Classical Liberals
Dan Sullivan: Are
you a Real Libertarian, or a ROYAL Libertarian?
According to royal libertarians, land becomes
private property when one mixes one's labor with it. And
mixing what is yours with what is not yours in order to
own the whole thing is considered great sport. But the
notion is filled with problems. How much labor does it
take to claim land, and how much land can one claim for
that labor? And for how long can one make that
claim?
According to classical liberals, land
belonged to the user for as long as the land was being
used, and no longer. But according to royal libertarians,
land belongs to the first user, forever. So, do the oceans
belong to the heirs of the first person to take a fish out
or put a boat in? Does someone who plows the same field
each year own only one field, while someone who plows a
different field each year owns dozens of fields? Should the
builder of the first transcontinental railroad own the
continent? Shouldn't we at least have to pay a toll to
cross the tracks? Are there no common rights to the earth
at all? To royal libertarians there are not, but classical
liberals recognized that unlimited ownership of land never
flowed from use, but from the state:
A right of property in movable things is
admitted before the establishment of government. A
separate property in lands not till after that
establishment.... He who plants a field keeps possession
of it till he has gathered the produce, after which one
has as good a right as another to occupy it. Government
must be established and laws provided, before lands can
be separately appropriated and their owner protected in
his possession. Till then the property is in the body of
the nation. --Thomas Jefferson ...
Classical liberals recognized that
exclusive access to land, and especially to more land than
one was using, was a privilege that should be paid for,
thereby eliminating the need for taxes. It is not a fee for
using land, but a fee for the state privilege of denying
use of that land to everyone else.
Men did not make the earth.... It is the value
of the improvement only, and not the earth itself, that
is individual property.... Every proprietor owes to the
community a ground rent for the land which he holds.
--Tom Paine, "Agrarian
Justice," paragraphs 11 to 15
Another means of silently lessening the
inequality of [landed] property is to exempt all from
taxation below a certain point, and to tax the higher
portions or property in geometrical progression as they
rise. --Thomas Jefferson
Today's land value tax advocates
consider graduated land value tax to be unnecessary and
problematic, leading to artificial subdivision (and phony
subdivision) of land. The point is that Jefferson, to whom
libertarians pay homage, considered land monopoly a great
evil and land value tax a remedy, as did many other
classical liberals:
Ground rents are a species of revenue
which the owner, in many cases, enjoys without any care
or attention of his own. Ground rents are, therefore,
perhaps a species of revenue which can best bear to
have a peculiar tax imposed upon them. --Adam
Smith
Landlords grow richer in their sleep,
without working, risking, or economizing. The increase
in the value of land, arising as it does from the
efforts of an entire community, should belong to the
community and not to the individual who might hold
title. --John Stuart Mill ...
Socialist Confusions
The classical liberal distinctions between land,
labor and capital were greatly confused by socialists,
and particularly Marxists, who substituted the fuzzy
abstract term, "means of production," for all three
factors. They also blurred the distinction between common
property and state property, for socialists believed, as
royalty also believed, that they were the people.
Today, the confusions between land and
capital and between state property and common property are
shared by socialists and royal libertarians, and only
classical liberals keep these distinctions clearly defined.
Yet royal libertarians frequently duck the land issue by
charging that it is the classical liberals, not the royal
libertarians, who have embraced socialist ideas....
Read
the whole piece
winstonchurchill.org: THE
PEOPLE'S RIGHTS: OPPORTUNITY LOST?
(reviews)
Publisher's pamphlet, circa 1970:
The republication of any
Churchill work after sixty years is an event commanding
widespread public interest. Such attention is owed the
rich desert of The People's
Rights, last published at the culmination of the
election campaign of 1909/10, when the speeches from
which Churchill compiled the book were
delivered.
Many a reader will find himself
astonished that so vivid a portrayal of one of the great
men of our time should have lain so long out of print.
Yet modern readers will miss much of the value of the
book if it is read only for the brilliant and sometimes
surprising insight into this vital stage of Churchill's
political development.
For the principles and aspirations
set out here are not those of the individual, but the
life force of the great movement that reached its zenith
in the Liberal Governments of Sir Henry Campbell
Bannerman and Herbert Asquith that followed the landslide
Liberal victory of 1906. If one dares to
summarise the purpose and vision of Liberal leaders of
that time, it was to bring in a society in which the
poverty and social injustice of the previous century
would be eradicated without diminishing the liberty and
independence of the individual. The incentive would
remain to develop his abilities to the full for the good
of himself and of the community.
...
Apart from Free Trade, the great
economic and social issues were taxation and the
alleviation of poverty. The Liberals were concerned to
remove the basic cause of the problem -- not just to
mitigate its undesirable effects.
It was the American economist
Henry George who, towards the end
of the 19th century, had examined the paradox of the age
in his Progress and Poverty. His principles had
a major impact, first upon the radicals of Scotland and
Ireland, including Campbell Bannerman himself; and later
upon the policy of the Liberal Party.
Henry George
propounded that whilst people have the right to possess
what they produce, or receive in exchange for their work,
there is no such right to private ownership of the
elements upon which all depend -- air, water, sunshine
and land. Indeed, George held the right of access to
these basic elements as strong and equal as the right to
life itself, and that if private ownership of basic
elements is permitted, suppression and exploitation of
one class by another is inevitable. The
consequent injustice must become more acute as the
community develops.
Thus it became a major point of
Liberal policy to shift taxation from production, and to
raise taxation upon the value of land, on the basis that
this value, as witnessed by the
tremendously high prices even then demanded for
commercial land, is created not by any individual but by
the existence and work of the whole community. A
natural source thus arises from which the community may
meet its growing needs without discouraging production or
inhibiting the growth of earnings.
The justice and
practicality of this proposition can rarely if ever have
enjoyed a more brilliant advocate than Winston Churchill,
and today's reader is left to wonder how different might
be the present state of Britain had the forces of social
change pursued these principles to their
enactment. As it was, the great power and
intellectual prowess of the Liberal Movement, which had
commanded worldwide admiration for the breadth and
nobility of its vision, was soon to be dissipated by war,
internal feuding and the fear of
Bolshevism.
Under the cruel heel
of war and unemployment, Britons came to value security
more and independence less. The emphasis in social
advance shifted to the massive provision of public
benefits, and the increasing intervention of the State in
almost every area of human activity. The two World
Wars and the great depression between them severed, to a
great extent, the line of liberal thought that had
developed over the previous century.
Of Churchill himself, one can only
feel that he was fated to be the great war leader.
Certainly, opposition to communism and later to the rise
of European tyrannies dominated the remainder of his
political life. It is perhaps ironic that a reason so
often given for his dismissal in 1945 is that he was not
capable of dealing with social problems, and thus was
unfit to be a peacetime leader.
The People's Rights tells
a very different story and comes now not as a document of
historic interest but as a challenge to politicians,
indeed to the entire electorate, to consider again the
causes of poverty and the basic issues of social and
economic justice. Perhaps current disillusionment
with politics springs from a sense that if justice in the
community can only be achieved at the expense of
individual liberty, the price -- especially in terms of
ever-increasing taxation and bureaucracy -- is too high
to pay.
As a proposition that justice in the
community and the freedom of the individual are
complementary and that taxes may be raised without
undermining either, The People's Rights comes as a major
contribution to current political and economic thought.
Indeed it deserves a place in the annals of Man's
struggle for freedom and yearning for a society in which
the genius of every person would be nurtured and the
liberty of every person respected.
John Nixon's
Review of The People's
Rights
Churchill as
Classical Liberal
Churchill's pre-World War I
books tend to be overlooked by casual students of The
Great Man. which is unfortunate as they are well
written and present a great variety for the reader:
four war histories, a novel, a biography, a travelogue,
three speech compilations, and a political campaign
statement, The People's Rights.
... Read the whole piece
|
To share this page with a friend:
right click, choose "send," and add your
comments.
|
|
Red links have not been
visited; .
Green links are pages you've seen
|
Essential Documents pertinent
to this theme:
|
|