1
2
3
Wealth and Want | |||||||
... because democracy alone is not enough to produce widely shared prosperity. | |||||||
Home | Essential Documents | Themes | All Documents | Authors | Glossary | Links | Contact Us |
Classical vs Neo-Classical Economists
Mason Gaffney: Land as a Distinctive Factor of Production
The classical economists
treated land as distinct from capital: "land, labor and
capital" were the three basic "factors of
production." They were mutually exclusive.
They were comprehensive, including all economic agents.
Each was also "limitational," meaning at least some of
each was needed for all economic activity (v. A9,
below)1 They made
a coherent system, like Humboldt’s Cosmos, in the
spirit of The Enlightenment that spawned them
both.
Neo-classical economists denied the distinction and undertook to purge land from economese.
What ever possessed the neo-classicals to leave
such a mess? One needs to know something of their
times and politics. J.B. Clark and E.R.A. Seligman
of Columbia University were obsessed with deflecting
proposals, strongly supported at the time and place they
wrote, to focus taxation on land. Henry George,
after all, was nearly elected Mayor of New York City in
1886 and 1897. Frank Knight, founder of The Chicago
School, followed them closely. That explains why
some of the points made herein may seem obvious to
readers who have been spared the formal conditioning
imposed on graduate students in economics. In
graduate training, however, the obvious is obscured,
silenced, or denied. Hundreds of
books on economic theory are published with "land" absent
from the index.
Denial is reinforced by dominant figures using
sophistical, pedantic cant, which students learn to ape
to distinguish themselves from the laity and advance
their careers.2
Read the whole
article Bill Batt: How the Railroads Got Us On the Wrong Economic Track
Professor Gaffney has for the first time shown how
powerful economic interests in American society
essentially bought the leading figures of the
newly-established American Economics Association with all
the blandishments that can be used to influence
academicians. Leading scholars were induced to change
definitions of terms so that special interests would be
advantaged. What were those interests? Primarily the
railroad industry, which at the time was probably the
most powerful political force in America. By changing
definitions and conflating the land factor into capital,
it was no longer essential for land rent to be paid in
taxes, and the railroads, holders of some of the most
valuable land in the nation, were thereby able to escape
their full duty. This is an astonishing story, one never
fully spelled out until now, and it explains both how the
academic community was beholden to powerful interests and
how many of the social problems we see today could have
been avoided.
The classical tradition of economic thought was ably synthesized and represented by one dominant figure of the age: Henry George. All but forgotten today, perhaps in good part due to the assiduous disparagement of his economic foes, one should note that he was more widely known in his time in America than anyone except Thomas Edison. His 1879 book, Progress and Poverty, sold more copies throughout the world than any book till that time except the Bible. Born in Philadelphia the son of a publisher of religious books, he travelled to California as a young man to make his fortune as a journalist. But what he saw in land speculation and the exploitation of labor soon led him to study the classical economists and to write his ideas down. Upon publication of his book he shortly became known throughout the world, and travelled and lectured widely as a social reformer for the rest of his life. By the time he died he had become so famous that he almost won the mayoralty of the city of New York. He ran twice, losing to Tammany Hall the first time in what was probably a corrupt election (but beating the third-place finisher, Theodore Roosevelt) in 1886, and died four days before a second election he might have won in 1897. As a spellbinding orator and lucid writer, he captivated the world with his vision of societies made more just by a proper understanding of economics. Gaffney shows that it was George, not Marx, that was the primary threat to dominant interests in end-of-century United States. He had to be stopped, and he was. ... In classical economics, the definition of capital grew out of labor mixed with earlier capital. Land, by conventional definition, was not capital, nor was it a component of wealth. Rather land was its own category. Conflating land into capital allowed land rent to be hidden and diluted in ways so that the unearned increment arising from social improvements fell to speculators rather than being returned to society in rent.
The failure of society to recapture the
appropriate level of land rent from titleholders led also
to depression of labor wages at the margin, creating
poverty and artificial scarcity of labor where otherwise
it could be relieved. Hence the title of George's book,
Progress and Poverty. George
recognized that the value of any land parcel arose out of
its social activity, not from anything which a
titleholder might have done to it. He recognized that
many, perhaps most, titleholders in land were
speculators, reaping the benefit of others' investments,
and selling out at last when their price was met. Hence
it made sense that society had a right to a return on
what it had brought about, as well as from the fact that
those titles could never be other than leaseholds. That
land rent, shortly confused by use of the words "single
tax," was, to George, the rightful return to
society. ... read the
whole article
Kris Feder: Progress and Poverty Today
As this book was written, the Industrial
Revolution was transforming America and Europe at a
breathless pace. In just a century, an economy that
worked on wind, water, and muscular effort had become
supercharged by steam, coal, and electricity. Canals,
railroads, steamships and the telegraph were linking
regional economies into a national and global network of
exchange. The United States had stretched from coast to
coast; the western frontier was evaporating.
American journalist and editor Henry George marveled at the stunning advance of technology, yet was alarmed by ominous trends. Why had not this unprecedented increase in productivity banished want and starvation from civilized countries, and lifted the working classes from poverty to prosperity? Instead, George saw that the division of labor, the widening of markets, and rapid urbanization had increased the dependence of the working poor upon forces beyond their control. The working poor were always, of course, the most vulnerable in depressions, and last to recover from them. Unemployment and pauperism had appeared in America, and indeed, were more prevalent in the developed East than in the aspiring West. It was "as though a great wedge were being forced, not underneath society, but through society. Those who are above the point of separation are elevated, but those who are below are crushed down." This, the "great enigma of our times," was the problem George set out to solve in Progress and Poverty.
Economists will recognize his analysis as a
precursor to the modern marginal productivity theory of
functional distribution. His story is framed in the
language of what is today called classical political
economy, though George was careful to avoid
inconsistencies of definition and reasoning which, he
showed, had led other economists astray.
A central feature of the British classical school was the classification of productive resources into three "factors of production" - labor, land, and capital. Most classical economists had conceived of these in terms of three great social classes (the workers, the landed aristocracy, and the capitalists). George, on the other hand, identified them as functional categories, distinguished by the conditions under which the factors are made available for production. In a competitive economy, the earnings of the factors of production measure their separate contributions to the value of the product. Payments for the use of labor are called wages; payments for land are called rent; the income of capital is interest. In George's terms, the distress of the working classes had to do with a persistently low level of real wages. "Why," he asked, "in spite of increase in productive power, do wages tend to a minimum which will give but a bare living?" The book proceeds systematically. First, George explores the prevailing scholarly and popular explanations, which relied principally on the famous population theory of Malthus, in combination with the "wage fund" theory of British political economy. Together these theories implied that the aggregate income of labor depends upon the amount of capital devoted to the payment of wages. An increase in wages required an increase in the amount of capital per worker. However, any rise in living standards above mere subsistence motivated workers to marry younger and bear more children, until population growth caused capital per worker - and, therefore, wages - to recede again. Moreover, population growth diminished agricultural productivity by forcing recourse to inferior soils. Technological advance and capital accumulation might afford a period of relative prosperity - but ultimately, increasing applications of labor to a fixed amount of land could raise output only at a diminishing rate. In short, immutable laws of nature - the population principle and the law of diminishing returns to land - were widely believed to explain the persistence of poverty. To George, the Malthusian analysis was abhorrent: It asserted that no institutional reform could fundamentally alter the pattern of income distribution, and that charitable support for the needy only compounded the problem - by lowering death rates and raising birth rates. ... In his own analysis, George takes meticulous care to avoid inconsistencies of definition and reasoning. ...
Public debate about economic policy revolves
today, as it always has, around a tension between two
fundamental social goals. Economists and policymakers
lament a perennial "trade-off between efficiency and
equity." ...
Most economists deem it their business to evaluate the efficiency of policy choices, but, claiming no special knowledge of ethics, they leave it to philosophers and the political process to evaluate questions of justice. Can it be true that society's arrangements to provide for common needs must always confront a divisive choice between equity and efficiency - between what is fair and what is feasible? Henry George not only denied it; he asserted the reverse: Full recognition of economic rights and responsibilities would reveal the goals of equity and efficiency to be mutually reinforcing. Neither social justice nor a well-functioning free market system can long be enjoyed without the other. "The laws of the universe are harmonious," George proclaimed. His analysis showed that the root cause of widening inequality lies not in the laws of nature, but in social maladjustments which ignore them. Moreover, the breach of justice which underlies the problem of poverty is not merely incidental to economic development; it impedes development, leading to wider and wider inequality. George emphasized that unequal distribution is itself wasteful of wealth. Unemployment and underemployment of labor mean that energy and intelligence go untapped. ...
In short, an unjust system of privileges and
entitlements tends to cause misallocation of resources,
macroeconomic instability and stagnation, political
corruption, and social conflict that ultimately may
threaten whole civilizations. George's central
contribution was to show that the distinction between
individual property and common property forms a rational
basis for distinguishing the domain of public activity
from that of the private.
...
George's insights have wide application to modern problems. ... Modern fiscal and monetary policies have not resolved the problem of macroeconomic fluctuations. Yet a half century before Keynes, George outlined a theory of boom and bust which explained the underlying instability of the market economy under present fiscal institutions. ... Many American cities are plagued by the twin problems of urban decay and suburban sprawl. ... Thus, George's synthesis informs a research program of remarkable breadth. Some writers understand Georgism to constitute a distinct paradigm of political economy, one which reconciles the contradictions between the two competing paradigms dominant in the world today - the mainstream neoclassical school, which tends to focus on the impressive efficiency properties of free markets, and Marxist socialism. Other Georgist writers believe that Georgism can and should be explained in the modern language of neoclassical economics. What is certain is that geoclassical thought bears crucially on some of the foremost controversies in America and the world today. Read the whole article Fred E. Foldvary — The Ultimate Tax Reform: Public Revenue from Land Rent
|
|
to email this page to a friend: right click, choose
"send"
|
||||||
Wealth and Want
|
www.wealthandwant.com
|
|||||
... because democracy alone hasn't yet led to a society
in which all can prosper
|