling value is wholly
or partly unused, producing no Rent at all, or less
than it would if fully used. This condition is
expressed in the chart by the blue color.
"The capitalized value of land is the
actuarial 'discounted' value of all the net incomes
which it is likely to afford, allowance being made on
the one hand for all incidental expenses, including
those of collecting the rents, and on the other for
its mineral wealth, its capabilities of development
for any kind of business, and its advantages,
material, social, and aesthetic, for the purposes of
residence." — Marshall's Prin., book vi, ch.
ix, sec. 9.
"The value of land is commonly
expressed as a certain number of times the current
money rental, or in other words, a certain 'number of
years' purchase' of that rental; and other things
being equal, it will be the higher the more important
these direct gratifications are, as well as the
greater the chance that they and the money income
afforded by the land will rise." — Id.,
note.
"Value . . . means not utility, not
any quality inhering in the thing itself, but a
quality which gives to the possession of a thing the
power of obtaining other things, in return for it or
for its use. . . Value in this sense — the
usual sense — is purely relative. It exists
from and is measured by the power of obtaining things
for things by exchanging them. . . Utility is
necessary to value, for nothing can be valuable
unless it has the quality of gratifying some physical
or mental desire of man, though it be but a fancy or
whim. But utility of itself does not give value. . .
If we ask ourselves the reason of . . . variations in
. . . value . . . we see that things having some form
of utility or desirability, are valuable or not
valuable, as they are hard or easy to get. And if we
ask further, we may see that with most of the things
that have value this difficulty or ease of getting
them, which determines value, depends on the amount
of labor which must be expended in producing them ;
i.e., bringing them into the place, form and
condition in which they are desired. . . Value is
simply an expression of the labor required for the
production of such a thing. But there are some things
as to which this is not so clear. Land is not
produced by labor, yet land, irrespective of any
improvements that labor has made on it, often has
value. . . Yet a little examination will show that
such facts are but exemplifications of the general
principle, just as the rise of a balloon and the fall
of a stone both exemplify the universal law of
gravitation. . . The value of everything produced by
labor, from a pound of chalk or a paper of pins to
the elaborate structure and appurtenances of a
first-class ocean steamer, is resolvable on analysis
into an equivalent of the labor required to produce
such a thing in form and place; while the value of
things not produced by labor, but nevertheless
susceptible of ownership, is in the same way
resolvable into an equivalent of the labor which the
ownership of such a thing enables the owner to obtain
or save." —
Perplexed Philosopher, ch. v.
The figure 1 in parenthesis, as an item of Rent,
indicates potential Rent. Labor would give that much
for the privilege of using the space, but the owners
hold out for better terms; therefore neither Rent nor
Wages is actually produced, though but for this both
might be.
In this chart, notwithstanding that but little space
is used, indicated with red, Wages are reduced to the
same low point by the mere appropriation of space,
indicated with blue, that they would reach if all the
space above the poorest were fully used. It thereby
appears that under a system which confiscates Rent to
private uses, the demand for land for speculative
purposes becomes so great that Wages fall to a minimum
long before they would if land were appropriated only
for use.
In illustrating the effect of confiscating Rent to
private use we have as yet ignored the element of
social growth. Let us now assume as before (page 73),
that social growth increases the productive power of
the given expenditure of labor force to 100 when
applied to the best land, 50 when applied to the next
best, 10 to the next, 3 to the next, and 1 to the
poorest. Labor would not be benefited now, as it
appeared to be when on page 73 we illustrated the
appropriation of land for use only, although much less
land is actually used. The prizes which expectation of
future social growth dangles before men as the rewards
of owning land, would raise demand so as to make it
more than ever difficult to get land. All of the fourth
grade would be taken up in expectation of future
demand; and "surplus labor" would be crowded out to the
open space that originally yielded nothing, but which
in consequence of increased labor power now yields as
much as the poorest closed space originally yielded,
namely, 1 to the given expenditure of labor force.102
Wages would then be reduced to the present
productiveness of the open space. Thus: [chart]
102. The paradise to which the youth
of our country have so long been directed in the
advice, "Go West, young man, go West," is truthfully
described in "Progress and Poverty," book iv, ch. iv,
as follows :
"The man who sets out from the
eastern seaboard in search of the margin of
cultivation, where he may obtain land without
paying rent, must, like the man who swam the river
to get a drink, pass for long distances through
half-titled farms, and traverse vast areas of
virgin soil, before he reaches the point where land
can be had free of rent — i.e., by homestead
entry or preemption."
If we assume that 1 for the given expenditure of
labor force is the least that labor can take while
exerting the same force, the downward movement of Wages
will be here held in equilibrium. They cannot fall
below 1; but neither can they rise above it, no matter
how much productive power may increase, so long as it
pays to hold land for higher values. Some laborers
would continually be pushed back to land which
increased productive power would have brought up in
productiveness from 0 to 1, and by perpetual
competition for work would so regulate the labor market
that the given expenditure of labor force, however much
it produced, could nowhere secure more than 1 in
Wages.103 And this tendency would persist until some
labor was forced upon land which, despite increase in
productive power, would not yield the accustomed living
without increase of labor force. Competition for work
would then compel all laborers to increase their
expenditure of labor force, and to do it over and over
again as progress went on and lower and lower grades of
land were monopolized, until human endurance could go
no further.104 Either that, or they would be obliged to
adapt themselves to a lower scale of living.105
103. Henry Fawcett, in his work on
"Political Economy," book ii, ch. iii, observes with
reference to improvements in agricultural implements
which diminish the expense of cultivation, that they
do not increase the profits of the farmer or the
wages of his laborers, but that "the landlord will
receive in addition to the rent already paid to him,
all that is saved in the expense of cultivation."
This is true not alone of improvements in
agriculture, but also of improvements in all other
branches of industry.
104. "The cause which limits
speculation in commodities, the tendency of
increasing price to draw forth additional supplies,
cannot limit the speculative advance in land values,
as land is a fixed quantity, which human agency can
neither increase nor diminish; but there is
nevertheless a limit to the price of land, in the
minimum required by labor and capital as the
condition of engaging in production. If it were
possible to continuously reduce wages until zero were
reached, it would be possible to continuously
increase rent until it swallowed up the whole
produce. But as wages cannot be permanently reduced
below the point at which laborers will consent to
work and reproduce, nor interest below the point at
which capital will be devoted to production, there is
a limit which restrains the speculative advance of
rent. Hence, speculation cannot have the same scope
to advance rent in countries where wages and interest
are already near the minimum, as in countries where
they are considerably above it. Yet that there is in
all progressive countries a constant tendency in the
speculative advance of rent to overpass the limit
where production would cease, is, I think, shown by
recurring seasons of industrial paralysis." —
Progress and Poverty, book iv, ch. iv.
105. As Puck once put it, "the man who
makes two blades of grass to grow where but one grew
before, must not be surprised when ordered to 'keep
off the grass.' "
They in fact do both, and the incidental
disturbances of general readjustment are what we call
"hard times." 106 These culminate in forcing unused
land into the market, thereby reducing Rent and
reviving industry. Thus increase of labor force, a
lowering of the scale of living, and depression of
Rent, co-operate to bring on what we call "good times."
But no sooner do "good times" return than renewed
demands for land set in, Rent rises again, Wages fall
again, and "hard times" duly reappear. The end of every
period of "hard times" finds Rent higher and Wages
lower than at the end of the previous period.107
106. "That a speculative advance in
rent or land values invariably precedes each of these
seasons of industrial depression is everywhere clear.
That they bear to each other the relation of cause
and effect, is obvious to whoever considers the
necessary relation between land and labor." —
Progress and Poverty, book v, ch. i.
107. What are called "good times"
reach a point at which an upward land market sets in.
From that point there is a downward tendency of wages
(or a rise in the cost of living, which is the same
thing) in all departments of labor and with all
grades of laborers. This tendency continues until the
fictitious values of land give way. So long as the
tendency is felt only by that class which is hired
for wages, it is poverty merely; when the same
tendency is felt by the class of labor that is
distinguished as "the business interests of the
country," it is "hard times." And "hard times" are
periodical because land values, by falling, allow
"good times" to set it, and by rising with "good
times" bring "hard times" on again. The effect of
"hard times" may be overcome, without much, if any,
fall in land values, by sufficient increase in
productive power to overtake the fictitious value of
land.
The dishonest and disorderly system under which
society confiscates Rent from common to individual
uses, produces this result. That maladjustment is the
fundamental cause of poverty. And progress, so long as
the maladjustment continues, instead of tending to
remove poverty as naturally it should, actually
generates and intensifies it. Poverty persists with
increase of productive power because land values, when
Rent is privately appropriated, tend to even greater
increase. There can be but one outcome if this
continues: for individuals suffering and degradation,
and for society destruction. ...
IV.
CONCLUSION
In "Progress and Poverty," after reaching his
conclusion that command of the land which is necessary
for labor is command of all the fruits of labor save
enough to enable labor to exist, Henry George says:
So simple and so clear is this truth that to fully
see it once is always to recognize it. There are
pictures which, though looked at again and again,
present only a confused labyrinth of lines or
scroll-work — a landscape, trees, or something
of the kind — until once attention is called to
the fact that these things make up a face or a
figure. This relation once recognized is always
afterward clear. 111 It is so in this case. In the
light of this truth all social facts group themselves
in an orderly relation, and the most diverse
phenomena are seen to spring from one great
principle.
111. This idea of the concealed
picture was graphically illustrated with a story by
Congressman James G. Maguire, at that time a Judge of
the Superior Court of San Francisco, in a speech at
the Academy of Music, New York City, in 1887. In
substance he said:
"I was one day walking along Kearney
Street in San Francisco, when I noticed a crowd
around the show window of a store, looking at
something inside. I took a glance myself and saw only
a very poor picture of a very uninteresting
landscape. But as I was turning away my eye caught
the words underneath the picture, 'Do you see the
cat?' I looked again and more closely, but saw no cat
in the picture. Then I spoke to the crowd.
"'Gentlemen,' I said, 'I see no cat in
that picture. Is there a cat there?'
Some one in the crowd replied:
"'Naw, there ain't no cat there.
Here's a crank who says he sees the cat, but nobody
else can see it.'
Then the crank spoke up:
'I tell you there is a cat there, too.
It's all cat. What you fellows take for a landscape
is just nothing more than the outlines of a cat. And
you needn't call a man a crank either, because he can
see more with his eyes than you can.'
"Well," the judge continued, "I looked
very closely at the picture, and then I said to the
man they called a crank:
"'Really, sir, I cannot make out a
cat. I can see nothing but a poor picture of a
landscape.'
"'Why, judge,' he exclaimed, 'just
look at that bird in the air. That's the cat's
ear.'
I looked, but was obliged to say:
'I am sorry to be so stupid, but I
can't make a cat's ear of that bird. It is a poor
bird, but not a cat's ear.'
"'Well, then,' the crank urged, 'look
at that twig twirled around in a circle. That's the
cat's eye.'
But I couldn't make an eye of it.
'Oh, then,' said the crank a little
impatiently, 'look at those sprouts at the foot of
the tree, and the grass. They make the cat's
claws.'
"After another deliberate examination,
I reported that they did look a little like a claw,
but I couldn't connect them with a cat.
"Once more the crank came back at me.
'Don't you see that limb off there? and that other
limb under it? and that white space between? Well,
that white space is the cat's tail.'
"I looked again and was just on the
point of replying that there was no cat there so far
as I could see, when suddenly the whole cat burst
upon me. There it was, sure enough, just as the crank
had said; and the only reason that the rest of us
couldn't see it was that we hadn't got the right
point of view. But now that I saw it I could see
nothing else in the picture. The landscape had
disappeared and a cat had taken its place. And, do
you know, I was never afterward able, upon looking at
that picture, to see anything in it but the cat!"
From this story as told by Judge
Maguire, has come the slang of the single tax
agitation. To "see the cat " is to understand the
single tax.
Many events subsequent to his writing have gone to
prove that Henry George was right. Each new phase of
the social problem makes it still more clear that the
disorderly development of our civilization is
explained, not by pressure of population, nor by the
superficial relations of employers and employed, nor by
scarcity of money, nor by the drinking habits of the
poor, nor by individual differences in ability to
produce wealth, nor by an incompetent or malevolent
Creator, but, as he has said, by "inequality in the
ownership of land." And each new phase makes it equally
clear that the remedy for poverty is not to be found in
famine and disease and war, nor in strikes which are
akin to war, nor in the suppression of strikes by force
of arms, nor in the coinage of money, nor in
prohibition or high license, nor in technical
education, nor in anything else short of approximate
equality in the ownership of land. This alone secures
equal opportunities to produce, and full ownership by
each producer of his own product. This is justice, this
is order. And unless our civilization have it for a
foundation, new forms of slavery will assuredly lead us
into new forms of barbarism.112
112. "Our primary social adjustment is
a denial of justice. In allowing one man to own the
land on which and from which other men must live, we
have made them his bondsmen in a degree which
increases as material progress goes on. This is the
subtile alchemy that in ways they do not realize is
extracting from the masses in every civilized country
the fruits of their weary toil; that is instituting a
harder and more hopeless slavery in place of that
which has been destroyed; that is bringing political
despotism out of political freedom, and must soon
transmute democratic institutions into anarchy.
"It is this that turns the blessings
of material progress into a curse. It is this that
crowds human beings into noisome cellars and squalid
tenement houses; that fills prisons and brothels;
that goads men with want and consumes them with
greed; that robs women of the grace and beauty of
perfect womanhood; that takes from little children
the joy and innocence of life's morning.
"Civilization so based cannot
continue. The eternal laws of the universe forbid it.
Ruins of dead empires testify, and the witness that
is in every soul answers, that it cannot be. It is
something grander than Benevolence, something more
august than Charity — it is justice herself
that demands of us to right this wrong. justice that
will not be denied; that cannot be put off —
justice that with the scales carries the sword."
— Progress and Poverty, book x, ch. v.
... read the
book
Clarence Darrow: How to Abolish
Unfair Taxation (1913)
Everybody nowadays is anxious to help do something
for the poor, especially they who are on the backs of
the poor; they will do anything that is not
fundamental. Nobody ever dreams of giving the poor a
chance to help themselves. The reformers in this state
have passed a law prohibiting women from working more
than eight hours in one day in certain industries
— so much do women love to work that they must be
stopped by law. If any benevolent heathen see fit to
come here and do work, we send them to gaol or send
them back where they came from.
All these prohibitory laws are froth. You can only
cure effects by curing the cause. Every sin and every
wrong that exists in the world is the product of law,
and you cannot cure it without curing the cause.
Lawyers, as a class, are very stupid. What would you
think of a doctor, who, finding a case of malaria,
instead of draining the swamp, would send the patient
to gaol, and leave the swamp where it is? We are
seeking to improve conditions of life by improving
symptoms.
Land Basic
No man created the earth, but to a large extent all
take from the earth a portion of it and mould it into
useful things for the use of man. Without land man
cannot live; without access to it man cannot labor.
First of all, he must have the earth, and this he
cannot have access to until the single tax is applied.
It has been proven by the history of the human race
that the single tax does work, and that it will work as
its advocates claim. For instance, man turned from
Europe, filled with a population of the poor, and
discovered the great continent of America. Here, when
he could not get profitable employment, he went on the
free land and worked for himself, and in those early
days there were no problems of poverty, no wonderfully
rich and no extremely poor — because there was
cheap land. Men could go to work for themselves, and
thus take the surplus off the labor market. There were
no beggars in the early days. It was only when the
landlord got in his work — when the earth
monopoly was complete — that the great mass of
men had to look to a boss for a job.
All the remedial laws on earth can scarcely help the
poor when the earth is monopolized. Men must live from
the earth, they must till the soil, dig the coal and
iron and cut down the forest. Wise men know it, and
cunning men know it, and so a few have reached out
their hands and grasped the earth; and they say, "These
mines of coal and iron, which it took nature ages and
ages to store, belong to me; and no man can touch them
until he sees fit to pay the tribute I demand." ...
read the
whole speech
I know of a woman — I have never had the
pleasure of making her acquaintance, because she lives
in a lunatic asylum, which does not happen to be on my
visiting list. This woman has been mentally incompetent
from birth. She is well taken care of, because her
father left her when he died the income of a large farm
on the outskirts of a city. The city has since grown
and the land is now worth, at conservative estimate,
about twenty million dollars. It is covered with office
buildings, and the greater part of the income, which
cannot be spent by the woman, is piling up at compound
interest. The woman enjoys good health, so she may be
worth a hundred million dollars before she dies.
I choose this case because it is one about which
there can be no disputing; this woman has never been
able to do anything to earn that twenty million
dollars. And if a visitor from Mars should come down to
study the situation, which would he think was most
insane, the unfortunate woman, or the society which
compels thousands of people to wear themselves to death
in order to pay her the income of twenty million
dollars?
The fact that this woman is insane makes it easy to
see that she is not entitled to the "unearned
increment" of the land she owns. But how about all the
other people who have bought up and are holding for
speculation the most desirable land? The value of this
land increases, not because of anything these owners do
— not because of any useful service they render
to the community — but purely because the
community as a whole is crowding into that neighborhood
and must have use of the land.
The speculator who bought this land thinks that he
deserves the increase, because he guessed the fact that
the city was going to grow that way. But it seems clear
enough that his skill in guessing which way the
community was going to grow, however useful that skill
may be to himself, is not in any way useful to the
community. The man may have planted trees, or built
roads, and put in sidewalks and sewers; all that is
useful work, and for that he should be paid. But should
he be paid for guessing what the rest of us were going
to need?
Before you answer, consider the consequences of this
guessing game. The consequences of land speculation are
tenantry and debt on the farms, and slums and luxury in
the cities. A great part of the necessary land is held
out of use, and so the value of all land continually
increases, until the poor man can no longer own a home.
The value of farm land also increases; so year by year
more independent farmers are dispossessed, because they
cannot pay interest on their mortgages. So the land
becomes a place of serfdom, that land described by the
poet, "where wealth accumulates and men decay." The
great cities fill up with festering slums, and a small
class of idle parasites are provided with enormous
fortunes, which they do not have to earn, and which
they cannot intelligently spend. ...
In Philadelphia, as in all our great cities, are
enormously wealthy families, living on hereditary
incomes derived from crowded slums. Here and there
among these rich men is one who realizes that he has
not earned what he is consuming, and that it has not
brought him happiness, and is bringing still less to
his children. Such men are casting about for ways to
invest their money without breeding idleness and
parasitism. Some of them might be grateful to learn
about this enclave plan, and to visit the lovely
village of Arden, and see what its people are doing to
make possible a peaceful and joyous life, even in this
land of bootleggers and jazz orchestras. ... read the whole
article
Henry George called attention to this situation over
fifty years ago. The contradiction between increasing
plenty, increase of potential security — and
actual want and insecurity is stated in the title of
his chief work, Progress and Poverty. That is what his
book is about. It is a record of the fact that as the
means and appliances of civilization increase, poverty
and insecurity also increase. It is an exploration of
why millionaires and tramps multiply together. It is a
prediction of why this state of affairs will continue;
it is a prediction of the plight in which the nation
finds itself today. At the same time it is the
explanation of why this condition is artificial,
man-made, unnecessary, and how it can be remedied. So I
suggest that as a beginning of the first steps to
permanent recovery there be a nationwide revival of
interest in the writings and teachings of Henry George
and that there be such an enlightenment of public
opinion that our representatives in legislatures and
public places be compelled to adopt the changes he
urged. ...
... Yet these words were penned in 1883, just fifty
years ago, by George in his work called Social
Problems, every word of which applies to our present
condition, only in a more intense degree. Nor did our
people have to wait for the advent of technocrats to
hear that the machine and the control of power make it
possible to abolish poverty while actually improvements
in the machinery of production and distribution are
working in the opposite direction. Fifty years ago,
George pointed out the same contrast. On the one hand,
as he said: "Productive power in such a state of
civilization as ours is sufficient did we give it play,
to so enormously increase the production of wealth as
to give abundance to all." On the other hand, now, as
when George wrote: "The tendency of all the inventions
and improvements so wonderfully augmenting productive
power is to concentrate enormous wealth in the hands of
a few, to make the condition of the many more hopeless
. . . Without a single exception I can think of, the
effect of all modern industrial improvements is to
production upon a large scale, to the minute division
of labor, to the giving of large capital an
overpowering advantage . . . The tendency of the
machine is in everything not merely to place it out of
the power of the workman to become his own employer,
but to reduce him to the position of a mere feeder or
attendant; to dispense with judgment, skill and brains
. . . He has no more control of the conditions that
give him employment than has the passenger in the
railway train over the motion of the train." And yet
machine and scientific technology contains in itself
the possibility of the complete abolition of want and
poverty. What is the trouble? ... read the whole speech
Robert H. Browne: Abraham Lincoln and the
Men of His Time
“Christ knew better than we that 'No man
having put his hand to the plow and looking back is fit
for the kingdom of God;' nor is many man doing his duty
who shrinks and is faithless to his fellow-men. Now a
word more about Abolitionists and new ideas in
Government, whatever they may be: We are all called
Abolitionists now who desire any restriction of slavery
or believe that the system is wrong, as I have declared
for years. We are called so, not to help out a peaceful
solution, but in derision, to abase us, and enable the
defamers to make successful combinations against us. I
never was much annoyed by these, less now than ever. I
favor the best plan to restrict the extension of
slavery peacefully, and fully believe that we must
reach some plan that will do it, and provide for some
method of final extinction of the evil, before we can
have permanent peace on the subject. On other questions
there is ample room for reform when the time comes; but
now it would be folly to think that we could undertake
more than we have on hand. But when slavery is
over with and settled, men should never rest content
while oppressions, wrongs, and iniquities are in force
against them.
“The land, the earth that God gave to
man for his home, his sustenance, and support, should
never be the possession of any man, corporation,
society, or unfriendly Government, any more than the
air or the water, if as much. An individual company or
enterprise requiring land should hold no more in their
own right than is needed for their home and sustenance,
and never more than they have in actual use in the
prudent management of their legitimate business, and
this much should not be permitted when it creates an
exclusive monopoly. All that is not so used should be
held for the free use of every family to make
homesteads, and to hold them as long as they are so
occupied.
“A reform like this will be worked out
some time in the future. The idle talk of foolish men,
that is so common now, on 'Abolitionists, agitators,
and disturbers of the peace,' will find its way against
it, with whatever force it may possess, and as strongly
promoted and carried on as it can be by land
monopolists, grasping landlords, and the titled and
untitled senseless enemies of mankind
everywhere.” ... read extended
excerpts
Peter Barnes:
Capitalism 3.0 — Chapter 2: A Short History of
Capitalism (pages 15-32)
In the beginning, the commons was everywhere. Humans
and other animals roamed around it, hunting and
gathering. Like other species, we had territories, but
these were tribal, not individual. ...
Why did this happen? There are many
explanations. One is that welfare kept the poor poor;
this was argued by Charles Murray in his 1984 book
Losing Ground. Welfare, he contended,
encouraged single mothers to remain unmarried,
increased the incidence of out-of-wedlock births, and
created a parasitic underclass. In other words, Murray
(and others) blamed victims or particular policies for
perpetuating poverty, but paid scant attention to why
poverty exists in the first place.
There are, of course, many roots, but my own
hypothesis is this: much of what we label private
wealth is taken from, or coproduced with, the commons.
However, these takings from the commons are far from
equal. To put it bluntly, the rich are rich
because (through corporations) they get the
lion’s share of common wealth; the poor are poor
because they get very little.
Another way to say this is that, just as
water flows downhill to the sea, so money flows uphill
to property. Capitalism by its very design
maximizes returns to existing wealth owners. It
benefits, in particular, those who own stock when a
successful company is young; they can receive hundreds,
even thousands of times their initial investments when
the company matures. Moreover, once such stockholders
accumulate wealth, they can increase it through
reinvestment, pass it on to their heirs, and use their
inevitable influence over politicians to gain extra
advantages — witness the steady lowering of taxes
on capital gains, dividends, and inheritances. On top
of this, in the last few decades, has been the
phenomenon called globalization. The whole point of
globalization is to increase the return to capital by
enabling its owners to find the lowest costs on the
planet. Hence the stagnation at the bottom alongside
the surging wealth at the top. ...
read the whole chapter
Turning land-value gains into capital
gains
Hiding the free lunch
Two appraisal methods
How land gets a negative value!
Where did all the land value go?
A curious asymmetry
Site values as the economy's "credit sink"
Immortally aging buildings
Real estate industry's priorities
THE FREE LUNCH Its cost to citizens
Its cost to the economy
Hiding the free lunch
BAUDELAIRE OBSERVED that the devil wins at the
point where he convinces humanity that he does not
exist. The Financial, Insurance and Real Estate
(FIRE) sectors seem to have adopted a kindred
philosophy that what is not quantified and reported
will be invisible to the tax collector, leaving more to
be pledged for mortgage credit and paid out as
interest. It appears to have worked. To academic theorists as well., breathlessly
focused on their own particular hypothetical world, the
magnitude of land rent and land-price gains has become
invisible. But not to
investors. They are out to pick a property whose
location value increases faster rate than the interest
charges, and they want to stay away from earnings on
man-made capital -- like improvements. That's earned
income, not the "free lunch" they get from land value
increases.
Chicago School economists
insist that no free lunch exists. But when one
begins to look beneath the surface of national income
statistics and the national balance sheet of assets and
liabilities, one can see that modern economies are all
about obtaining a free lunch. However, to make this
free ride go all the faster, it helps
if the rest of the world does not see that anyone is
getting the proverbial something for nothing -
what classical economists called unearned income, most characteristically in
the form of land rent. You start by
using a method of appraising that undervalues the real
income producer, land. Here's how it's
done. Read the whole
article
Bill Batt: How Our
Towns Got That Way (1996 speech)
We face a far greater problem on
account of the way in which America has allowed its
landscape to be configured than most people today
realize. Over-reliance upon the car
causes inefficiencies in transportation patterns and
thereby disenfranchises the poor, the disabled, the young
and the old from their right to mobility. One 1993
study concludes that "when the full range of costs of
transportation are tallied, passenger ground
transportation costs the American public a total of $1.2
to $1.6 trillion each year. This is equal to about
one-quarter of the annual GNP and is greater than our
total national annual expenditure on either education or
health." Just the costs of motor vehicle accidents
nothing else represents a figure equal to 8 percent of
the American Gross Domestic Product. Conventional
American land use configurations and the automobile
dependent lifestyle that goes with it sap our resources
and what effort could be used for other ventures and
activities. Since so much of this activity is consumption
and not production, it weakens America's world economic
position and precludes reinvestment in more productive
areas. Because of the way in which we
have encouraged development, people who need jobs are
frequently too poor to own the cars necessary to get to
them. ...
read the whole article
Martin Luther King, Jr: Where Do
We Go From Here? (1967)
Up to recently we have proceeded from a premise that
poverty is a consequence of multiple evils:
-
lack of education restricting job opportunities;
-
poor housing which stultified home life and
suppressed initiative;
-
fragile family relationships which distorted
personality development.
-
The logic of this approach suggested that each of
these causes be attacked one by one. Hence a housing
program to transform living conditions, improved
educational facilities to furnish tools for better
job opportunities, and family counseling to create
better personal adjustments were designed. In
combination these measures were intended to remove
the causes of poverty.
While none of these remedies in itself is unsound,
all have a fatal disadvantage. ...
In addition to the absence of coordination and
sufficiency, the programs of the past all have
another common failing -- they are indirect. Each
seeks to solve poverty by first solving something
else.
I am now convinced that the simplest approach will
prove to be the most effective -- the solution to
poverty is to abolish it directly by a now widely
discussed measure: the guaranteed income. ...
Our nation's adjustment to a new mode of thinking
will be facilitated if we realize that for nearly
forty years two groups in our society have already
been enjoying a guaranteed income. Indeed, it is a
symptom of our confused social values that these two
groups turn out to be the richest and the poorest.
The wealthy who own securities have always had an
assured income; and their polar opposite, the relief
client, has been guaranteed an income, however
miniscule, through welfare benefits. ...
I want to say to you as I move to my conclusion, as
we talk about "Where do we go from here," that we
honestly face the fact that the Movement must address
itself to the question of restructuring the whole of
American society. There are forty million poor people
here. And one day we must ask the question, "Why are
there forty million poor people in America?" And when
you begin to ask that question, you are raising
questions about the economic system, about a broader
distribution of wealth. When you ask that question,
you begin to question the capitalistic economy. And
I'm simply saying that more and more, we've got to
begin to ask questions about the whole society. We
are called upon to help the discouraged beggars in
life's market place. But one day we must come to see
that an edifice which produces beggars needs
restructuring. It means that questions must be
raised. You see, my friends, when you deal with this,
-
you begin to ask the question, "Who owns the oil?"
You begin to ask the question, "Who owns the iron
ore?"
You begin to ask the question, "Why is it that
people have to pay water bills in a world that is
two thirds water?"
Thomas Flavin, writing in The
Iconoclast, 1897
Now, it is quite true that all taxes of whatever
nature are paid out of the products of labor. But must
they be for that reason a tax on labor products. Let us
see.
I suppose you won't deny that a unit of labor
applies to different kinds of land will give very
different results. Suppose that a unit of labor
produces on A's land 4, on B's 3, on C's 2 and on D's
1. A's land is the most, and D's is the least,
productive land in use in the community to which they
belong. B's and C's represent intermediate grades.
Suppose each occupies the best land that was open to
him when he entered into possession. Now, B, and C, and
D have just as good a right to the use of the best land
as A had.
Manifestly then, if this be the whole story, there
cannot be equality of opportunity where a unit of labor
produces such different results, all other things being
equal except the land.
How is this equality to be secured? There is but one
possible way. Each must surrender for the common use of
all, himself included, whatever advantages accrues to
him from the possession of land superior to that which
falls to the lot of him who occupies the poorest.
In the case stated, what the unit of labor produces
for D, is what it should produce for A, B and C, if
these are not to have an advantage of natural
opportunity over D.
Hence equity is secured when A pays 3, D, 2 and C, 1
into a common fund for the common use of all--to be
expended, say in digging a well, making a road or
bridge, building a school, or other public utility.
Is it not manifest that here the tax which A, B and
C pay into a common fund, and from which D is exempt,
is not a tax on their labor products (though paid out
of them) but a tax on the superior advantage which they
enjoy over D, and to which D has just as good a right
as any of them.
The result of this arrangement is that each takes up
as much of the best land open to him as he can put to
gainful use, and what he cannot so use he leaves open
for the next. Moreover, he is at no disadvantage with
the rest who have come in ahead of him, for they
provide for him, in proportion to their respective
advantages, those public utilities which invariably
arise wherever men live in communities. Of course he
will in turn hold to those who come later the same
relation that those who came earlier held to him.
Suppose now that taxes had been levied on labor
products instead of land; all that any land-holder
would have to do to avoid the tax is to produce little
or nothing. He could just squat on his land, neither
using it himself nor letting others use it, but he
would not stop at this, for he would grab to the last
acre all that he could possibly get hold of. Each of
the others would do the same in turn, with the sure
result that by and by, E, F and G would find no land
left for them on which they might make a living.
So they would have to hire their labor to those who
had already monopolized the land, or else buy or rent a
piece of land from them. Behold now the devil of
landlordism getting his hoof on God's handiwork! Exit
justice, freedom, social peace and plenty. Enter
robbery, slavery, social discontent, consuming grief,
riotous but unearned wealth, degrading pauperism, crime
breeding, want, the beggar's whine, and the tyrant's
iron heel.
And how did it all come about? By the simple
expedient of taxing labor products in order that
precious landlordism might laugh and grow fat on the
bovine stupidity of the community that contributes its
own land values toward its own enslavement!
And yet men vacuously ask, "What difference does it
make?"
O tempora! O mores! To be as plain as is necessary,
it makes this four-fold difference.
- First, it robs the community of its land
values;
- second, it robs labor of its wages in the name of
taxation;
- third, it sustains and fosters landlordism, a
most conspicuously damnable difference;
- fourth, it exhibits willing workers in enforced
idleness; beholding their families in want on the one
hand, and unused land that would yield them abundance
on the other.
This last is a difference that cries to heaven for
vengeance, and if it does not always cry in vain, will
W. C. Brann be able to draw his robe close around him
and with a good conscience exclaim, "It's none of my
fault; I am not my brother's keeper."
Milton, quoted by James Dundas White in a pamphlet
entitled "Land-Value
Policy"
Nature's Full Blessings
"If every just man that now pines with want
Had but a moderate and beseeming share
Of that which lewdly-pampered Luxury
Now heaps upon some few with vast excess,
Nature's full blessings would he well dispensed
In unsuperfluous even proportion,
And she no whit encumbered with her store."
[Milton, COMUS, 768-774]
Patrick Edward Dove, quoted by James Dundas White in a
pamphlet entitled "Land-Value
Policy"
"Political economists have insisted much on the small
matters that affect the value of labor. By far the most
important is the mode in which the land is distributed.
Wherever there is a free soil, labor maintains its
value. Wherever the soil is in the hands of a few
proprietors, or tied up by entails, labor necessarily
undergoes depreciation. In fact, it is the disposition
of the land that determines the value of labor. If men
could get the land to labor on, they would manufacture
only for a remuneration that afforded more profit than
God has attached to the cultivation of the earth. Where
they cannot get the land to labor on, they are starved
into working for a bare subsistence." [Patrick Edward
DOVE, Theory of Human Progression, 1850, p. 406 n]
Rev. A. C. Auchmuty: Gems from George, a themed
collection of excerpts from the writings of Henry
George (with links to sources)
OR let him go to Edinburgh, the "modern Athens," of
which Scotsmen speak with pride, and in buildings from
whose roofs a bowman might strike the spires of twenty
churches he will find human beings living as he would
not keep his meanest dog. Let him toil up the stairs of
one of those monstrous buildings, let him enter one of
those "dark houses," let him close the door, and in the
blackness think what life must be in such a place. Then
let him try the reduction to iniquity. And if he go to
that good charity (but, alas! how futile is Charity
without Justice!) where little children are kept while
their mothers are at work, and children are fed who
would otherwise go hungry, he may see infants whose
limbs are shrunken from want of nourishment. Perhaps
they may tell him, as they told me, of that little
girl, barefooted, ragged, and hungry, who, when they
gave her bread, raised her eyes and clasped her hands,
and thanked our Father in Heaven for His bounty to her.
They who told me that never dreamed, I think, of its
terrible meaning. But I ask the Duke of Argyll, did
that little child, thankful for that poor dole, get
what our Father provided for her? Is He so niggard? If
not, what is it, who is it, that stands, between such
children and our Father's bounty? If it be an
institution, is it not our duty to God and to our
neighbor to rest not till we destroy it? If it be a
man, were it not better for him that a millstone were
hanged about his neck and he were cast into the depths
of the sea? — The Reduction to Iniquity (a reply
to the Duke of Argyll), The Nineteenth Century, July,
1884
WE are so accustomed to poverty that even in the
most advanced countries we regard it as the natural lot
of the great masses of the people; that we take it as a
matter of course that even in our highest civilization
large classes should want the necessaries of healthful
life, and the vast majority should only get a poor and
pinched living by the hardest toil. There are
professors of political economy who teach that this
condition of things is the result of social laws of
which it is idle to complain! There are ministers of
religion who preach that this is the condition which an
all-wise, all-powerful Creator intended for His
children! If an architect were to build a theater so
that not more than one-tenth of the audience could see
and hear, we should call him a bungler and a botcher.
If a man were to give a feast and provide so little
food that nine-tenths of his guests must go away
hungry, we should call him a fool, or worse. Yet so
accustomed are we to poverty, that even the preachers
of what passes for Christianity tell us that the great
Architect of the Universe, to whose infinite skill all
nature testifies, has made such a botch job of this
world that the vast majority of the human creatures
whom He has called into it are condemned by the
conditions he has imposed to want, suffering, and
brutalizing toil that gives no opportunity for the
development of mental powers — must pass their
lives in a hard struggle to merely live! — Social
Problems
THAT thought on social questions is so confused and
perplexed, that the aspirations of great bodies of men,
deeply though vaguely conscious of injustice, are in
all civilized countries being diverted to futile and
dangerous remedies, is largely due to the fact that
those who assume and are credited with superior
knowledge of social and economic laws have devoted
their powers, not to showing where the injustice lies
but to hiding it; not to clearing common thought but to
confusing it. — A Perplexed Philosopher
(Conclusion)
TAKE now some hard-headed businessman, who has no
theories, but knows how to make money. Say to him:
"Here is a little village; in ten years it will be a
great city — in ten years the railroad will have
taken the place of the stagecoach, the electric light
of the candle; it will abound with all the machinery
and improvements that so enormously multiply the
effective power of labor. Will, in ten years, interest
be any higher?"
He will tell you, "No!"
"Will the wages of common labor be any higher; will
it be easier for a man who has nothing but his labor to
make an independent living?"
He will tell you, "No; the wages of common labor
will not be any higher; on the contrary, all the
chances are that they will be lower; it will not be
easier for the mere laborer to make an independent
living; the chances are that it will be harder."
"What, then, will be higher?" " Rent; the value of
land. Go; get yourself a piece of ground, and hold
possession."
And if, under such circumstances, you take his
advice, you need do nothing more. You may sit down and
smoke your pipe; you may lie around like the lazzaroni
of Naples or the leperos of Mexico: you may go up in a
balloon, or down a hole in the ground; and without
doing one stroke of work, without adding one iota to
the wealth of the community, in ten years you will be
rich! In the new city you may have a luxurious mansion;
but among its public buildings will be an almshouse.
— Progress & Poverty — Book V, Chapter
2: The Problem Solved: The Persistence of Poverty amid
Advancing Wealth
THERE may be disputes as to whether there is yet a
science of political economy, that is to say, whether
our knowledge of the natural economic laws is as yet so
large and well digested as to merit the title of
science. But among those who recognize that the world
we live in is in all its spheres governed by law, there
can be no dispute as to the possibility of such a
science. — The Science of Political Economy
— unabridged: Book I, Chapter 14, The Meaning of
Political Economy: Political Economy as Science and as
Art • abridged: Part 1, Chapter 12: Political
Economy as Science and Art
THE domain of law is not confined to physical
nature. It just as certainly embraces the mental and
moral universe, and social growth and social life have
their laws as fixed as those of matter and of motion.
Would we make social life healthy and happy, we must
discover those laws, and seek our ends in accordance
with them. — Social Problems — Chapter 22:
Conclusion
THE general subjection of the many to the few, which
we meet with wherever society has reached a certain
development, has resulted from the appropriation of
land as individual property. It is the ownership of the
soil that everywhere gives the ownership of the men
that live upon it. It is slavery of this kind to which
the enduring pyramids and the colossal monuments of
Egypt yet bear witness, and of the institution of which
we have, perhaps, a vague tradition in the biblical
story of the famine during which the Pharaoh purchased
up the lands of the people. It was slavery of this kind
to which, in the twilight of history, the conquerors of
Greece reduced the original inhabitants of that
peninsula, transforming them into helots by making them
pay rent for their lands. It was the growth of the
latifundia, or great landed estates, which transmuted
the population of ancient Italy from a race of hardy
husbandmen, whose robust virtues conquered the world,
into a race of cringing bondsmen; it was the
appropriation of the land as the absolute property of
their chieftains which gradually turned the descendants
of free and equal Gallic, Teutonic and Hunnish warriors
into colonii and villains, and which changed the
independent burghers of Sclavonic village communities
into the boors of Russia and the serfs of Poland; which
instituted the feudalism of China and Japan, as well as
that of Europe, and which made the High Chiefs of
Polynesia the all but absolute masters of their
fellows. How it came to pass that the Aryan shepherds
and warriors who, as comparative philology tells us,
descended from the common birth-place of the
Indo-Germanic race into the lowlands of India, were
turned into the suppliant and cringing Hindoo, the
Sanscrit verse which I have before quoted gives us a
hint. The white parasols and the elephants mad with
pride of the Indian Rajah are the flowers of grants of
land. — Progress & Poverty — Book VII,
Chapter 1, Justice of the Remedy: Injustice of private
property in land
TRACE to their root the causes that are thus
producing want in the midst of plenty, ignorance in the
midst of intelligence, aristocracy in democracy,
weakness in strength — that are giving to our
civilization a one-sided and unstable development, and
you will find it something which this Hebrew statesman
three thousand years ago perceived and guarded against.
Moses saw that the real cause of the enslavement of the
masses of Egypt was, what has everywhere produced
enslavement, the possession by a class of the land upon
which, and from which, the whole people must live. He
saw that to permit in land the same unqualified private
ownership that by natural right attaches to the things
produced by labor, would be inevitably to separate the
people into the very rich and the very poor, inevitably
to enslave labor — to make the few the masters
of. the many, no matter what the political forms, to
bring vice and degradation, no matter what the
religion.
And with the foresight of the philosophic statesman who
legislates not for the need of a day, but for all the
future, he sought, in ways suited to his times and
conditions, to guard against this error. —
Moses
THE women who by the thousands are bending over
their needles or sewing machines, thirteen, fourteen,
sixteen hours a day; these widows straining and
striving to bring up the little ones deprived of their
natural bread-winner; the children that are growing up
in squalor and wretchedness, under-clothed, under-fed,
under-educated, even in this city without any place to
play — growing up under conditions in which only
a miracle can keep them pure — under conditions
which condemn them in advance to the penitentiary or
the brothel — they suffer, they die, because we
permit them to be robbed, robbed of their birthright,
robbed by a system which disinherits the vast majority
of the children that come into the world. There is
enough and to spare for them. Had they the equal rights
in the estate which their Creator has given them, there
would be no young girls forced to unwomanly toil to eke
out a mere existence, no widows finding it such a
bitter, bitter struggle to put bread in the mouths of
their little children; no such misery and squalor as we
may see here in the greatest of American cities; misery
and squalor that are deepest in the largest and richest
centers of our civilization today. — Thou Shalt
Not Steal
THE poverty to which in advancing civilization great
masses of men are condemned, is not the freedom from
distraction and temptation which sages have sought and
philosophers have praised: it is a degrading and
embruting slavery, that cramps the higher nature, dulls
the finer feelings, and drives men by its pain to acts
which the brutes would refuse. It is into this
helpless, hopeless poverty, that crushes manhood and
destroys womanhood, that robs even childhood of its
innocence and joy, that the working classes are being
driven by a force which acts upon them like a
resistless and unpitying machine. The Boston collar
manufacturer who pays his girls two cents an hour may
commiserate their condition, but he, as they, is
governed by the law of competition, and cannot pay more
and carry on his business, for exchange is not governed
by sentiment. And so, through all intermediate
gradations, up to those who receive the earnings of
labor without return, in the rent of land, it is the
inexorable laws of supply and demand, a power with
which the individual can no more quarrel or dispute
than with the winds and the tides, that seem to press
down the lower classes into the slavery of want.
But, in reality, the cause is that which always has,
and always must result in slavery — the
monopolization by some of what nature has designed for
all. . . . Private ownership of land is the nether
millstone. Material progress is the upper millstone.
Between them; with an increasing pressure, the working
classes are being ground. — Progress &
Poverty — Book VII, Chapter 2, Justice of the
Remedy: Enslavement of laborers the ultimate result of
private property in land
IT is not in the relations of capital and labor; it
is not in the pressure of population against
subsistence that an explanation of the unequal
development of our civilization is to be found. The
great cause of inequality in the distribution of wealth
is inequality in the ownership of land. The ownership
of land is the great fundamental fact which ultimately
determines the social, the political and, consequently,
the intellectual and moral condition of a people. And
it must be so. For land is the habitation of man, the
storehouse upon which he must draw for all his needs,
the material to which his labor must be applied for the
supply of all his desires; for even the products of the
sea cannot be taken, the light of the sun enjoyed, or
any of the forces of nature utilized, without the use
of land or its products. On the land we are born, from
it we live, to it we return again — children of
the soil as truly as is the blade of grass or the
flower of the field. — Progress & Poverty
— Book V, Chapter 2: The Problem Solved: The
persistence of poverty amid advancing wealth
THERE is nothing strange or inexplicable in the
phenomena that are now perplexing the world. It is not
that material progress is not in itself a good, it is
not that nature has called into being children for whom
she has failed to provide; it is not that the Creator
has left on natural laws a taint of injustice at which
even the human mind revolts, that material progress
brings such bitter fruits. That amid our highest
civilization men faint and die with want is not due to
the niggardliness of nature, but to the injustice of
man. Vice and misery, poverty and pauperism, are not
the legitimate results of increase of population and
industrial development; they only follow increase of
population and industrial development because land is
treated as private property — they are the direct
and necessary results of the violation of the supreme
law of justice, involved in giving to some men the
exclusive possession of that which nature provides for
all men. — Progress & Poverty — Book
VII, Chapter 1, Justice of the Remedy: Injustice of
private property in land
LABOR may be likened to a man who as he carries home
his earnings is waylaid by a series of robbers. One
demands this much, and another that much, but last of
all stands one who demands all that is left, save just
enough to enable the victim to maintain life and come
forth next day to work. So long as this last robber
remains, what will it benefit such a man to drive off
any or all of the other robbers?
Such is the situation of labor today throughout the
civilized world. And the robber that takes all that is
left, is private property in land. Improvement, no
matter how great, and reform, no matter how beneficial
in itself, cannot help that class who, deprived of all
right to the use of the material elements, have only
the power to labor — a power as useless in itself
as a sail without wind, a pump without water, or a
saddle without a horse. — Protection or Free
Trade — Chapter 25: The Robber That Takes All
That Is Left - econlib | abridged
THERE is but one way to remove an evil — and
that is, to remove its cause. Poverty deepens as wealth
increases, and wages are forced down while productive
power grows, because land, which is the source of all
wealth and the field of all labor, is monopolized. To
extirpate poverty, to make wages what justice commands
they should be, the full earnings of the laborer, we
must therefore substitute for the individual ownership
of land a common ownership. Nothing else will go to the
cause of the evil — in nothing else is there the
slightest hope. — Progress & Poverty —
Book VI, Chapter 2, The Remedy: The True Remedy
BUT is there not some line the recognition of which
will enable us to say with something like scientific
precision that this man is rich and that man is poor;
some line of possession which will enable us truly to
distinguish between rich and poor in all places and
conditions of society; a line of the natural mean or
normal possession, below which in varying degrees is
poverty, and above which in varying degrees is
wealthiness? It seems to me that there must be. And if
we stop to think of it, we may see that there is. If we
set aside for the moment the narrower economic meaning
of service, by which direct service is conveniently
distinguished from the indirect service embodied in
wealth, we may resolve all the things which directly or
indirectly satisfy human desire into one term service,
just as we resolve fractions into a common denominator.
Now is there not a natural or normal line of the
possession or enjoyment of service? Clearly there is.
It is that of equality between giving and receiving.
This is the equilibrium which Confucius expressed in
the golden word of his teaching that in English we
translate into "reciprocity." Naturally the services
which a member of a human society is entitled to
receive from other members are the equivalents of those
he renders to others. Here is the normal line from
which what we call wealthiness and what we call poverty
take their start. He who can command more service than
he need render, is rich. He is poor, who can command
less service than he does render or is willing to
render: for in our civilization of today we must take
note of the monstrous fact that men willing to work
cannot always find opportunity to work. The one has
more than he ought to have; the other has less. Rich
and poor are thus correlatives of each other; the
existence of a class of rich involves the existence of
a class of poor, and the reverse; and abnormal luxury
on the one side and abnormal want on the other have a
relation of necessary sequence. To put this relation
into terms of morals, the rich are the robbers, since
they are at least sharers in the proceeds of robbery;
and the poor are the robbed. This is the reason, I take
it, why Christ, Who was not really a man of such
reckless speech as some Christians deem Him to have
been, always expressed sympathy with the poor and
repugnance of the rich. In His philosophy it was better
even to be robbed than to rob. In the kingdom of right
doing which He preached, rich and poor would be
impossible, because rich and poor in the true sense are
the results of wrong-doing. And when He said, "It is
easier for a camel to pass through the eye of a needle
than for a rich man to enter the kingdom of heaven," He
simply put in the emphatic form of Eastern metaphor a
statement of fact as coldly true as the statement that
two parallel lines can never meet. Injustice cannot
live where justice rules, and even if the man himself
might get through, his riches — his power of
compelling service without rendering service —
must of necessity be left behind. If there can be no
poor in the kingdom of heaven, clearly there can be no
rich. And so it is utterly impossible in this, or in
any other conceivable world, to abolish unjust poverty,
without at the same time abolishing unjust possessions.
This is a hard word to the softly amiable
philanthropists, who, to speak metaphorically, would
like to get on the good side of God without angering
the devil. But it is a true word nevertheless. —
The Science of Political Economy unabridged: Book II,
Chapter 19, The Nature of Wealth: Moral Confusions as
to Wealth • abridged: Part II, Chapter 15, The
Nature of Wealth: Moral Confusions as to Wealth
...
"Wise" and "Babes"
IT is as bad for a man to think that he can know
nothing as to think he knows all. There are things
which it is given to all possessing reason to know, if
they will but use that reason. And some things it may
be there are, that — as was said by one whom the
learning of the time sneered at, and the high priests
persecuted, and polite society, speaking through the
voice of those who knew not what they did, crucified
— are hidden from the wise and prudent and
revealed unto babes. — A Perplexed
Philosopher
(Conclusion)
THAT thought on social questions is so confused and
perplexed, that the aspirations of great bodies of men,
deeply though vaguely conscious of injustice, are in
all civilized countries being diverted to futile and
dangerous remedies, is largely due to the fact that
those who assume and are credited with superior
knowledge of social and economic laws have devoted
their powers, not to showing where the injustice lies
but to hiding it; not to clearing common thought but to
confusing it. — A Perplexed
Philosopher
(Conclusion)
POLITICAL economy is the simplest of the sciences. It
is but the intellectual recognition, as related to
social life, of laws which in their moral aspect men
instinctively recognize, and which are embodied in the
simple teachings of him whom the common people heard
gladly. But, like Christianity, political economy has
been warped by institutions which, denying the equality
and brotherhood of man, have enlisted authority,
silenced objection, and ingrained themselves in custom
and habit of thought. — Protection or Free
Trade, Chapter 1
econlib
... go to "Gems
from George"
|
To share this page with a friend:
right click, choose "send," and add your
comments.
|
|
Red links have not been
visited; .
Green links are pages you've seen
|
Essential Documents pertinent
to this theme:
|
|