Pigou
Bill Batt: The
Nexus of Transportation, Economic Rent, and Land
Use
Charging for pollution
externalities of motor vehicle travel invites more
complex issues. One approach widely explored
involves reliance upon what are known as Pigou taxes,
after noted British economist Arthur
Pigou.(31) It
attempts to recover the costs of externalities in the
natural environment and even involving health damages.
Yet Pigou taxes are more often talked about than actually
implemented. Related to such designs are those growing
out of the theories of Ronald Coase, designed not
necessarily to recover the full social costs of negative
externalities but rather to foster the most efficient
economic choice among options, even if some parties are
disadvantaged.(32)
Taxes recovering such costs are most easily collected at
the production stage -- at the wellhead or the refinery
for oil, and from the manufacturer for tires and other
materials.(33)
Still a third approach is that represented by the
Georgist tradition, which would recover the costs of
specified pollution externalities by accepting them to
the extent that the environment is capable of absorbing
them, and charging polluters for the use of the
environment as a sink for such wastes. This approach is
particularly attractive as a way to charge for the
release of noxious gases in motor vehicle
exhaust.(34)...
read the whole
article
Mason Gaffney: Economics in Support of
Environmentalism
Private property: from means to end
In a proper view of things, I submit, private property
is a means to an end. It is not an end in itself; it
needs a functional rationale. The end is to get land put
to the best use. All the private land in the world was
originally granted by some sovereign public person or
body, mainly for that purpose, not as a welfare
entitlement. Landowners and their lawyers have slyly,
over time, turned the means into an end, a fetish they
endow with "sanctity." This is a term they borrowed from
absolutist medieval theology. "Sanctity" means the
quality or state of being holy or sacred, hence
inviolable. It means property may not be challenged, or
even questioned. It has become an end in itself, its own
voucher. You're not even supposed to think about it, it
is above thought. Taboo!
Neoclassical economics, historically, marked the
final, total surrender of the profession to this fetish.
The modern economist's view runs something like this: "I
pledge allegiance to the 14th Amendment, and to the
overinterpretation of private landowner supremacy for
which it has come to stand." It is ironic to recall that
Radical Republicans passed that Amendment, at a time when
a "Radical Republican" was one who favored freeing the
slaves. The 14th Amendment was designed to protect the
rights of freedmen. As interpreted now, the 14th
Amendment means that The Emancipation Proclamation itself
was unconstitutional! Fortunately, no one has brought
that case - yet.
The Neo-classical economists' view of their proper
role is rather like that in The Realtor's Oath, which
includes a vow "To protect the individual right of real
estate ownership." The word "individual" is construed
broadly to include corporations, estates, trusts,
anonymous offshore funds, schools, government agencies,
institutions, partnerships, cooperatives, the Duke of
Westminster, the Sultan of Brunei, the Medellin Cartel,
Saddam Hussein, congregations, Archbishops, families
(including criminal families) and so on, but "individual"
sounds more all-American and subsumes them all. This is a
potent chant that stirs people to extremes of
self-righteousness and siege mentality when
challenged.
The resemblance between Neo-classical economics and
the Realtor's Oath is easier to understand when you learn
that Professor Richard T. Ely, founder of the modern
discipline of Land Economics, was heavily subsidized by
the National Association of Real Estate Boards, the
utilities, the major landowning railroads, and others of
like mind and property interests.
When it comes to violating property
rights, air pollution today is perhaps the greatest
invader and confiscator of property. Where do
economists stand? Once a few of them tried to say,
following A.C. Pigou, "let the polluter pay," and in
parts of Europe they still do. In our modern backward
thinking here at home, however, it's not the polluter who
is invading the property of others, nor the human rights
of those not owning property. Rather, when you tell them
to stop, the government is invading their rights. The
wage-earning taxpayers must pay them to stop, else you
are violating both the 14th Amendment and the "Coase
Theorem," a rationalization for polluting now dearly
beloved by Neo-classical economists. ... read the
whole article
Nic Tideman:
Improving Efficiency and Preventing Exploitation in Taxing
and Spending Decisions
Whenever a one-time redistribution is proposed, a
reaction of many economists is, "Yeah, right. Why would
anyone one believe that it would be only one time?" What
would make it reasonable to believe that such a
redistribution would be a one-time event is its
rationale: The recognition that some persons have had
unfairly inadequate starting positions in life, and the
determination to end that. If the purpose is achieved,
there is no rationale for further redistribution, unless,
at some future time, our society attains a new moral
insight that implies that further redistribution is
required.
With transfers replaced by private insurance and local
action, and defense pad for substantially by Pigouvian
taxes on capital, not much is left for federal taxes to
support. Perhaps some international relations, perhaps
some research (though in view of the possibility of a
conflict of interest on my part, one should not take my
word for it.) If I could have my way, the little that
would be needed in national spending would be paid for by
voluntary subscription by lower levels of government, as
the UN is financed. ...
read the whole article
Nic Tideman:
Revenue Sharing under Land Value Taxation
The ideas in this paper can be regarded as a variation
on the Pigouvian idea of equating marginal private cost
and marginal social cost. Independent localities with
free migration are inefficient because of the resulting
discrepancy between the marginal private cost and the
marginal social cost of migration. Taxation of a common
base is inefficient because of the discrepancy between
the social cost of local government spending and the cost
of such spending to localities that make spending
decisions. Taxation of the rental value of land by both
localities and states is inefficient because it causes
the local cost of a project to exceed its marginal social
cost. Taxation of the sale value of land by both
localities and states is inefficient because it causes
the cost to the locality of being inefficient to be less
than its social cost. The system that does not have
inefficiencies is one that avoids externalities in
migration decisions and makes the local contribution to
state coffers independent of actions that localities
take. ...
read the whole article
Peter Barnes:
Capitalism 3.0 — Chapter 3: The Limits of Government
(pages 33-48)
Let’s set aside for a moment the question of
whether government is inherently biased toward property
and focus instead on a purely mechanical question: is
taxation a good tool for preserving gifts of nature? I
pose this question because economists have advocated
“green taxes” for over eighty years, and
it’s time to move beyond this hoary panacea.
The idea of using taxes to protect nature dates back
to 1920, when Cambridge University’s top economist,
Arthur Pigou, proposed it. At first
blush the idea makes sense. If pollution is free,
there’ll be lots of it. If it’s taxed,
there’ll be less. Taxation forces polluters to
internalize some of the costs they’d otherwise
externalize.
So far, so good. The devil, however, is in the
details. For example, who sets the taxes? What algorithm
do they use? How quickly can they act? To whom are they
accountable? And where does the money go?
When the federal government sets taxes, the key
players are the House Ways and Means Committee and the
Senate Finance Committee. As any observer of Congress
will tell you, the process of writing tax laws is ugly,
contentious, and time-consuming. Bills are introduced,
hearings held, politics unleashed. More than anything
else, this is what keeps Washington’s lobbyists on
their cell phones.
What algorithm drives committee members when they
write tax laws? Most often, it’s what’s best
for their reelection. They’re not economists,
they’re politicians. They want to please donors and
voters. Protecting nature, or future generations,
isn’t foremost in their minds. Hence, pollution
taxes will never be as high as they need to be.
Consider a real example here — carbon taxes. A
tax on carbon emissions could, in theory, reduce global
warming. But in order to make a difference, the tax would
have to get extremely high. This means Congress would
have to raise the prices of gasoline, natural gas, and
electricity year after year, hitting every business and
consumer in the pocketbook. That’s an improbable
scenario.
In most situations, mainstream economists would shout,
“Politicians shouldn’t set prices, markets
should!” Prices should announce to the world, on
any given day, what buyers are willing to pay and sellers
are willing to accept. To the extent that government
distorts or delays this process, it leads to inefficient
allocation of scarce resources, not the least of which is
Congress’s own time.
So why did Pigou and his followers give the
price-setting job to politicians? Because, in their
minds, there was no alternative. Someone had to
set prices for pollution, and they thought no one else
could do it. But there are other options. ...
read the whole chapter
|
To share this page with a friend:
right click, choose "send," and add your
comments.
|
|
Red links have not been
visited; .
Green links are pages you've seen
|
Essential Documents pertinent
to this theme:
|
|