What Percentage of Economic Rent
Should We Collect?
Should we collect 100% of Rent? 95%? 90%? This
question is sometimes raised among Georgists. There is no
agreement, but most Georgists would also say that society
would be in a far better position if this was the
question we were considering — that is, if a
consensus had been reached that we should indeed collect
Rent as the underlying basis for the revenue we need to
provide government services, and had begun doing so. And
most of us would not quibble about the difference between
collecting 90% and collecting 95%. Most of us would
advocating something less than 100%, but likely more than
90%.
Harry Pollard, of the Henry George School of Social
Science in Los Angeles, has often said that it would be
better for us to collect economic rent and throw it into
the sea, than not to collect it at all. By this, I think
he means that it is even more important that it not be
left in private hands because of the mal effects of that,
than that we collect it and use the revenue to reduce or
replace some of the dumb, market-dulling taxes we
currently use.
Every dollar of economic rent we collect means a
revenue dollar we don't need to collect from wages, or
sales, or buildings. Both aspects move us toward a more
just society and a more efficient economy
Currently, we tend to collect less than 1/5 of
economic rent. (At the same time, we collect property tax
on the assessed value of buildings and other improvements
to property. In California, with Proposition 13, some
properties which haven't changed hands in more than 10
years see only a small fraction of the economic rent
collected.) This is the most important explanation for
California's high housing prices, low housing
affordability, high barriers to entry for new
businesses.
Louis Post: Outlines of Louis F. Post's
Lectures, with Illustrative Notes and Charts (1894)
f. The Single Tax Retains Rent for Common
Use.
To retain Rent for common use it is not necessary to
abolish land-titles, nor to let land out to the highest
bidder, nor to invent some new mechanism of taxation, nor
in any other way to directly change existing modes of
holding land for use, or existing machinery for
collecting public revenues. "Great changes can be best
brought about under old forms."109 Let land be held
nominally as it is now. Let taxes be collected by the
same kind of machinery as now. But abolish all taxes
except those that fall upon actual and potential Rent,
that is to say, upon land values.
109. "Such dupes are men to custom, and
so prone
To rev'rence what is ancient and can plead
A course of long observance for its use,
That even servitude, the worst of ills,
Because delivered down from sire to son
Is kept and guarded as a sacred thing."
—Cowper.
It is only custom that makes the
ownership of land seem reasonable. I have frequently
had occasion to tell of the necessity under which the
city of Cleveland, Ohio, found itself, of paying a
land-owner several thousand dollars for the right to
swing a bridge-draw over his land. When I described the
matter in that way, the story attracted no attention;
it seemed perfectly reasonable to the ordinary lecture
audience. But when I described the transaction as a
payment by the city to a land-owner of thousands of
dollars for the privilege of swinging the draw "through
that man's air," the audience invariably manifested its
appreciation of the absurdity of such an ownership. The
idea of owning air was ridiculous; the idea of owning
land was not. Yet who can explain the difference,
except as a matter of custom?
To the same effect was the question of
the Rev. F. L. Higgins to a friend. While stationed at
Galveston, Tex., Mr. Higgins fell into a discussion
with his friend as to the right of government to make
land private property. The friend argued that no matter
what the abstract right might be, the government had
made private property of land, and people had bought
and sold upon the strength of the government title, and
therefore land titles were morally absolute.
"Suppose," said Mr. Higgins, "that the
government should vest in a corporation title to the
Gulf of Mexico, so that no one could fish there, or
sail there, or do anything in or upon the waters of the
Gulf without permission from the corporation. Would
that be right?"
"No," answered the friend.
"Well, suppose the corporation should
then parcel out the Gulf to different parties until
some of the people came to own the whole Gulf to the
exclusion of everybody else, born and unborn. Could any
such title be acquired by these purchasers, or their
descendants or assignees, as that the rest of the
people if they got the power would not have a moral
right to abrogate it?"
"Certainly not," said the friend.
"Could private titles to the Gulf
possibly become absolute in morals?"
"No."
"Then tell me," asked Mr. Higgins, "what
difference it would make if all the water were taken
off the Gulf and only the bare land left."
If that were done it is doubtful if land-owners could
any longer confiscate enough Rent to be worth the
trouble. Even though some surplus were still kept by
them, it would be so much more easy to secure Wealth by
working for it than by confiscating Rent to private use,
to say nothing of its being so much more respectable,
that speculation in land values would practically be
abandoned. At any rate, the question of a surplus —
Rent in excess of the requirements of the community
— may be readily determined when the principle that
Rent justly belongs to the community and Wages to the
individual shall have been recognized by society in the
adoption of the Single Tax. 110
110. Thomas G. Shearman, Esq., of New
York, author of the famous magazine article on "Who
Owns the United States," estimates that sixty-five per
cent of the present annual value of the land in the
United States would pay all the present expenses of
American government — federal, state, county, and
municipal. ...
Q2. Would the single tax yield revenue sufficient
for all kinds of government?
A. Thomas G. Shearman, Esq., of New York, estimates that
sixty-five per cent of the rent that the land in the
United States now yields actually and potentially to its
owners, would be sufficient. But whether it would or not
is as yet an unimportant question. If all revenues ought
to be raised from land values, then no revenues should be
drawn from other sources while any land value remains in
private possession. Until land values are exhausted the
taxation of labor cannot be excused.
Q5. If the full rental value were taken would it
not produce too much revenue and encourage official
extravagance? If only what was needed for an economical
administration of government, would not land still have a
speculative value?
A. In the first part of your question you are thinking of
a vast centralized government as administering public
revenues. With the revenues raised locally, each locality
being assessed for its contribution to the state and the
nation, there would be no such danger. The possibility of
this danger would be still further reduced by the fact
that private business would then offer greater pecuniary
prizes than would public office, wherefore public office
would be sought for purer purposes than as money-making
opportunities. As to the second part of your question,
the speculative value of land would be wiped out as soon
as the tax on land values was high enough and that on
improvement values low enough to make production more
profitable than speculation. And this point would be
reached long before the whole rental value was absorbed
in taxation.
Q16. Should the whole rental value of land be
taken for common use, or only enough for government
purposes?
A. Only enough for government purposes. When the people
see that this method of taxation improves business,
increases wages, cheapens land, and generally promotes
prosperity, they will not hesitate to increase their
taxes so long as public improvements are needed and land
values are unexhausted. As is said in "Progress and
Poverty" (book viii, ch. ii): "When the common right to
land is so far appreciated that all taxes are abolished
save those which fall upon rent, there is no danger of
much more than is necessary to induce them to collect the
public revenues being left to individual
landholders."
Q33. Would not the full single tax destroy the
basis of all credit — land values?
A. The full single tax — one hundred per cent of
annual ground rent — would wipe out land values,
which are but the capitalization of rent. But land values
are not the basis of credit. Merchants do not prefer
mortgages on land as security for commercial debts,
unless they hope to get the ownership of the land through
foreclosure. The true basis of every man's credit, from
the consumer at the cross-roads store to the great retail
merchant at the factory or the jobbing house, is honesty,
opportunity, and ability. He who will pay his debts if he
can, and has an opportunity to earn enough to pay them
with, and is able to make good use of the opportunity,
needs no land values to offer as a basis for commercial
credit. He has the ideal basis of all credit. And this
basis of credit every man could have if the single tax
were in operation. ... read the book
Charles B. Fillebrown: A Catechism of
Natural Taxation, from Principles of Natural
Taxation (1917)
Q10. What is the distinction between the taxation
of land and the taxation of rent?
A. Taxing land means, in the ordinary use of the words,
to tax the land upon its capital value, or selling value,
at a given rate per $100 or $1,000 of that value. Taxing
rent means taxing the annual value, or ground rent, at a
given percentage of that rent. It is in one case a tax on
rent; in the other is a tax on capitalized rent.
Q15. What should be the limit of revenue under the
single tax?
A. The same as under any other system of taxation, the
cost of government economically administered.
Q16. Did not Henry George hold that the full
ground rent of land should be taken in
taxation?
A. No! Not only did he concede a margin of rent to the
landlord, but as a matter of fact, as Thomas G. Shearman
said, "not all the power of all governments" could
collect in taxation all of ground rent.
Q40. What is meant by a capitalized
tax?
A. It is a sum, the interest of which would pay the
tax.
Q62. Would it be wise to take gradually in
taxation, say, 1/4, one half, or 3/4 of the future
increase in economic rent?
A. One hundred and one professors of political economy
have answered "Yes." Twenty-nine have answered
"No."
Q63. How could the single tax be put into
operation?
A. By gradually transferring to land all taxes not
already on it.
Q64. How might such a plan be worked
out?
A. If fifty cents per thousand should be deducted yearly
for 30 years from the rate on all property other than
land, the reduction would finally amount to $15 per
thousand, and it would then be practically exempt from
all taxation.
Q65. But how could it be worked out in case of the
land?
A. Recognizing that a right thing may be done in a wrong
way, it is insisted that a right way ought to be found to
do a thing that ought to be done. The following is
presented as a natural and convenient unit of calculation: To be exact,
an average of about 20 percent of the
gross ground rent of land is now taken in taxation, for
instance, in Boston, as well as for the whole state of
Massachusetts. If an additional one percent should be
taken each year for 30 years, it would amount at the end
of that period to 30 percent, which, added to 20 percent,
would make 50 percent, or one half, which is about the
average proportion that present taxes levied on all
property bear to gross ground rent. Meantime few
landowners would feel the change, much less be prejudiced
by it.
The following variable illustrations, A, B, and C, make
clear.
A "Modus
Operandi"
A Increase of Present Tax
For instance, applied to the assessment of a specific
lot of land for which the user pays a gross ground rent
of say ...... $68.00
Of which amount there is taken in taxation, 1915 .....
$18.00
Leaving a net income to the owner of ....
$50.00
The selling value (presumably also the assessed
valuation) would be at 5 per cent ... $1,000.00
Proceeding to take yearly from now on 1 per cent
additional of the gross ground rent of $68 for a period
of thirty years would amount in all to 30 per cent of
$68, equal to .... $20.40
Which, added to the tax already taken .... $18.00
Would give at the end of thirty years, from the $1,000
worth of land alone, everything else being exempted, a
total tax of .... $38.40.
Which is not much more than one half of the gross ground
rent of ... $68.00
The opening exhibit in detail would stand as
follows:
In 1915 the tax on this $1,000 worth of land was
$18.00
In 1916 the tax would be $18 plus 68 cents (1 per cent of
the gross ground rent, $68); equal to .... $18.68
Reducing the owner's net rent from $50 to $49.32
In 1917 the tax would be $18 plus $1.36 (2 per cent of
the $68), totaling .... $19.36
Reducing the owner's net rent from $50 to $48.64,
In 1918 the tax would be $18 plus $2.04 (3 per cent of
the $68) or $20.45
Reducing the owner's net rent from $50 to $47.96
In 1945 the tax on the land would be $18 plus $20.40 (30
per cent of the $68) or ... $38.40
With all improvements exempted.
Reducing the owner's net rent from $50 to $29.60.
B
For a Future Increment
Tax
The taking in taxation of any desired proportion of
the future increment could be accomplished simply by
continuing the present valuation and present rate as
constant factors, and making a separate individual
assessment of the increment tax after the following or
similar formula, according to the proportion to be
taken. For instance, to take in taxation 50 per
cent of the future increase:
Year
|
Valuation
|
Increment
|
Rate Per M.
|
Tax for Each Year
|
1915 |
$1,000 |
|
|
|
1916 |
$1,040 |
$40 |
$25 |
Tax for year 1916, $1 |
|
1915 |
$1,000 |
|
|
|
1917 |
$1,080 |
$80 |
25 |
Tax for year 1917, $2 |
|
1915 |
$1,000 |
|
|
|
1918 |
$1,120 |
$120 |
25 |
Tax for year 1918, $3 |
|
1915 |
$1,000 |
|
|
|
1919 |
$1,160 |
$160 |
25 |
Tax for year 1919, $4 |
|
1915 |
$1,000 |
|
|
|
1920 |
$1,200 |
$200 |
25 |
Tax for year 1920, $5 |
In applying this formula it would be necessary after the
first few years at least to increase the rate to
correspond to the decrease in assessed valuation due to
this new tax. For computations upon this and
related points, see the Report of the
New York City Commission on New Sources of City
Revenue (1913), p. 7 and Appendices X to XV.
C
The Assessment of Rent
It should be reiterated that inasmuchas gross
ground rent, actual or potential, is the initial factor
in getting at the value of land, it cannot be
unprofitable to become familiar with a more correct
formula as expressed in terms of rent.
Starting with the present unit of annual value for use to
take in taxation in 25 years 50 per cent of the future
increase in ground rent:
Year
|
Net Ground Rent
|
Increment
|
Percentage of Rent
|
Tax for Each Year
|
1915 |
$50 |
|
|
|
1916
|
$52 |
2 |
50 |
Tax for year 1916, $1 |
|
1915 |
$50 |
|
|
|
1917 |
54 |
4 |
50 |
Tax for year 1917, $2 |
|
1915 |
$50 |
|
|
|
1918 |
56 |
6 |
50 |
Tax for year 1918, $3 |
|
1915 |
$50 |
|
|
|
1919 |
58 |
8 |
50 |
Tax for year 1919, $4 |
|
1915 |
$50 |
|
|
|
1920
|
60
|
10
|
50
|
Tax for year 1920, $5 |
|
1915 |
$50 |
|
|
|
1940 |
100 |
50 |
50 |
Tax for year 1940, $25 |
... read
the whole article
|
To share this page with a friend:
right click, choose "send," and add your
comments.
|
|
Red links have not been
visited; .
Green links are pages you've seen
|
Essential Documents pertinent
to this theme:
essential_documents
|
|