1
2
3
Wealth and Want | |||||||
... because democracy alone is not enough to produce widely shared prosperity. | |||||||
Home | Essential Documents | Themes | All Documents | Authors | Glossary | Links | Contact Us |
Automobile
Our country has a huge dependence on cars and therefore on oil. This leads to a range of ills. Special interests, in the form of the auto industry and the subsidies and privileges it has received over the years, have moved us away from public transportation to individual transportation. Now we face issues of environmental sustainability and increasingly expensive oil as we approach the point where we have competition for the world's finite oil resources. Yes, improvements in technology can make a big difference, but we also need to re-examine our incentives and our structures. Those who have visited Japan have seen an alternative: an excellent system of trains, from local to national, which allow one to get around easily in a country whose urban areas and coasts are far more densely populated than ours. Many of our fellow Americans spend a disproportionate amount of their time and money commuting, to get from land where they can afford to live to active and specialized job markets. In the process, they produce pollution and use expensive fuel. Can a 19th century social philosopher inform this debate? Yes!
This substantial leakage of economic base results
in multiple declines in state income. Cities love
to commission "economic base" studies, and a small
industry of moonlighting economists love to perform them,
usually to rationalize subsidizing some transnational
conglomerate to put in a branch plant. They use canned
"input-output" models to show how every dollar invested
generates $2-3 of induced investment locally. Yet no one
has seized on this obvious case to show that local
property taxes, substituted for absentee rent payments,
creates multiple increases in local income. The whole
intellectual apparatus is dominated by absentee investors
and used for their benefit. Many rents may be taxed in other ways. Georgists have long noted that parking meters are a way of collecting rent for use of public land, but they are pikers when it comes to estimating the value thereof. Donald Shoup, a UCLA professor, estimates the value of street parking, if properly priced, as enough to replace the entire property tax. Parking, however, is less than half the story. Vehicles also use public space when they are moving, often bumper-to-bumper in heavy traffic. Bridge, tunnel and ferry tolls reflect this obvious fact, and yet even most Georgists resist the obvious logical extension of the principle: taxes on vehicles and fuels are a kind of rough "land tax on wheels." The revenue potentials are breathtaking. Auto dealers, of course, spearhead the opposition. Observe how many acres each dealership preempts, and you will understand how they make so much money to brainwash the public into rejecting such taxes, along, of course, with conventional property taxes on their land. ... read the whole essay Bill Batt: How Our Towns Got That Way (1996 speech)
The Costs of Poor Taxes
Society pays a price for not adopting taxes which
follow the principles developed over the centuries. Here
I want only to show how the resulting distortions that
arose in the use of land ultimately caused the railroads
to fail in being able to serve society. While in the
short term the railroads certainly saved themselves from
having to pay taxes on their vast land holdings, the most
valuable of which were right around their own investment
in tracks and stations, they ultimately lost the
frequency of traffic which that tax structure would have
induced. This is because the population and improvement
densities needed to make public transit traffic
economically viable did not come about. Taking the long
view of society, George Kennen notes in one of his books
that:
The railway. . . was capable of accepting and disgorging its loads, whether of passengers or freight, only at fixed points. This being the case, it tended to gather together, and to concentrate around its urban terminus and railhead, all activity that was in any way related to movements of freight or passengers into or out of the city. It was in this quality that it had made major and in some ways decisive contributions to the development not only of the great railway metropolises of the Victorian age particularly of such inland cities as Moscow, Berlin, Paris, and Chicago but even certain of the great maritime turnover ports, such as London and New York. The automobile, on the other hand, had precisely the opposite qualities. Incapable, in view of its own cumbersomeness and requirements for space, of accepting or releasing large loads at any concentrated points anywhere, but peculiarly capable of accepting and releasing them at multitudes of unconcentrated points anywhere else, the automobile tended to disintegrate and to explode all that the railway had brought together. It was, in fact, the enemy of the concentrated city. Thus it was destined to destroy the great densely populated urban centers of the nineteenth century, with all the glories of economic and cultural life that had flowed from their very unity and compactness.
Failure to recapture publicly-created
land rents through the tax mechanism provided the
incentive to speculators to buy land, not to use it in
production but to hold it for the rise. In this way,
choice parcels remain undeveloped or underdeveloped
relative to the full extent that their values warrant and
development occurs instead in remote areas where
opportunity for profit is more immediate. The result was
low density development what we know as sprawl.
To some people this may be counter-intuitive. It may not be obvious that increasing taxes on a parcel of land will foster its improvement. Consider, however, the possibility that there are two parcels of land in roughly the same location and of equal size. You own a vacant parcel and another next to it has a twenty-story building. If only the land-value is taxed you will be paying the same tax revenue as your neighbor. What are you likely to do with your parcel? If you are rational, you will either build a twenty-story building or else sell the land to someone who will. In this way improvements tend to be clustered in high-land-value areas except where it is prohibited, perhaps for a park. ... Transportation planners know that public transit typically takes a density of at least 8-10 households per acre in order for it to be economically viable. Because tax policies have been instituted that have the effect of deliberately fostering low density suburban sprawl, society has become dependent upon motor vehicle transportation rather than transit service. Had taxes been imposed heavily or solely upon land value, just the opposite would have occurred: development would have been most intense on the high land-value parcels, right by the transit services, making our society less dependent upon motor vehicles.
We face a far greater problem on account of the
way in which America has allowed its landscape to be
configured than most people today realize. Over-reliance
upon the car causes inefficiencies in transportation
patterns and thereby disenfranchises the poor, the
disabled, the young and the old from their right to
mobility. One 1993 study concludes that "when the full
range of costs of transportation are tallied, passenger
ground transportation costs the American public a total
of $1.2 to $1.6 trillion each year. This is equal to
about one-quarter of the annual GNP and is greater than
our total national annual expenditure on either education
or health." Just the costs of motor vehicle accidents
nothing else represents a figure equal to 8 percent of
the American Gross Domestic Product. Conventional
American land use configurations and the automobile
dependent lifestyle that goes with it sap our resources
and what effort could be used for other ventures and
activities. Since so much of this activity is consumption
and not production, it weakens America's world economic
position and precludes reinvestment in more productive
areas. Because of the way in which we have encouraged
development, people who need jobs are frequently too poor
to own the cars necessary to get to them.... read the
whole article Bill Batt: The Compatibility of Georgist Economics and Ecological Economics
Such means reflect a lack of understanding
and imagination according to authors David Osborne and
Ted Gaebler, who urge adoption policies of
“steering rather than rowing.” 62 As long as drivers personally are
able to pass off to others the true costs of their
travel, it guarantees, along with the failure to collect
land rent, that sprawl development will continue. One
1993 study concluded that "when the full range of costs
of transportation are tallied, passenger ground
transportation costs the American public a total of $1.2
to $1.6 trillion each year. This is equal to about
one-quarter of the annual GNP and is greater than our
total national annual expenditure on either education or
health."63 Japan,
by way of comparison, spends an estimated 10.4% to
satisfy all its transportation requirements, although the
figure might be a bit low because not all externalities
are included in the calculation.64 One reason we are spending so
much on motor vehicle transportation is that our public
policies encourage it. Road user fees represented about
$33 billion in 1991 but the true costs to society were
ten times that;65
put another way, drivers pay only 10% of the true costs
of their motor vehicle use.66
...
Underlying the whole agenda is a commitment beyond simple description to sustainable development economics and to Daly’s “steady state” economics. This entails the institution of environmental safeguards, protection of cultural and biological diversity, minimal resource use, and recycling. It further means protection of small countries and localities — of both ecosystems and populations — against all-encompassing economic units that preclude the possibility of their being able to survive independently. It presumes also that not just humans alive today have entitlements, especially privileged elements of wealthy countries; it recognizes rather the justice and moral claims of people and natural ecosystems yet to live to survive as intact and integral units. It recognizes that governments must take a hand in the preservation of such ecosystems, as markets forces left to themselves will wreak destruction on the most vulnerable parts of the earth and ultimately upon the earth itself. It accepts the fact that the carrying capacity of the earth is limited, and that we appear to have already exceeded that carrying capacity in our ignorance.119
119One oft-cited article
is that of Peter Vitousek, et al, “Human
Appropriation of the Products of Photosynthesis,”
BioScience, Vol. 36, No.6 (1986), pp. 368-373, available
at http://dieoff.org/page83.htm. It calculates that
consumption of earth’s resources is doubles at an
ever increasing rate, and that humans have already
appropriated 40% of terrestrial biological productivity.
The most comprehensive collection of articles addressing
this perspective is created and maintained by retired
Cornell Professor Jay Hanson, at www.dieoff.org. The site
name arises from his view that the world economy’s
dependence upon fossil fuels faces an imminent end, and
the earth will then be capable of supporting only about
two billion people. Hence a looming
dieoff.
The distinction between CAC approaches to environmental challenges as compared with pricing approaches is central to all this analysis. Daly’s shows a strong preference for the latter. In what he calls “graded ecozoning,” for example, potential atmospheric impacts are divided into three areas.
Green taxes, sometimes also called corrective
taxes or Pigouvian taxes, are their first candidates for
consideration. This is because they can, if priced right,
recover the costs of externalities in ways that allow
individuals to use their own discretion about employing
environmentally damaging practices. But the authors
extend their thinking to cover goods and materials that
may have negative ecological impacts although not yet
conclusively demonstrated by science. The answer there is
to rely upon a “precautionary polluter pays
principle” based on the present value of the
forecast impact should the worst case scenarios be borne
out. The annual cost of using a car in
the early 1990s, for example, was $51,656 according to
their calculations.120 This would obviously entail an
enormous imposition of taxes, far above the less than
$7,000 direct annual costs typically shouldered by
drivers now,121
the rest of which are now passed on to society generally.
Grave doubt exists about the potential impact of various
externalities of driving, along with concern about the
extent of damage which might possibly occur to the
ecosystem; this warrants employment of the precautionary
principle and calls for policy solutions to curtail this
travel mode. Complete prohibition of certain materials
and chemicals may be warranted in some cases.... read the whole
article
Bill Batt: Stemming Sprawl: The Fiscal Approach
Some explanations reflect downright
corruption. The earliest cars manufactured in this
country and in Europe were electric; streetcars also were
largely electric powered until a conspiracy of the
automobile and petroleum industry exerted its force to
ensure that fossil fuel powered motor vehicles would
dominate our transportation and land use
patterns.15 Our
motor-vehicle-dependent and urban sprawl configurations
can be explained by powerful interests continually
pressing for policies to make us so. One might even
conclude that the decision to drive on the right side of
the road was equally as much a defining moment.
15 This is an untold story. A trial
was held in a Chicago federal court in 1949, resulting in
an indictment of GM, Firestone, Standard Oil, Phillips
Petroleum, and Mack Trucks among others. Their crime was
in forming a holding company called National City Lines
which proceeded in the preceding decade to buy up the
public transportation services in dozens of US cities,
and then scrapping them so that people would then become
more automobile dependent. The corporations were fined
$5,000 each, and the CEOs of each one $1. See United
States Senate, Committee on the Judiciary, 93rd Congress,
2nd Session, “American Ground Transport: A Proposal
for Restructuring the Automobile, Truck, Bus, and Rail
Industries,” by Bradford C. Snell, February 26,
1974 (Washington: US Government Printing Office, 1974);
and Jonathan Kwitney, “The Great Transportation
Conspiracy,” Harper’s Magazine, February,
1981.
And I hope that you will forgive me for mentioning another great conspiracy in American history, the subject of my Torch presentation about four years ago. That story recounted how the American railroad industry, in collusion with the banks, induced the founders of the American economics profession to change definitions and formulas so that they would be relieved of taxation on their land holdings and speculation would be rewarded.16 This dividing line between classical and neoclassical economics is responsible I believe for many of our economic problems today — economic cycles, an inequitable tax structure, poverty and unemployment, urban sprawl and the gutting of urban centers. Only now is this economic ideology, almost sacrosanct for a century, falling apart and seen for what it is. ... read the whole article Bill Batt: How the Railroads Got Us On the Wrong Economic Track
The Costs of Poor Taxes
Society pays a price for not adopting taxes which follow the principles developed over the centuries. Here I want only to show how the resulting distortions that arose in the use of land ultimately caused the railroads to fail in being able to serve society. While in the short term the railroads certainly saved themselves from having to pay taxes on their vast land holdings the most valuable of which were right around their own investment in tracks and stations they ultimately lost the frequency of traffic which that tax structure would have induced. This is because the population and improvement densities needed to make public transit traffic economically viable did not come about. Taking the long view of society, George Kennen notes in one of his books that: The railway. . . was capable of accepting and disgorging its loads, whether of passengers or freight, only at fixed points. This being the case, it tended to gather together, and to concentrate around its urban terminus and railhead, all activity that was in any way related to movements of freight or passengers into or out of the city. It was in this quality that it had made major and in some ways decisive contributions to the development not only of the great railway metropolises of the Victorian age particularly of such inland cities as Moscow, Berlin, Paris, and Chicago but even certain of the great maritime turnover ports, such as London and New York. The automobile, on the other hand, had precisely the opposite qualities. Incapable, in view of its own cumbersomeness and requirements for space, of accepting or releasing large loads at any concentrated points anywhere, but peculiarly capable of accepting and releasing them at multitudes of unconcentrated points anywhere else, the automobile tended to disintegrate and to explode all that the railway had brought together. It was, in fact, the enemy of the concentrated city. Thus it was destined to destroy the great densely populated urban centers of the nineteenth century, with all the glories of economic and cultural life that had flowed from their very unity and compactness. Failure to recapture publicly-created land rents through the tax mechanism provided the incentive to speculators to buy land, not to use it in production but to hold it for the rise. In this way, choice parcels remain undeveloped or underdeveloped relative to the full extent that their values warrant and development occurs instead in remote areas where opportunity for profit is more immediate. The result was low density development what we know as sprawl. To some people this may be
counter-intuitive. It may not be obvious that increasing
taxes on a parcel of land will foster its improvement.
Consider, however, the possibility that there are two
parcels of land in roughly the same location and of equal
size. You own a vacant parcel and another next to it has a
twenty-story building. If only the land-value is taxed you
will be paying the same tax revenue as your neighbor. What
are you likely to do with your parcel? If you are rational,
you will either build a twenty-story building or else sell
the land to someone who will. In this way improvements tend
to be clustered in high-land-value areas except where it is
prohibited, perhaps for a park. ... read the
whole article Mason Gaffney: Red-Light Taxes and Green-Light Taxes Likewise, there are at least two kinds of containment policies for urban sprawl.
Consider Philadelphia, once the City of Brotherly Love founded by an idealistic English Quaker. Today, after 3 centuries of development, Philadelphia has 15,800 vacant lots, but that only begins the story. It has 27,000 empty houses (i.e. junkers on usable lots that might as well be vacant); 1500 acres of vacant land and brownfields; and 700 vacant commercial bldgs. A local journalist names it BlightTown, U.S.A. If he travelled a bit he'd find it is only one of many. The result of decay without renewal is to threaten the countryside; settlers spill out, "like ghosts from an enchanter fleeing." Yet, these are not ghosts, nor autumn leaves in the west wind; these are live people. Destroy man's habitat here and he moves it there, and takes habitat from other life forms. The solutions to urban decay and disintegration are infilling and renewal. Here is where the Green Light Tax is such a good management tool. It lets cities rebuild themselves without tax penalties on new building, and rise like the phoenix from their own ashes. There is a reflex against growth and development we must learn to overcome. "Growth" should not be an issue to divide us: it depends on the kind of growth. Resentment of growth and development stems in large part from associating them with territorial expansion. Infilling and renewal and rehab, however, UNCOUPLE growth from sprawl: they let cities grow (or at least stop shrinking) without sprawling. Ascending to a satellite view, let's look at the whole system of settlement: focusing people where they should be keeps them away from where they shouldn't be. Here is an aerial view of Albuquerque, New Mexico, a state dominated by owners of million-acre ranches, and therefore with about the lowest property tax rate in the U.S. Albuquerque sprawls out about 30 miles east-west, and another 30 miles north-south, giving a density of about 300-400 people per square mile for its 330,000 residents. Many of its homes are slums. Contrast that with the aerial view of Sydney, Australia, a city that raises a lot of its budget from "Green Light" taxes on site value. Sydney and suburbs have nearly 3 million people, on less land than Albuquerque, and with no slums. There is plenty of land to go around. The pleasant green villages of Shorewood and Whitefish Bay, Wisconsin are upper-income Milwaukee suburbs that feature detached homes on tree-lined streets, with detached garages, laws against overnight curb parking, a number of lakeshore mansions with parklike grounds, ample public parks, good shopping, and a little industry. Their densities are 10,000 persons per square mile. At this density, 250 million Americans would fit nicely into less than half of Wisconsin, an average-sized one of 50 states. (They would occupy 0.7% of the United States.) At the 10,000 density, Greater
Milwaukee would fit inside Milwaukee County, yet it now
sprawls out over several counties. It sprawls farther yet
if one counts the rural residents who float in and out of
town for seasonal work. Shorewood and Whitefish Bay have
high density because they are the only Milwaukee suburbs
with no vacant land; the others, and the central city
itself, are full of holes. Result: sprawl, invasion of
wildlands, loss of farmland, forced automobilization of
former pedestrians, water pollution from new grading - the
whole litany of green laments. High density is not their
cause, but their cure. ... read
the whole article Bill Batt - The Nexus of Transportation, Economic Rent and Land Use
Like the rest of the universe, US cities keep
expanding. Some time before the universe begins to
contract, American metro regions may, too. What
counterpart to gravity might suck suburbia back into the
hole of our doughnut cities? One of the most fundamental
forces in the world - money. Jeff Smith: Sharing
Natural Rents to Sustain Human SocietyIt was the lure of cold cash that drove urbanites out of downtown. The usual suspect, the car, was merely a convenient ride. Despite our present dependency on cars, the drive to profit is powerful enough to bring people back. Local governments have begun to modify the profit motive. Rather than meekly pick up the ever-rising tab for expanding the infrastructure, some localities now charge developers a portion of this cost. While this move may stymie development at the edge, what’s needed is something to draw development into the urban core. ... ... This property tax shift (PTS) "helps cities recover from auto-dependency," notes Gihring, author of The Journal of the American Planning Association’s first article on revenue reform (1999 Winter). The PTS turns lots for cars into structures for people. By densifying a city, it provides more riders for mass transit, justifying more routes and times. As riding becomes convenient while remaining a bargain, and parking grows inconvenient while rising in cost, more people switch from driving to riding. Less traffic lets cities transform streets for bikes, pedestrians, sidewalk cafes, and street performers. Architecture, too, could blossom. As car use wanes, so might those keep-out-snout houses. Frank Lloyd Wright, who’d design around a tree rather than ax it, advocated de-taxing structures while re-taxing sites. This idea peaked about a century ago with the popularity of American reformer Henry George. Today, some Australian towns still do tax land alone; they have 50% more built value per acre than those that don’t (Kenneth Lusht, Pennsylvania State University). ... Read the whole article To get rich, or more likely to stay rich, some of us can develop land, especially sprawling shopping centers, and extract resources, especially oil. While sprawl and oil depletion are not necessary, they are more profitable than a car-free functionally integrated city. Under the current rules of doing business, waste returns more than efficiency. We let a few privatize rent -- ground rent and resource rent -- although rent is a social surplus. As if rent were not profit enough, winners of rent have also won further state favors -- tax breaks, liability limits, subsidies, and a host of others designed to impel growth (20 major ones follow herein). If we are to sustain our selves, our civilization, and our eco-system, we must make some hard choices about property. What we decide to do with rent, whether we let it reward our exploiting or our attaining eco-librium, matters. Imagine society waking up to the public nature of rent. Then it would collect and share its surplus that manifests as the market value of sites, resources, the spectrum, and government-granted privileges. Then we could forego taxing labor and capital. On such a level playing field, this freed market would favor efficiency - the compact city - not waste - the mall and automobile. ...
Drawing their cue from the public, governments
tolerate "rentention", the private retention of
publicly-generated land values. Lacking this Rent, states
turn to taxes. But to grow the economy, all governments
-- left, right, or undecided -- hustle to stimulate
development; they cut taxes and slop subsidies. Going
beyond the call of duty, the state excuses producers'
their routine pollution and limit liability, thereby
cutting the cost of insurance. Companies that don't
impose on nature, worker, or customer are not benefited
at all but lose a competitive advantage. On this tilted
playing field, one with the lumps of subsidies and the
tilts of taxes, technologies lean and clean have a hard
time competing as suppliers of materials, homes, food,
rides, and energy. ...
Transportation - Cars vs. a Mix of Modes
To sustain that which we love, we must transform
our relationships to nature, to government, and to each
other. We need to become geonomists in worldview, theory,
discipline, and policy. Geonomics creates an economy
that's not at war with but aligned with the natural
world. ...
Read the whole
article |
|
to email this page to a friend: right click, choose
"send"
|
||||||
Wealth and Want
|
www.wealthandwant.com
|
|||||
... because democracy alone hasn't yet led to a society
in which all can prosper
|