Effects of Untaxing Wages and
Interest
When the Federal Tax Reform Panel of 2005
talked about "tax reform," they seldom moved beyond
talking about income tax brackets tax and deductions. We
need to get outside the income tax box, because it is the
wrong box. A lot of problems will start to clear up when
we (a) stop taxing the wrong things and (b) shift taxes
onto things that should be taxed (see also:
land).
It is an axiom of statesmanship, which the
successful founders of tyranny have understood and
acted upon that great changes can best be brought about
under old forms. We, who would free men, should heed
the same truth. It is the natural method. When nature
would make a higher type, she takes a lower one and
develops it. This, also, is the law of social growth.
Let us work by it. With the current we may glide fast
and far. Against it, it is hard pulling and slow
progress.
By making use of this existing machinery, we may,
without jar or shock, assert the common right to land
by appropriating rent by taxation. We already take some
rent in taxation. We have only to make some changes in
our modes of taxation to take it all.*
*Rent in the economic sense is not, as
those unfamiliar with economic terminology may
assume, the whole amount paid for the use of real
estate. It is only that part of such amount which is
paid for the use of the bare land or site employed,
exclusive of the payment for the use of any buildings
or other improvements on it. H. G. B.
In form, the ownership of land would remain just as
now. No owner of land need be dispossessed, and no
restriction need be placed upon the amount of land any
one could hold. For, rent being taken by the State in
taxes, land, no matter in whose name it stood, or in
what parcels it was held, would be really common
property, and every member of the community would
participate in the advantages of its ownership.
Now, insomuch as the taxation of rent, or land
values, must necessarily be increased just as we
abolish other taxes, we may put the proposition into
practical form by proposing --
to abolish all taxation save
that upon land values.
As we have seen, the value of land is at the
beginning of society nothing, but as society develops
by the increase of population and the advance of the
arts, it becomes greater and greater. In every
civilized country, even the newest, the value of the
land taken as a whole is sufficient to bear the entire
expenses of government. In the better developed
countries it is much more than sufficient. Hence it
will not be enough merely to place all taxes upon the
value of land. It will be necessary, where rent exceeds
the present governmental revenues, commensurately to
increase the amount demanded in taxation, and to
continue this increase as society progresses and rent
advances. But this is so natural and easy a matter,
that it may be considered as involved, or at least
understood, in the proposition to put all taxes on the
value of land. That is the first step upon which the
practical struggle must be made. When the hare is once
caught and killed, cooking him will follow as a matter
of course. When the common right to land is so far
appreciated that all taxes are abolished save those
which fall upon rent, there is no danger of much more
than is necessary to induce them to collect the public
revenues being left to individual landholders.
Wherever the idea of concentrating all taxation upon
land values finds lodgment sufficient to induce
consideration, it invariably makes way, but there are
few of the classes most to be benefited by it, who at
first, or even for a long time afterward, see its full
significance and power.
- It is difficult for workingmen to get over the
idea that there is a real antagonism between capital
and labor.
- It is difficult for small farmers and homestead
owners to get over the idea that to put all taxes on
the value of land would be unduly to tax them.
- It is difficult for both classes to get over the
idea that to exempt capital from taxation would be to
make the rich richer, and the poor poorer.
These ideas spring from confused thought. But behind
ignorance and prejudice there is a powerful interest,
which has hitherto dominated literature, education, and
opinion. A great wrong always dies hard, and the great
wrong which in every civilized country condemns the
masses of men to poverty and want, will not die without
a bitter struggle. ... read the
whole chapter
H.G. Brown: Significant
Paragraphs from Henry George's Progress &
Poverty: 10. Effect of Remedy Upon Wealth
Production (in the unabridged P&P:
Part IX — Effects of the Remedy: Chapter 1 — Of
the effect upon the production of wealth)
The elder Mirabeau, we are told, ranked the
proposition of Quesnay, to substitute one single tax on
rent (the impôt unique) for all other
taxes, as a discovery equal in utility to the invention
of writing or the substitution of the use of money for
barter.
To whosoever will think over the matter, this saying
will appear an evidence of penetration rather than of
extravagance. The advantages which would be gained by
substituting for the numerous taxes by which the public
revenues are now raised, a single tax levied upon the
value of land, will appear more and more important the
more they are considered.
- This is the secret which would transform the little
village into the great city.*
- With all the burdens removed which now oppress
industry and hamper exchange, the production of wealth
would go on with a rapidity now undreamed of.
- This, in its turn, would lead to an increase in the
value of land — a new surplus which society might
take for general purposes.
- And released from the difficulties which attend the
collection of revenue in a way that begets corruption
and renders legislation the tool of special interests,
society could assume functions which the increasing
complexity of life makes it desirable to assume, but
which the prospect of political demoralization under
the present system now leads thoughtful men to shrink
from.
*At the beginning of
Book IX of the complete Progress & Poverty,
Henry George quotes from Themistocles: "I cannot play
upon any stringed instrument, but I can tell you how
of a little village to make a great and glorious
city."
Consider the effect upon the production of wealth.
To abolish the taxation which, acting and reacting,
now hampers every wheel of exchange and presses upon
every form of industry, would be like removing an immense
weight from a powerful spring. Imbued with fresh energy,
production would start into new life, and trade would
receive a stimulus which would be felt to the remotest
arteries. The present method of taxation operates upon
exchange like artificial deserts and mountains;
- it costs more to get goods through a custom house
than it does to carry them around the world.
- It operates upon energy, and industry, and skill,
and thrift, like a fine upon those qualities.
- If I have worked harder and built myself a good
house while you have been contented to live in a hovel,
the taxgatherer now comes annually to make me pay a
penalty for my energy and industry, by taxing me more
than you.
- If I have saved while you wasted, I am mulct, while
you are exempt.
- If a man build a ship we make him pay for his
temerity, as though he had done an injury to the
state;
- if a railroad be opened, down comes the tax
collector upon it, as though it were a public
nuisance;
- if a manufactory be erected we levy upon it an
annual sum which would go far toward making a handsome
profit.
- We say we want capital, but if any one accumulate
it, or bring it among us, we charge him for it as
though we were giving him a privilege.
- We punish with a tax the man who covers barren
fields with ripening grain,
- we fine him who puts up machinery, and him who
drains a swamp.
How heavily these taxes burden production only those
realize who have attempted to follow our system of
taxation through its ramifications, for, as I have before
said, the heaviest part of taxation is that which falls
in increased prices.
To abolish these taxes would be to lift the whole
enormous weight of taxation from productive industry. The
needle of the seamstress and the great manufactory; the
cart horse and the locomotive; the fishing boat and the
steamship; the farmer's plow and the merchant's stock,
would be alike untaxed. All would be free to make or to
save, to buy or to sell, unfined by taxes, unannoyed by
the taxgatherer. Instead of saying to the producer, as it
does now, "The more you add to the general wealth the
more shall you be taxed!" the state would say to the
producer, "Be as industrious, as thrifty, as enterprising
as you choose, you shall have your full reward! You shall
not be fined for making two blades of grass grow where
one grew before; you shall not be taxed for adding to the
aggregate wealth."
And will not the community gain by thus refusing to
kill the goose that lays the golden eggs; by thus
refraining from muzzling the ox that treadeth out the
corn; by thus leaving to industry, and thrift, and skill,
their natural reward, full and unimpaired? For there is
to the community also a natural reward. The law of
society is, each for all, as well as all for each. No one
can keep to himself the good he may do, any more than he
can keep the bad. Every productive enterprise, besides
its return to those who undertake it, yields collateral
advantages to others. If a man plant a fruit tree, his
gain is that he gathers the fruit in its time and season.
But in addition to his gain, there is a gain to the whole
community. Others than the owner are benefited by the
increased supply of fruit; the birds which it shelters
fly far and wide; the rain which it helps to attract
falls not alone on his field; and, even to the eye which
rests upon it from a distance, it brings a sense of
beauty. And so with everything else. The building of a
house, a factory, a ship, or a railroad, benefits others
besides those who get the direct profits.
... Well may the community leave to the individual
producer all that prompts him to exertion; well may it
let the laborer have the full reward of his labor, and
the capitalist the full return of his capital. For the
more that labor and capital produce, the greater grows
the common wealth in which all may share. And in the
value or rent of land is this general gain expressed in a
definite and concrete form. Here is a fund which the
state may take while leaving to labor and capital their
full reward. With increased activity of production this
would commensurately increase.
And to shift the burden of taxation from production
and exchange to the value or rent of land would not
merely be to give new stimulus to the production of
wealth; it would be to open new opportunities. For under
this system no one would care to hold land unless to use
it, and land now withheld from use would everywhere be
thrown open to improvement.
The selling price of land would fall; land speculation
would receive its death blow; land monopolization would
no longer pay.* Millions and millions of acres from which
settlers are now shut out by high prices would be
abandoned by their present owners or sold to settlers
upon nominal terms. And this not merely on the frontiers,
but within what are now considered well settled
districts.
* The fact that a tax on the rental
value of land cannot be shifted by landowners to
tenants, though recognized by all competent economists,
is sometimes a stumbling block to persons untrained in
economics. The reason such a tax cannot be shifted is
that it cannot limit the supply of land. Landowners are
presumably, before the tax is laid, charging all the
rent they can get. There is nothing in a tax on the
rental value of land to make tenants willing to pay
more or to make land more difficult to hire. On the
contrary, more land will be on the market, because of
such a tax, rather than less, since the tax puts a
heavy penalty on holding land out of use and unimproved
for mere speculation. The competition of former vacant
land speculators to get their land used will make land
cheaper to rent rather than more expensive. And since
only the net rent remaining after the tax is subtracted
is capitalized into salable value, land will be very
much cheaper to buy. H.G.B.
And it must be remembered that this would apply, not
merely to agricultural land, but to all land. Mineral
land would be thrown open to use, just as agricultural
land; and in the heart of a city no one could afford to
keep land from its most profitable use, or on the
outskirts to demand more for it than the use to which it
could at the time be put would warrant. Everywhere that
land had attained a value, taxation, instead of
operating, as now, as a fine upon improvement, would
operate to force improvement. Whoever planted an orchard,
or sowed a field, or built a house, or erected a
manufactory, no matter how costly, would have no more to
pay in taxes than if he kept so much land idle.
- The monopolist of agricultural land would be taxed
as much as though his land were covered with houses and
barns, with crops and with stock.
- The owner of a vacant city lot would have to pay as
much for the privilege of keeping other people off of
it until he wanted to use it, as his neighbor who has a
fine house upon his lot.
- It would cost as much to keep a row of tumble-down
shanties upon valuable land as though it were covered
with a grand hotel or a pile of great warehouses filled
with costly goods.
Thus, the bonus that wherever labor is most productive
must now be paid before labor can be exerted would
disappear.
- The farmer would not have to pay out half his
means, or mortgage his labor for years, in order to
obtain land to cultivate;
- the builder of a city homestead would not have to
lay out as much for a small lot as for the house he
puts upon it*;
- the company that proposed to erect a manufactory
would not have to expend a great part of its capital
for a site.
- And what would be paid from year to year to the
state would be in lieu of all the taxes now levied upon
improvements, machinery, and stock.
*Many persons, and among them some
professional economists, have never succeeded in
getting a thorough comprehension of this point. Thus,
the editor has heard the objection advanced that the
greater cheapness of land is no advantage to the poor
man who is trying to save enough from his earnings to
buy a piece of land; for, it is said, the higher
taxes on the land after it is acquired, offset the
lower purchase price. What such objectors do not see
is that even if the lower price of land does no more
than balance the higher tax on it, (and this
overlooks, for one thing, the discouragement to
speculation in land), the reduction or removal of
other taxes is all clear gain. It is easier to save
in proportion as earnings and commodities are
relieved of taxation. It is easier to buy land,
because its selling price is lower, if the land is
taxed. And although the land, after its purchase,
continues to be taxed, not only can this tax be fully
paid out of the annual interest on the saving in the
purchase price, but also there is to be reckoned the
saving in taxes on buildings and other improvements
and in whatever other taxes are thus rendered
unnecessary. H.G.B.
Consider the effect of such a change upon the labor
market. Competition would no longer be one-sided, as now.
Instead of laborers competing with each other for
employment, and in their competition cutting down wages
to the point of bare subsistence, employers would
everywhere be competing for laborers, and wages would
rise to the fair earnings of labor. For into the labor
market would have entered the greatest of all competitors
for the employment of labor, a competitor whose demand
cannot be satisfied until want is satisfied — the
demand of labor itself. The employers of labor would not
have merely to bid against other employers, all feeling
the stimulus of greater trade and increased profits, but
against the ability of laborers to become their own
employers upon the natural opportunities freely opened to
them by the tax which prevented monopolization.
With natural opportunities thus free to labor;
- with capital and improvements exempt from tax, and
exchange released from restrictions, the spectacle of
willing men unable to turn their labor into the things
they are suffering for would become impossible;
- the recurring paroxysms which paralyze industry
would cease;
- every wheel of production would be set in
motion;
- demand would keep pace with supply, and supply with
demand;
- trade would increase in every direction, and wealth
augment on every hand. ... read the whole
chapter
Henry George: The Land Question
(1881)
There are other most important respects in
which this measure will commend itself to the English
mind. The tax upon land values or rent is in all economic
respects the most perfect of taxes. No political
economist will deny that it combines the maximum of
certainty with the minimum of loss and cost; that, unlike
taxes upon capital or exchange or improvement, it does
not check production or enhance prices or fall ultimately
upon the consumer. And, in proposing to abolish all other
taxes in favor of this theoretically perfect tax, the
Land Reformers will have on their side the advantage of
ideas already current, while they can bring the
argumentum ad hominem to bear on
those who might never comprehend an abstract principle.
Englishmen of all classes have happily been educated up
to a belief in free trade, though a very large amount of
revenue is still collected from customs.
- Let the Land Reformers take advantage of this
by proposing to carry out the doctrine of free trade to
its fullest extent. If a revenue tariff is better than a
protective tariff, then no tariff at all is better than a
revenue tariff.
- Let them propose to abolish the customs duties
entirely, and to abolish as well harbor dues and
lighthouse dues and dock charges, and in their place to
add to the tax on rent, or the value of land exclusive of
improvements
- Let them in the same way propose to get rid of
the excise, the various license taxes, the tax upon
buildings, the onerous and unpopular income tax, etc.,
and to saddle all public expenses on the
landlords.
This would bring home the land question to
thousands and thousands who have never thought of it
before; to thousands and thousands who have heretofore
looked upon the land question as something peculiarly
Irish, or something that related exclusively to
agriculture and to farmers, and have never seen how, in
various direct and indirect ways, they have to contribute
to the immense sums received by the landlords as rent. It
would be putting the argument in a shape in which even
the most stupid could understand it. It would be
directing the appeal to a spot where even the
unimaginative are sensitive – the pocket. How long
would a merchant or banker or manufacturer or annuitant
regard as dangerous and wicked an agitation which
proposed to take taxation off of him? Even the most
prejudiced can be relied on to listen with patience to an
argument in favor of making some one else pay what they
now are paying. ... read
the whole article
Henry George: Justice
the Object -- Taxation the Means (1890)
What would be the direct result? Take this city,
this State or the whole country; abolish all taxes on the
production of wealth; let every man be free to plough, to
sow, to build, in any way add to the common stock without
being fined one penny. Say to every man who would
improve, who would in any way add to the production of
wealth: Go ahead, go ahead; produce, accumulate all you
please; add to the common stock in any way you choose;
you shall have it all; we shall not fine or tax you one
penny. What would be the result of abolishing all these
taxes that now depress industry; that now fall on labour;
that now lessen the profits of those who are adding to
the general wealth? Evidently to stimulate production; to
increase wealth; to bring new life into every vocation of
industry.
On the other side what would be the
effect when abolishing all these taxes that now fall on
labour or the products of labour, if we were to resort for
public revenue to a tax upon land values; a tax that would
fall on the owner of a vacant lot just as heavily as upon
the man who has improved a lot by putting up a house; that
would fall on the speculator who is holding 160 acres of
agricultural land idle, waiting for a tenant or a
purchaser, as heavily as it would fall upon the farmer who
had made the 160 acres bloom? Why, the result would be
everywhere that the dog in the manger would he checked; for
the result everywhere would he that the men who are holding
natural opportunities, not for use but simply for profit,
by demanding a price of those who must use them, would have
either to use their land or give way to somebody who
would.
Read the entire article Henry George:
The Great Debate:
Single Tax vs Social Democracy (1889)
Now if that were done, if the land
were let out, those using it paying its premium value to
the community, it would amount to precisely the same thing
if, instead of calling the payment rent, we called it
taxes. “A rose by any other name would smell as
sweet.” In an old country, however, there is a very
great advantage in calling the rent a tax. In an old
country there is a very great advantage in moving on that
line. People are used to the payment of taxes. They are not
used to the formal ownership of land by the community; and
to the letting of it out in that way. Therefore, as society
is now constituted, and in our communities as they now
exist, we propose to move towards our ideal along the line
of taxation. (Hear, hear.)
If we were to take the rent of land
for the community, one of the first and best uses which
would be commended to us would be that of abolishing of
taxes that bear in any way upon production, or in any way
hamper industry, or in any way increase the price of those
things that people wish to use and can use without injury
to others. Therefore, as bringing in the idea of abolishing
these taxes we call our measure the Single Tax. (Hear,
hear.)
We would abolish all taxation that
falls on industry, and raise public revenue by this means,
and move to our end, the taking of the full rental value of
land for the use of the community, in this way. This name,
Single Tax, expresses our method; not our ideal. What we
are really is liberty men; what we believe in is perfect
freedom: What we wish to do is to give each individual in
the community the liberty to exert his powers in any way he
pleases, bounded only by the equal liberty of others.
(Applause.)
We would abolish all taxes, and begin
with the most important of all monopolies, the fruitful
parent of lesser monopolies, that monopoly which
disinherits men of their birthright; that monopoly which
puts m the hands of some that, element absolutely
indispensable to the use of all; and we believe not that
labour is a poor weak thing that must be coddled or
protected by Government. We believe that labour is the
producer of all wealth – (applause) – that all
labour wants is a fair field and no favour, and, therefore,
as against the doctrines of restriction we raise the banner
of liberty and equal right in the gospel of free, fair
play. (Loud cheers.) ... Read the
entire article
Henry George: The
Crime of Poverty (1885 speech)
... Nature gives to labour, and to
labour alone; there must be human work before any article
of wealth can be produced; and in the natural state of
things the man who toiled honestly and well would be the
rich man, and he who did not work would be poor. We have
so reversed the order of nature that we are accustomed to
think of the workingman as a poor man.
And if you trace it out I believe you
will see that the primary cause of this is that we compel
those who work to pay others for permission to do so. You
may buy a coat, a horse, a house; there you are paying the
seller for labour exerted, for something that he has
produced, or that he has got from the man who did produce
it; but when you pay a man for land, what are you paying
him for? You are paying for something that no man has
produced; you pay him for something that was here before
man was, or for a value that was created, not by him
individually, but by the community of which you are a part.
What is the reason that the land here,
where we stand tonight, is worth more than it was
twenty-five years ago? What is the reason that land in the
centre of New York, that once could be bought by the mile
for a jug of whiskey, is now worth so much that, though you
were to cover it with gold, you would not have its value?
Is it not because of the increase of population?
Take away that population, and where would the value of the
land be? Look at it in any way you please.
...
Now, supposing we should abolish all
other taxes direct and indirect, substituting for them a
tax upon land values, what would be the effect?
- In the first place it would be to kill
speculative values. It would be to remove from the newer
parts of the country the bulk of the taxation and put it
on the richer parts. It would be to exempt the pioneer
from taxation and make the larger cities pay more of it.
It would be to relieve energy and enterprise, capital and
labour, from all those burdens that now bear upon them.
What a start that would give to
production!
- In the second place we could, from the value
of the land, not merely pay all the present expenses of
the government, but we could do infinitely more.
In the city of San Francisco James Lick
left a few blocks of ground to be used for public
purposes there, and the rent amounts to
so much, that out of it will be built the largest
telescope in the world, large public baths and other
public buildings, and various costly works. If,
instead of these few blocks, the whole value of the land
upon which the city is built had accrued to San Francisco
what could she not do? ... read the
whole speech
Rev. A. C. Auchmuty: Gems from George, a themed
collection of excerpts from the writings of Henry
George (with links to sources)
THAT the masses now festering in the tenement houses
of our cities, under conditions which breed disease and
death, and vice and crime, should each family have its
healthful home, set in its garden; that the working
farmer should be able to make a living with a daily
average of two or three hours' work, which more resembled
healthy recreation than toil; that his home should be
replete with all the conveniences yet esteemed luxuries;
that it should be supplied with light and heat, and power
if needed, and connected with those of his neighbors by
the telephone; that his family should be free to
libraries, and lectures, and scientific apparatus and
instruction; that they should be able to visit the
theater, or concert, or opera, as often as they cared to
do so, and occasionally to make trips to other parts of
the country or to Europe; that, in short, not merely the
successful man, the one in a thousand, but the man of
ordinary parts and ordinary foresight and prudence,
should enjoy all that advancing civilization can bring to
elevate and expand human life, seems, in the light of
existing facts, as wild a dream as ever entered the brain
of hasheesh eater. Yet the powers already within the
grasp of man make it easily possible. —
Social Problems — Chapter 21: City and
Country.
GIVE labor a free field and its full earnings; take for
the benefit of the whole community that fund which the
growth of the community creates, and want and the fear of
want would be gone. The springs of production would be
set free, and the enormous increase of wealth would give
the poorest ample comfort. Men would no more worry about
finding employment than they worry about finding air to
breathe; they need have no more care about physical
necessities than do the lilies of the field. The progress
of science, the march of invention, the diffusion of
knowledge, would bring their benefits to all.
With this abolition of want and the fear of want, the
admiration of riches would decay, and men would seek the
respect and approbation of their fellows in other modes
than by the acquisition and display of wealth. In this
way there would be brought to the management of public
affairs and the administration of common funds the skill,
the attention, the fidelity and integrity, that can now
only be secured for private interests, and a railroad or
gas works might be operated on public account, not only
more economically and efficiently than, as at present,
under joint stock management, but as economically and
efficiently as would be possible under a single
ownership. The prize of the Olympian games, that called
forth the most strenuous exertions of all Greece, was but
a wreath of wild olive; for a bit of ribbon men have over
and over again performed services no money could have
bought. —
Progress & Poverty
— Book IX, Chapter 4— Effects of the Remedy:
Of the Changes that Would be Wrought in Social
Organization and Social Life
... go to "Gems from
George"
Louis Post: Outlines
of Louis F. Post's Lectures, with Illustrative Notes and
Charts (1894) — Appendix: FAQ
Q48. Would you let money escape taxation, and so
favor money lenders?
A. It is a curious fact that this question is most
popular among people who clamor for cheap money. How they
expect to cheapen money by taxing its lenders on their
loans is past finding out. To tax money lenders is to
discourage money lending, and thereby to increase
interest on loans. Yes, we should let money escape
taxation. It escapes taxation now, which in itself is a
politic reason for exempting it; but we should exempt it
(by taxing nothing but land values) for the additional
and better reason that a man's money is his own and the
community has no right to it, while a man's land value is
the community's and the man has no right to it. This
would not favor money lenders in any invidious sense. It
would favor both lenders and borrowers; borrowers by
enabling them to borrow on easier terms, and lenders by
making their loans more secure. ... read the book
Charles B. Fillebrown: A Catechism of Natural
Taxation, from Principles of Natural Taxation
(1917)
Q19. Why should buildings and all other
improvements and personal property and capital be exempt
from taxes?
A. Because a tax on them falls upon industry, and so
increases the cost of living, while continuing the
invidious exemption of the present net land value.
Q20. Why should stocks and bonds be
exempt?
A. Stocks, because they are only paper certificates of
property which itself has been taxed once already. Bonds,
if legitimate, because a tax on borrowed money is paid
after all by the borrower and so becomes an added factor
in cost of production, and consequently in the cost of
living.
Q41. Why would the single tax be an improvement
upon present systems of taxation?
A. Because: (1) The taking for public uses of that value
which justly belongs to the public is not a tax; (2) it
would relieve all workers and capitalists of those taxes
by which they are now unjustly burdened, and (3) it would
make unprofitable the holding of land idle.
Q62. Would it be wise to take gradually in
taxation, say, 1/4, one half, or 3/4 of the future
increase in economic rent?
A. One hundred and one professors of political economy
have answered "Yes." Twenty-nine have answered
"No."
Q63. How could the single tax be put into
operation?
A. By gradually transferring to land all taxes not
already on it.
Q64. How might such a plan be worked
out?
A. If fifty cents per thousand should be deducted yearly
for 30 years from the rate on all property other than
land, the reduction would finally amount to $15 per
thousand, and it would then be practically exempt from
all taxation.
Q65. But how could it be worked out in case of the
land?
A. Recognizing that a right thing may be done in a wrong
way, it is insisted that a right way ought to be found to
do a thing that ought to be done. The following is
presented as a natural and convenient unit of calculation: To be exact,
an average of about 20 percent of the
gross ground rent of land is now taken in taxation, for
instance, in Boston, as well as for the whole state of
Massachusetts. If an additional one percent should be
taken each year for 30 years, it would amount at the end
of that period to 30 percent, which, added to 20 percent,
would make 50 percent, or one half, which is about the
average proportion that present taxes levied on all
property bear to gross ground rent. Meantime few
landowners would feel the change, much less be prejudiced
by it.
The following variable illustrations, A, B, and C, make
clear.
A "Modus
Operandi"
A Increase of Present Tax
For instance, applied to the assessment of a specific
lot of land for which the user pays a gross ground rent
of say ...... $68.00
Of which amount there is taken in taxation, 1915 .....
$18.00
Leaving a net income to the owner of ....
$50.00
The selling value (presumably also the assessed
valuation) would be at 5 per cent ... $1,000.00
Proceeding to take yearly from now on 1 per cent
additional of the gross ground rent of $68 for a period
of thirty years would amount in all to 30 per cent of
$68, equal to .... $20.40
Which, added to the tax already taken .... $18.00
Would give at the end of thirty years, from the $1,000
worth of land alone, everything else being exempted, a
total tax of .... $38.40.
Which is not much more than one half of the gross ground
rent of ... $68.00
The opening exhibit in detail would stand as
follows:
In 1915 the tax on this $1,000 worth of land was
$18.00
In 1916 the tax would be $18 plus 68 cents (1 per cent of
the gross ground rent, $68); equal to .... $18.68
Reducing the owner's net rent from $50 to $49.32
In 1917 the tax would be $18 plus $1.36 (2 per cent of
the $68), totaling .... $19.36
Reducing the owner's net rent from $50 to $48.64,
In 1918 the tax would be $18 plus $2.04 (3 per cent of
the $68) or $20.45
Reducing the owner's net rent from $50 to $47.96
In 1945 the tax on the land would be $18 plus $20.40 (30
per cent of the $68) or ... $38.40
With all improvements exempted.
Reducing the owner's net rent from $50 to $29.60.
B
For a Future Increment
Tax
The taking in taxation of any desired proportion of
the future increment could be accomplished simply by
continuing the present valuation and present rate as
constant factors, and making a separate individual
assessment of the increment tax after the following or
similar formula, according to the proportion to be
taken. For instance, to take in taxation 50 per
cent of the future increase:
Year
|
Valuation
|
Increment
|
Rate Per M.
|
Tax for Each Year
|
1915 |
$1,000 |
|
|
|
1916 |
$1,040 |
$40 |
$25 |
Tax for year 1916, $1 |
|
1915 |
$1,000 |
|
|
|
1917 |
$1,080 |
$80 |
25 |
Tax for year 1917, $2 |
|
1915 |
$1,000 |
|
|
|
1918 |
$1,120 |
$120 |
25 |
Tax for year 1918, $3 |
|
1915 |
$1,000 |
|
|
|
1919 |
$1,160 |
$160 |
25 |
Tax for year 1919, $4 |
|
1915 |
$1,000 |
|
|
|
1920 |
$1,200 |
$200 |
25 |
Tax for year 1920, $5 |
In applying this formula it would be necessary after the
first few years at least to increase the rate to
correspond to the decrease in assessed valuation due to
this new tax. For computations upon this and
related points, see the Report of the
New York City Commission on New Sources of City
Revenue (1913), p. 7 and Appendices X to XV.
C
The Assessment of Rent
It should be reiterated that inasmuchas gross
ground rent, actual or potential, is the initial factor
in getting at the value of land, it cannot be
unprofitable to become familiar with a more correct
formula as expressed in terms of rent.
Starting with the present unit of annual value for use to
take in taxation in 25 years 50 per cent of the future
increase in ground rent:
Year
|
Net Ground Rent
|
Increment
|
Percentage of Rent
|
Tax for Each Year
|
1915 |
$50 |
|
|
|
1916
|
$52 |
2 |
50 |
Tax for year 1916, $1 |
|
1915 |
$50 |
|
|
|
1917 |
54 |
4 |
50 |
Tax for year 1917, $2 |
|
1915 |
$50 |
|
|
|
1918 |
56 |
6 |
50 |
Tax for year 1918, $3 |
|
1915 |
$50 |
|
|
|
1919 |
58 |
8 |
50 |
Tax for year 1919, $4 |
|
1915 |
$50 |
|
|
|
1920
|
60
|
10
|
50
|
Tax for year 1920, $5 |
|
1915 |
$50 |
|
|
|
1940 |
100 |
50 |
50 |
Tax for year 1940, $25 |
... read
the whole article
Charles T. Root — Not a Single Tax! (1925)
Now what is this net $20,000 a year, which will be
regularly remitted to Mr. Rhinelastor, in Europe or
wherever he may be, given in payment for? Not for the old
building — the first thing the lessee does is to
pull it down. Not for the land itself — it is all
rock, which has got to be blasted out as part of its
improvement.
Clearly it is paid for a location or site value, which
the community, and the community only, has built up and
paid for. In other words, the present $20,000 rental, and
the larger one which that location will command in later
years, is strictly a community product, and as such
belongs to the community and not to Mr. Rhinelastor.
That the latter has no good right to it is at once
evident when we remember that "When one man gets
something for nothing somebody else has got to give
something for nothing." Here are $20,000 that some men
and women have got to work to earn every year to hand
over to a man who does not render, and does not feel any
obligation to render, one dollar's worth of public or
private service in return. Such is the wild travesty of
justice which we call law. It is not comical only because
it is frankly tragic in its social results.
Now suppose this $20,000 and all the rest of this same
community product — i.e., the site or location rent
of its ground — were paid every year to its
rightful owner, the treasurer of New York City, what
would become of taxation, with its inseparable retinue,
Fraud, Evasion, Perjury, Inequality, and an all-pervading
public sense of injustice?
An authority on municipal taxation estimates the
present economic rent of the land embraced in the City of
New York at from $350,000,000 to $400,000,000. Assuming
the lesser of these figures and adding the receipts from
licenses, fees and fines, New York City should receive,
of her own income, enough to pay all her own legitimate
bills, to make her proper contributions to county and
state and build a new subway or its equivalent every
year. ... read the whole
article
Mason Gaffney: George's Economics of
Abundance: Replacing dismal choices with practical
resolutions and synergies
... Equity and efficiency
George refutes the commonplace idea that we must choose
between equity and efficiency. This idea is premised on
identifying "equity" with price and rent controls
designed to help the poor against the rich; or with
counter-incentive progressive income taxation, with its
warping, suppressive effects. George rejects both price
controls and progressive income taxation, and identifies
a different tax policy that brings us both equity and
efficiency together. He would untax productive activity,
and instead base taxes on land, in proportion to its
value. This combines the magic of justice with the
magic of incentive.
George's land tax promotes equity toward the landless
in at least four ways.
- One, it relieves them of taxes, to the extent that
landowners pay more;
- Two, it makes jobs by removing all tax penalties
from hiring workers, and also because the land tax, a
fixed charge, spurs landowners to use land to earn cash
to pay the taxes;
- Three, while jobs are generating new money incomes,
new production supplies more goods and services. Those
give substance to the money incomes, precluding
inflation such as poisoned the springs of Keynesian
"fiscal stimulus";
- Four, it offers the landless new chances to acquire
land themselves, as old owners release surplus lands to
the market. ... read the
whole article
Nic Tideman:
Applications of
Land Value Taxation to Problems of Environmental
Protection, Congestion, Efficient Resource Use, Population,
and Economic Growth
Recognition of the equal rights of
all to natural opportunities, through land value taxation
and its extension to charges for the use of other
resources, is not only just and efficient, but has the
capacity to make a major contribution to economic growth.
This occurs through a variety of paths.
The most important path is that
public collection of the value of exclusive use of natural
opportunities provides revenue that makes it possible to
remove taxes from the earnings of labor and capital. When
people are taxed less, they earn more. Using data that
emerged from changes in U.S. tax rates, Feldstein has
estimated that the elasticity of earnings with respect to
the fraction of income not taken at the margin by federal
taxes is at least 1.0 (and more for workers in higher tax
brackets).6 When the entity that removes a tax
on labor is less than global, this action also attract
labor to the region.
When taxes are removed from capital,
the effect is even more powerful, as long as the entity
removing the tax is less than global. Capital is extremely
mobile in response to regional changes in net returns. It
is highly counterproductive for any locality or nation to
tax capital, because there will be virtually no effect on
the return to capital after taxes. Capital will merely be
driven from the taxed region until the return after taxes
matches what can be obtained elsewhere. If the whole world
removes taxes from capital, the resulting increase in the
rate of return to capital will increase the rate of saving,
but the adjustment will occur over some years.
Taxing land has an additional effect
that increases the stock of capital. A tax on land
represents a redistribution from living adults to the young
and unborn, who will now be born with rights to land.
Unless there is a perfectly offsetting reduction in the
desire to accumulate assets to transfer to the next
generation, this redistribution will induce the living, who
now have fewer assets, to accumulate at a more rapid rate
than they would otherwise do. That is, saving and capital
accumulation will increase.
Taxing land also increases the
efficiency with which land is used. This occurs through
three paths.
- First, a tax on land reduces the return to
land speculation, and therefore reduces the quantity of
land speculation.
- Second, as taxes on land are capitalized into
the selling price of land, the result is the substitution
of a recurring cost (the annual tax) for a one-time cost
(the purchase price). This makes land relatively more
attractive to bidders with high discount rates and
relatively less attractive to bidders with low discount
rates. To the extent that the former are more
entrepreneurial and the latter more passive investors,
land will tend to flow into the hands of persons who will
choose to use it more intensively.
- The third path by which a tax on land
increases the efficiency with which land is used is that,
for those who are using land inefficiently, it
substitutes an explicit cost (the tax) for an implicit
one (the income foregone by inefficient
use).
Psychologically, explicit costs tend
to be more effective in motivating efficient behavior than
implicit ones.
VIII. An Estimate of the Magnitudes of
the Consequences of Taxing Land
For all of the above reasons, the
substitution of tax on land for taxes on labor and capital
will increase the efficiency of an economy. To estimate the
magnitudes of these consequences, one needs a model of the
economy. Consider the following model. There is a
three-factor CES (constant elasticity of substitution)
production function:
Q = (aTà + bLà +
cKà)(1/à). (1)
where Q is output, T is the quantity
of land, L is the quantity of labor, K is the quantity of
capital, a, b and c are coefficients, and à is related
to the elasticity of substitution, å, by à = 1 -
1/å. Land has a completely fixed supply. Labor is
assumed to have an elasticity of supply of 0.8 (adjusting
Feldstein's number for the fact that he was considering
only federal income taxes. Capital is assumed to be
supplied perfectly elastically. Taking the ratio of
compensation of employees to Net Domestic Product in
National Income and Product Accounts, I assume that labor
receives two thirds of output. Somewhat arbitrarily, I
assume that the remaining third is divided equally between
land and capital. I estimate that the marginal tax rate on
labor is 43% (28% for the federal income tax, 12% for the
combination of state income taxes indirect taxes, and 3%
for the Medicare tax--I treat social security as having
benefits equal to its costs, and therefore not a tax.) I
estimate the marginal tax rate on land and capital at 50%
(28% for the federal income tax, 12% for the combination of
state income taxes and indirect taxes, plus 10% for profits
taxes). The elasticity of substitution is a parameter that
I am very unsure of. But Feldstein has estimated that the
marginal welfare cost of taxation is 1.65, and I get that
result with a å of 0.68, so I assume that å =
0.68.
I have a spreadsheet that
takes parameters such as the ones named and determines what
would happen (in a comparative static framework) if all
taxes were removed from labor and capital, and 100% of the
rent of land were taxed. Here are the results:
- The quantity of labor would
increase by 55%.
- The quantity of capital would
increase by 145%.
- Output would increase by
53%.
- The wage before taxes would fall
by 1.7%, but the wage after taxes would increase by
72%.
- The rent of land would increase by
87%, and would provide more than enough revenue for all
existing expenditures of all levels of government in the
U.S., other than social security.
-
The aggregate improvement in well-being of
citizens would be about 12.6% of output, or about $1
trillion per year. ... Read the entire
article
Mason Gaffney: Land
Rent in a Tax-free Society (Outline of remarks by
Mason Gaffney, for use at Moscow Congress,
5/21/96)
3. Rent will become
huger yet when you abate taxes presently levied on
production and exchange, because these now depress the rent
of land. That is, in a tax-free market economy, the
benefit of abating present taxes will lodge mainly in land
rents. The taxable surplus simply shifts from one form to
another.
This is more than a simple shift of a
fixed amount. When you substitute land revenues for
existing taxes, the surplus actually grows, as if by
synergy. You gain more revenue base than you lose, because
existing taxes now suppress much latent production. Payroll
taxes directly drive workers from taxable jobs to untaxed
gains from crime. Abating those taxes will unleash
suppressed economic giants, along with all the new surplus
values their latent production will generate. "Monetarists"
warn you that "there are no free lunches." In fact,
however, good policy creates lots of "free lunches." It
makes the whole greater than the sum of its parts. Imagine
the benefits, alone, of turning people from destructive
careers in crime to useful jobs producing
goods.
At the same time, the effect of
socializing land revenues is to stimulate better land use -
the opposite of the effect of existing taxes. Every
landowner, to pay the required land charge, is pushed to
steer his land to the best use (just as paying interest
steers capital to its best use). Thus, the shift to
rent-based revenues doubly induces new production: it
releases the brake of present taxes, and replaces it with
an added push to produce. This is "supply-side economic
policy" in the best and truest sense. It generates yet more
surplus. You may take all of rent to support government
functions, without damaging private market incentives, but
only sharpening them.
This policy lets us achieve and reconcile two
policies that many now believe are incompatible, viz.:
free markets, and common rights in land. It is a kind of
miracle, yet simple to understand and implement.
Monetarist advisers would bind you in a dilemma: they
claim you must choose between private markets and common
rights. In fact, you may have both at once. Public
revenue is simply the kind of socialization that occurs
in a market economy. Socialize the rent of land, and you
socialize the net benefits of owning land, even while
privatizing the management of land, and gaining the
benefits of using free markets.
The combined effect of all this
stimulus would be a burst of growth such as few economies
have ever shown, except in wartime. We learned in the
U.S.A. in World War II the astounding effects of simply
taking the brakes off production. U.S. GNP doubled,
1941-43; all willing workers were fully employed. This same
miracle can occur in Russia, 1996-98. The natural resources
and human talent are here: you only need the right
incentive structure to turn labor from idleness and crime
to producing goods and services.
4. Some of the benefit of abating
existing taxes will lodge in higher after-tax wage rates,
rather than higher rents. For the present and near
future, however, the supply of labor in Russia is highly
elastic because so many potential workers are now
unemployed, or underemployed, or occupied in crime. In
this condition, raising demand for labor will raise
payrolls by raising the number of good jobs, more than by
raising wage rates. On balance, therefore, this effect on
jobs will create new rents, more than it cuts into old
ones. After Russia shall have achieved full employment,
wage rates may rise and cut into the surplus of land
rents, but if this should then create a new kind of
problem (which I doubt), it is more pleasant, and easier
to solve, than those that afflict you now. Read the whole
article
Jeff Smith Share
Rent, Transform Society
If society decided to share among its members all
the annual value of society's sites and resources and air
space, what would happen?
If you were to choose the
Libertarian version, and rely on fees and dividends, you
get a geobonus, an added benefit. You would quit
distorting prices, you could pull government back in a
sense. Now taxes and subsidies at the margin can make
housing unaffordable to maintain, so the apartment owner
lets his apartment building become dilapidated and causes
nearby owners to do the same. He can breed a
slum.
We subsidize water and make water cheap for
farmers in Arizona to irrigate their land, and we then
have taxes to pay for environmental absurdities. Shift to
fees and dividends and have prices precise and use the
weight of the market to guide our choices toward
sustainability. If we had this price leveling, we could
get the market to work right. ...
It is not just collecting ground
rent but also untaxing other systems. Untax labor and
make it more affordable. Enterprises such as
recycling and reforestation, weatherization,
reconstruction, and health enterprises are labor
intensive and made more expensive artificially by taxing
labor. We subsidize business: free roads for the timber
industry, cheap water for agribusiness. Stop those
subsidies and recycling could compete.
On a level field, recycling would roll over
extraction of virgin material. We could spare forests and
salmon and have a healthier eco system. Look at
restoration. Money has to come from the public treasury
but we could look at it as public investment. Pay for
restoration and land values increase, so land dividends
would increase. Direct investment benefits the entire
public.
Now the public is paying for
private parties. That is not fair. Look at the
economy. Take taxes off homes, and they become more
affordable. Have some kind of land charge, and housing
stock increases as sites get developed. Affordable
housing helps stabilize neighborhoods. In places that do
have the land tax, i.e., Australia and New Zealand, they
have fewer disputes with assessment. Assessors say their
job is so much easier now. If land is less profitable and
less of a political football, it is less tense in local
politics.
- If you take taxes off labor
and capital, more investment flows into jobs, and we
would have close to full employment, so labor could
demand full market value for services.
We could double the income of the
average worker with no loss in standard of
living.
- If fewer demands are placed on government by
citizens, it doesn't have to borrow so much.
- If you reduce the amount of tax on the
economy, and reduce the amount of redeemable notes, then
we should be able to eliminate inflation. It is unmasked.
You can see lower prices; the cost of living goes down.
It will change social relationships.
- Labor and capital make up, with higher wages
for labor, lower taxes for capital, and more investment
funds.
- Labor can negotiate from a position of
strength.
- Capital might want to share management
decisions and spread that risk of liability to workers.
It tends to reduce hierarchy and increase equality in
society.
What other social relations might change? Increase
land ownership participation in community and it benefits
community, with town hall meetings and block
parties. ...
Read the whole
article
Jeff Smith: How Sharing Earth
Brought Peace
New Yorkers benefited before from geonomics. After
World War I, the city lacked housing. Borrowing a page
from former mayoral candidate Henry George, the council
exempted new buildings but not underlying sites from
taxation for the next ten years. During the first half of
the Roaring 20s, new construction more than tripled while
in other big cities it barely doubled. Economic good
times came to an end when owners in 1928 began to
anticipate the expiration of the exemption. Stalled
housing starts helped trigger the Great Depression.
More recently, Mayor Rudy Giuliani used to welcome
the school year by suspending for a week
the tax on shoes and clothes. Shoppers saved,
stores profited, and the city took in more revenue.
If the city zeroed out taxes on all
sales and wages, customers and workers would flock to the
Big Apple, pumping up site values even higher, providing
a fat fund for fixing up infrastructure. That'd
help owners redevelop both lower Manhattan and the blocks
of vacant lots and abandoned buildings in the Bronx and
Bedford-Stuyvesant.
Read the whole
article
see also Michael Hudson and Kris Feder: Real Estate and the
Capital Gains Debate which explores the extent to
which land gains are transformed for tax purposes into
"capital" gains, and are largely untaxed.
Dan Sullivan: Are you a
Real Libertarian, or a ROYAL Libertarian?
Much of the government spending to which
libertarians strenuously object is made necessary by its
taxing productivity instead of land values.
The property tax falls mostly on
improvements, so less housing is built, giving the
government an excuse to build public housing. Profits are
taxed, leading to less employment and giving government an
excuse to spend money on economic stimulus projects. Family
income is taxed to the point that they have difficulty
buying a house or sending their children to college, so
government institutes subsidized mortgages and student
loans.
Even the indirect effects are
substantial. Land speculations gone sour chew up inner
cities, so poor people turn to crime (if drug selling and
prostitution be crimes) and the government gets an excuse
to beef up the police state.
Politically connected real estate
interests see that they can buy up land in the boondocks
for a pittance and then get other taxpayers to build them a
superhighway, increasing the value of their holdings by
orders of magnitude. With land value tax they would have
ultimately paid for their own highway or more likely would
not have had it built in the first place.
Even welfare increases do not stay in
the hands of welfare recipients, but are quickly greeted by
higher rent demands from ghetto landlords. (The War on
Poverty did little to end poverty, but it did a lot to
enrich absentee owners of poor communities.)
All goes back to the land, and the land owner
is enabled to absorb to himself a share of almost every
public and every private benefit, however important or
however pitiful those benefits may be. --Winston
Churchill...
Read the whole piece
Ted Gwartney: A Free Market Strategy to
Reduce Sprawl
- Unused land is far more abundant than we
realize.
- End the Public Subsidy of Land Speculation and
Sprawl
- Counterproductive growth limitations and
regulations should be abolished.
- A Strategy for Urban Renewal
- A Strategy for Economic
Development
- Public Finance by Self-Financing
A Strategy for Economic
Development
Economic theory recognizes that when
government places taxes on production and on commerce the
net result is a reduction in those activities. The reason
this occurs is that these taxes add to the cost of
production and to the cost of doing business. The ideal
public policy would be to reduce taxes on production and
commerce and raise public revenue from non-distorting
revenue sources.
That non-distorting revenue source is
land and natural resources. The central problem which
limits the operational success of the economy is the
failure to procure the public value which is created by the
community.
This value ought to be reserved for
the community to pay for public improvements. However, this
value is to a large extent diverted into private pockets by
speculation in land and natural resource values. The
correct approach is to create a system in which no-one,
except the citizenry as a whole, is rewarded by the
collection of publicly created values.
Economists can agree that the
economically efficient public finance system is one in
which revenue is drawn from the rent that people pay for
the use of land and natural resources. These payments do
not distort economic activity. Land rent, because it is
pure surplus, could be taken and used for any purpose and
there would be no negative consequences for the allocation
of labor and capital, or in the use of land and natural
resources. If this surplus is invested in needed
infrastructure and other public services, it will in turn
increase land values for future public investment....
Read
the whole article
Frank Stilwell and Kirrily Jordan: The Political Economy of Land:
Putting Henry George in His Place
One might expect such arguments to have led to the
advocacy of land nationalisation. But George thought this
unnecessary because a tax on land could be effective in
capturing the economic surplus arising from land
ownership. This tax would generate all the revenue
necessary to fund public expenditures. George thought
that such a land tax would permit the removal of other
taxes on labour and capital, which he regarded as
inherently inefficient. He argued that taxes on incomes,
sales, and payrolls, for example, acted as disincentives
to production and active endeavour, thereby stifling
economic growth and creating a barrier to full
employment. A land tax, by contrast, would be both
economically efficient and more equitable in its
distributional effects.
George’s advocacy of replacing all existing
taxes with a single tax on land values was powerful. He
argued that this tax would redistribute the wealth that
would otherwise accrue to private landowners, forcing
them to repay the community for their exclusive use of a
public resource. Moreover, such redistribution would
reduce wealth inequalities and allow massive improvements
in welfare provisions and public services. In addition,
removing taxes on labour and capital would boost economic
growth and provide a stimulus to employment. Conversely,
taxing land values would reduce speculation in land and
depress land prices, allowing greater access to
landownership while reducing economic instability. ...
read the whole
article
Nic Tideman:
Land Taxation and Efficient Land Speculation
Indirect Effects of Taxing Land
One consequence of levying additional taxes on land is
that it becomes possible to lower taxes on other things.
One of the things most likely to be taxed less when land
is taxed more is improvements. Lowering taxes on
improvements makes the present value of land development
very much less costly, and hence is likely to accelerate
development although it would be possible to construct
cases in which the effect of lowering taxes on
improvements would be to postpone development. Whether it
retards or accelerates development, the lowering of taxes
on improvements results in more intensive development
when development occurs. The possibility of promoting
more intensive development by reducing or eliminating
taxes on improvements is an important beneficial effect
of an increase in taxes on land.
A second consequence of levying additional taxes on
land is that it becomes possible to price public services
more efficiently. Services to land such as sewers, water
and electricity are used most effectively when they are
priced at marginal cost. The costs of these services,
however, are generally such that the sum of marginal
costs will not cover total costs. Land taxes have the
potential to provide a fund to cover the difference
between total costs and the sum of marginal costs. If
land taxes are so used, the reductions in the costs of
using services that complement development will promote
more efficient development. ...
read the whole article
Judge Samuel Seabury: An Address delivered upon the
100th anniversary of the birth of Henry George
WE are met to celebrate the 100th anniversary of the
birth of Henry George. We meet, therefore, in a spirit of
joy and thanksgiving for the great life which he devoted
to the service of humanity. To very few of the children
of men is it given to act the part of a great teacher who
makes an outstanding contribution toward revealing the
basic principles to which human society must adhere if it
is to walk in the way which leads to freedom. This Henry
George did, and in so doing he expressed himself with a
clarity of thought and diction which has rarely been
surpassed. ... read
the whole speech
Fred E. Foldvary — The Ultimate Tax Reform: Public
Revenue from Land Rent
Reformers who want to impose a national retail sales
tax are well aware of the substantial impact taxes have
on human behavior. That, indeed, is often why such
reforms are proposed: The reformer wishes to discourage
borrowing, reduce consumption, or encourage savings, for
example. But moving to a national retail sales tax
results in little improvement.
Most people use their wage income to pay for goods and
services and sales taxes. Switching from an income to a
sales tax is like taxing you when you leave a room
instead of when you enter the room.
Income taxes punish savings, but sales taxes punish
borrowing. If you borrow $10,000 to buy a car and there
is a 20 percent sales tax, you need to borrow an extra
$2,000 to pay the tax. Some folks might decide to not buy
the car, spending the $10,000 on something else, without
borrowing $2,000.
There is no good economic reason to tax-punish
consumption or borrowing. The purpose of production is
consumption! If we punish consumption, we punish
production. Consumption is not an evil to be thwarted,
but the very benefit we get from the economy. We may as
well also tax fun and joy! Those seeking to tax
consumption act as though they have a Puritan streak that
considers enjoying goods to be evil and working and
saving to be good for their own sake. ...
Those suggesting positive consequences of shifting
taxation to rent have been accused of exaggerating its
beneficial effects.33 Freedom from punitive taxation is
not a panacea, but the infliction of arbitrary costs on
enterprise and the skewing of market signals such as
prices and profits is indeed a universal and major cause
of economic woes. It is not an exaggeration to propose
that removing these would have many beneficial results,
just as one’s health improves considerably if one
stops taking poison. ...
An ideal public revenue policy respects a
person’s right to privacy, does not discourage work
or savings, and does not induce dishonesty. While income,
sales, and value-added taxes fall woefully short of this
ideal, land value taxation meets each requirement.
Imagine the increased prosperity and opportunities for
advancement that would exist if people could keep all of
the money they earn; if billions of dollars wasted on
efforts to avoid high income taxes were suddenly turned
to productive endeavors; and if the growth of government
were constrained by a tax system that would raise only
enough to pay for services actually provided.
...
The shift from taxing productive human action to
collecting the economic rent generated by nature and
communities is more than a fiscal reform. There is a
philosophical and even spiritual side to this reform.
One of the ongoing problems of social philosophy is
the relationship of the individual to society. In
conventional tax policy, there is an inherent conflict
between the individual and government as the agent of
society. Individuals want to benefit from the collective
services provided by government, but the mechanisms for
financing those services typically have used force
against individuals and invaded their private lives. ...
read the whole
document
|
To share this page with a friend:
right click, choose "send," and add your
comments.
|
|
Red links have not been
visited; .
Green links are pages you've seen
|
Essential Documents pertinent
to this theme:
|
|