1
2
3
Wealth and Want | |||||||
... because democracy alone is not enough to produce widely shared prosperity. | |||||||
Home | Essential Documents | Themes | All Documents | Authors | Glossary | Links | Contact Us |
Land progression
Land's highest and best use progresses from wild to agricultural to single family housing to commercial, and then to more and more intense use. When a particular site's use progresses faster than it needs to, we call it urban sprawl. When a well-located site is held out of use, or remains in a lower use than its current highest and best use, we call it underused or blighted. When land in the central business district is put to its highest and best use, land on the fringes is preserved in its wild or agricultural state. Commutes are shorter, wages higher, infrastructure and services costs minimized. A historic cottage in the downtown may be a wonderful reminder of the town's past, but for many purposes, it is no better than a hole in the ground. Specialized businesses will almost always prefer to located in the central business district, because business will be better if they can draw customers and employees from a 360 degree radius. We may find progress quite upsetting. Open fields we remember from childhood give way to subdivisions. Subdivisions of homes that seemed palatial when we were children are being torn down because the split-level or single-story homes that served well now are considered too small or obsolete, and are often places that are now considered quite well-located, served by highways, public transportation, infrastructure, established schools. Older single family homes downtown which once housed the town's most successful business people and professionals are now subdivided into apartments, or torn down to be replaced by low-rise or even high-rise condominiums. We may mourn the passing of an era, or the absence of beloved reminders of our earlier years. But we fail to remember that the downtown of our childhood had not been that way forever. Teardowns are a sign of progress, of the reuse of our best sites. They are a reminder that tastes change, technology improves, but locations close to the centers of activity are in high demand. Put them to a better use. Louis Post: Outlines of Louis F. Post's Lectures, with Illustrative Notes and Charts (1894) — Appendix: FAQ
Charles B. Fillebrown: A Catechism of Natural Taxation, from Principles of Natural Taxation (1917)
Winston Churchill: Land Price as a Cause of Poverty (1909 speech in Parliament)
I do not think the Leader of the Opposition could
have chosen a more unfortunate example than Glasgow. He
said that the demand of that great community for land was
for not more than forty acres a year. Is that the only
demand of the people of Glasgow for land? Does that
really represent the complete economic and natural demand
for the amount of land a population of that size requires
to live on? I will admit that at present prices it may be
all that they can afford to purchase in the course of a
year. But there are one hundred and twenty thousand
persons in Glasgow who are living in one-room tenements;
and we are told that the utmost land those people can
absorb economically and naturally is forty acres a
year.
What is the explanation? Because the population is congested in the city the price of land is high upon the suburbs, and because the price of land is high upon the suburbs the population must remain congested within the city. That is the position which we are complacently assured is in accordance with the principles which have hitherto dominated civilised society.
The "Poor Widow" Bogey
But when we seek to rectify this system, to break down this unnatural and vicious circle, to interrupt this sequence of unsatisfactory reactions, what happens? We are not confronted with any great argument on behalf of the owner. Something else is put forward, and it is always put forward in these cases to shield the actual landowner or the actual capitalist from the logic of the argument or from the force of a Parliamentary movement. Sometimes it is the widow. But that personality has been used to exhaustion. It would be sweating in the cruellest sense of the word, overtime of the grossest description, to bring the widow out again so soon. She must have a rest for a bit; so instead of the widow we have the market-gardener -- the market-gardener liable to be disturbed on the outskirts of great cities, if the population of those cities expands, if the area which they require for their health and daily life should become larger than it is at present.
What is the position disclosed by the argument? On
the one hand, we have one hundred and twenty thousand
persons in Glasgow occupying one-room tenements; on the
other, the land of Scotland. Between the two stands the
market-gardener, and we are solemnly invited, for the
sake of the market-gardener, to keep that great
population congested within limits that are unnatural and
restricted to an annual supply of land which can bear no
relation whatever to their physical, social, and economic
needs -- and all for the sake of the market-gardener, who
can perfectly well move farther out as the city spreads
and who would not really be in the least injured.
... Read the
whole piece Nic Tideman: Land Taxation and Efficient Land Speculation
Abstract
I. Introduction II. The Private and Social Returns from Land Speculation III. Effects of Land Taxes on Speculation
A. Taxes on the Rental Value of Land
B. Taxes on the Sale Value of Land C. Taxes on Realized Income from Land D. Taxes on Realized Gains from the Sale of Land
IV. Indirect Effects of Taxing Land
V. Summary References The optimal timing of development is an important allocative function that can be either enhanced or degraded by the impact of land taxes on land speculation. This paper discusses four types of taxes on land:
All four taxes reduce incentives for speculation in land, which is generally beneficial. The third and fourth produce distortions with respect to incentives to develop land, while the first and second do not. All four taxes have some beneficial effect of mitigating imperfections in capital markets. All permit reduction or elimination of taxes with significant dead-weight losses, such as those on improvements. ... Abstract from the continuous divisibility of land and suppose that land comes in "sites." At each moment in time, each site is in one of three states: 1. Suitable for agriculture. While each site can be used for any activity, the net return will be greatest if it is used for the activity for which it is suited, provided that it remains in that activity long enough to fully amortize the associated capital that is state-specific, durable and immobile. What could keep a site from remaining in an activity long enough to amortize the associated capital is that from time to time a site makes a transition from state 1 to state 2 or from state 2 to state 3. These transitions are imperfectly predictable. When a transition from state 2 to state 3 occurs unexpectedly, the course of action that maximizes the net return to the site may entail scrapping prematurely the residential structure built there and building a commercial structure. In such an instance, one may be able to look backward and say that it would have been better not to have built the residential structure at all, but rather to have left the site in agricultural use until the transition to state 3 occurred. However, such reckoning can affect investment decisions only to the extent that transitions can be foreseen. The transitions are assumed to be costly to foresee, and to be more costly to foresee when they will be occurring further in the future. Like signs of spring, symptoms of a possible transition are at first faint and unreliable, becoming more and more obvious and certain as the time of the transition approaches. In addition to the land management motive for seeking to foresee transitions, there is a speculative motive, which differs in form and magnitude. While the land management motive is concerned with the possibility that capital will be wasted on a site that is soon to undergo a transition in state, the speculative motive arises from the gains to be made from owning title to land at the time that its better future prospects become generally known. People differ in the costs they incur in ascertaining whether the signs present at a particular site herald a pending transition, and how soon it will occur. Therefore those who have a comparative advantage in foreseeing the transitions tend to do the speculating. A speculator will incur the cost of ascertaining the significance of the signs at a particular site if, based on that speculator's experience, the probability of a transition given the signs, multiplied by the increase in the current value of the property if there is a transition, is greater than the sum of the cost of making the determination, the transactions costs of acquiring the site and the net cost of holding the site until its future prospects become generally known. The activity of speculation yields a normal expected private return to the funds spent on speculation, with particularly skillful speculators also obtaining unusual returns to their unique talents. The speculative return from foreseeing future transitions arises from holding title to land when pending transitions become generally known. This return is a purely private return, with no corresponding social return, since the land will increase in value whether or not any given speculator holds it. The land-management return from foreseeing future transitions, on the other hand, arises from knowing not to employ capital on sites where future transitions will cause the capital to depreciate prematurely. This is a social return, since it involves improving the allocation of scarce resources. There is no necessary connection between the private return and the social return. ... An additional social cost of land speculation was elucidated by Harry Gunnison Brown (1927). He pointed out that when it is possible to profit from land speculation, land will tend to be acquired by those who have the most extreme beliefs about how much it will rise in value, and that such beliefs will generally be more optimistic than is warranted. Economists have given the name "winner's curse" (Milgrom & Weber, 1982) to the phenomenon that those who bid the most tend to bid too much. The winner's curse can cause the whole land market to become dominated by persons with extreme beliefs about future rises in value, creating an artificial scarcity of land for current use, as those who have land wait for illusory future opportunities. The winner's curse is thereby shifted to society.
The next section discusses the features of various
taxes on land, and in particular their capacity to remove
the incentive for inefficient land speculation.
...
Read the whole
article Jeff Smith and Kris Nelson: Giving Life to the Property Tax
Shift (PTS)
John Muir is right. "Tug on any one thing and find
it connected to everything else in the universe." Tug on
the property tax and find it connected to urban slums,
farmland loss, political favoritism, and unearned equity
with disrupted neighborhood tenure. Echoing Thoreau, the
more familiar reforms have failed to address this
many-headed hydra at its root. To think that the root
could be chopped by a mere shift in the property tax base
-- from buildings to land -- must seem like the epitome
of unfounded faith. Yet the evidence shows that state and
local tax activists do have a powerful, if subtle, tool
at their disposal. The "stick" spurring efficient use of
land is a higher tax rate upon land, up to even the
site's full annual value. The "carrot" rewarding
efficient use of land is a lower or zero tax rate upon
improvements. ... Bill Batt: The
Merits of Site Value Taxation
Good for the economy, the PTS is also good for the eco-system. Were land levied, the owners of the most valuable sites would feel most pressure to develop; their sites tend to be closer to the city center. Hence those owners draw any needed development, infilling cities, sparing suburbs further encroachment. Other highly valued sites are those rich in natural resources. Again, using them more intensely frees up sites of lesser natural endowment. Thus, besides conserving sites, the PTS also conserves resources. A big problem needs a big solution which in turn needs a matching shift of our prevailing paradigm. Geonomics -- advocating that we share the social value of sites and natural resources and untax earnings -- does just that. Read the whole article
When one looks at the value of land in any broad
way, its value will be highest at the center and falls as
one looks out to the frontier. The highest value land,
that with the greatest accrued rent, is at the very
center of the city -- usually where the commercial
parcels are located. In the spring of
1998, one land parcel (the building was to be razed) of
less than an acre and split in two pieces in New York
City's Times Square was sold by Prudential Life to Disney
for an estimated $240 million,19more than the value of all the land and buildings
together in the lands north of the Mohawk River/Erie
Canal in New York State. The highest value land is
typically surrounded by a belt of residential areas, and
with farmlands starting at the fringe. The more valuable
parcels are taxed, the more their titleholders will find
ways to recover their carrying costs. And it cannot
affect the behavior of tenants as any change in burden is
not passed through. In this sense, land value taxation
fosters clustered development and reverses the egregious
patterns of sprawl. ... Read the
whole piece
Charles T. Root — Not a Single Tax! (1925)
...The failure to collect site
rent leads to a distortion in land use configurations. If
patterns unfolded along the lines of both social
preference and economic efficiency, high value landsites
would tend to have high value buildings, and low value
landsites would tend to be vacant or have very modest
buildings. Consistent with this, urban
centers sites would tend to have office and commercial
use, surrounded by lower-value residential land uses, and
still further out would be farms and forests. The
ratio of building to land value, land to total value (or
for that matter any other ratio between buildings, land,
and total values) would be relatively constant throughout
a region. Instead, the ratio of land value to total value
consistently tends to reveal a patchwork of random
development. This inefficient settlement of land sites is
what we know as sprawl.
Land Rent is Capitalized Transportation Cost There is another dimension to the distortion of land use in contemporary life. That is the heavy subsidy granted to motor vehicle transportation services. Estimates are that the typical driver pays only about a tenth of the true cost of his travel; society picks up the rest. This profuse subsidy paid to private automobile and truck transportation further encourages people to locate on sites at far greater distances from where they would choose than if they had to pay the full burden of that travel. ... The conventional property tax, one taxing both land values and improvement values, is analogous to a train with an engine at each end. The tax on land value fosters improvement on the parcels with the highest market and social value, while the tax on structures discourages that very same thing. No wonder it is that economic activities is stymied most in the urban centers and manifests itself in areas where the least imposition of all has taken hold. As scholar Jessica Matthews once put it,
In a now familiar sequence, developers
reach for the cheapest land, out in the cow pastures.
Government is left to fill in behind with brand new
infrastructure roads, sewerage systems and schools paid
for in part by those whose existing roads and schools are
left to decline. Property values rise in a ring that
marches steadily outward from the city and fall in older
suburbs inside the moving edge. Because residential
development can't meet the public bills, local
governments compete for commercial investment with tax
discounts that deplete their revenues still further.
Property taxes then rise, providing an incentive for new
development. Years of such leap-frogging construction
devours land at an astonishing pace.(35) ... read the
whole article
|
|
to email this page to a friend: right click, choose
"send"
|
||||||
Wealth and Want
|
www.wealthandwant.com
|
|||||
... because democracy alone hasn't yet led to a society
in which all can prosper
|