Trade
H.G. Brown: Significant
Paragraphs from Henry George's Progress & Poverty,
Chapter 5: The Basic Cause of Poverty (in the
unabridged:
Book V: The Problem Solved)
The great problem, of which these recurring seasons of
industrial depression are but peculiar manifestations, is
now, I think, fully solved, and the social phenomena
which all over the civilized world appall the
philanthropist and perplex the statesman, which hang with
clouds the future of the most advanced races, and suggest
doubts of the reality and ultimate goal of what we have
fondly called progress, are now explained.
The reason why, in spite of the increase of productive
power, wages constantly tend to a minimum which will give
but a bare living, is that, with increase in productive
power, rent tends to even greater increase, thus
producing a constant tendency to the forcing down of
wages.
Land being necessary to labor, and being reduced to
private ownership, every increase in the productive power
of labor but increases rent — the price that labor
must pay for the opportunity to utilize its powers; and
thus all the advantages gained by the march of progress
go to the owners of land, and wages do not increase.*
*Whatever be the fact as to wages, the
reader will, of course, recognize that higher money
wages which merely balance higher living costs, are not
to be reckoned as real wage increases. H.G.B
The simple theory which I have outlined (if indeed it
can be called a theory which is but the recognition of
the most obvious relations) explains this conjunction of
poverty with wealth, of low wages with high productive
power, of degradation amid enlightenment, of virtual
slavery in political liberty.
- It harmonizes, as results flowing from a general
and inexorable law, facts otherwise most perplexing,
and exhibits the sequence and relation between
phenomena that without reference to it are diverse and
contradictory.
- It explains why improvements which increase the
productive power of labor and capital increase the
reward of neither.
- It explains what is commonly called the conflict
between labor and capital, while proving the real
harmony of interest between them.
- It cuts the last inch of ground from under
the fallacies of protection, while showing why free
trade fails to benefit permanently the working
classes.
- It explains why want increases with abundance, and
wealth tends to greater and greater aggregations.
- It explains the vice and misery which show
themselves amid dense population, without attributing
to the laws of the All-Wise and All-Beneficent defects
which belong only to the shortsighted and selfish
enactments of men.
The truth is self-evident. ... read the whole
chapter
Rev. A. C. Auchmuty: Gems from George, a themed
collection of excerpts from the writings of Henry
George (with links to sources)
LET us try to trace the genesis of civilization.
Gifted alone with the power of relating cause and effect,
man is among all animals the only producer in the true
sense of the term. . . . But the same quality of reason
which makes him the producer, also, wherever exchange
becomes possible, makes him the exchanger. And it is
along this line of exchanging that the body economic is
evolved and develops, and that all the advances of
civilization are primarily made. . . . With the beginning
of exchange or trade among men this body economic begins
to form, and in its beginning civilization begins. . . .
To find an utterly uncivilized people, we must find a
people among whom there is no exchange or trade. Such a
people does not exist, and, as far as our knowledge goes,
never did. To find a fully civilized people, we must find
a people among whom exchange or trade is absolutely free,
and has reached the fullest development to which human
desires can carry it. There is, as yet, unfortunately, no
such people. — The Science of Political
Economy —
unabridged: Book I, Chapter 5, The Meaning of Political
Economy: The Origin and Genesis of Civilization
• abridged:
Chapter 4, The Origin and Genesis of
Civilization
WHEN we, come to analyze production, we find it to fall
into three modes, viz::
ADAPTING, or changing natural products either in form or
in place so as to fit them for the satisfaction of human
desire.
GROWING, or utilizing the vital forces of nature, as by
raising vegetables or animals.
EXCHANGING, or utilizing, so as to add to the general sum
of wealth, the higher powers of those natural forces
which vary with locality, or of those human forces which
vary with situation, occupation, or character. —
Progress & Poverty
— Book III, Chapter 3, The Laws of Distribution: of
Interest and the Cause of Interest
THESE modes seem to appear and to assume importance, in
the development of human society, much in the order here
given. They originate from the increase of the desires of
men with the increase of the means of satisfying them,
under pressure of the fundamental law of political
economy, that men seek to satisfy their desires with the
least exertion. In the primitive stage of human life the
readiest way of satisfying desires is by adapting to
human use what is found in existence. In a later and more
settled stage it is discovered that certain desires can
be more easily and more fully satisfied by utilizing the
principle of growth and reproduction, as by cultivating
vegetables and breeding animals. And in a still later
period of development, it becomes obvious that certain
desires can be better and more easily satisfied by
exchange, which brings out the principle of co-operation
more fully and powerfully than could obtain among
unexchanging economic units. — The Science of
Political Economy
unabridged: Book III, Chapter 2, The Production of
Wealth: The Three Modes of Production •
abridged: Part III, Chapter 2, The Production of Wealth:
The Three Modes of Production
ALL living things that we know of co-operate in some
kind and to some degree. So far as we can see, nothing
that lives can live in and for itself alone. But man is
the only one who co-operates by exchanging, and he may be
distinguished from all the numberless tribes that with
him tenant the earth as the exchanging animal. . . .
Exchange is the great agency by which what I have called
the spontaneous or unconscious co-operation of men in the
production of wealth is brought about, and economic units
are welded into that social organism which is the Greater
Leviathan. To this economic body, this Greater Leviathan,
into which it builds the economic units, it is what the
nerves or perhaps the ganglions are to the individual
body. Or, to make use of another illustration, it is to
our material desires and powers of satisfying them what
the switchboard of a telegraph or telephone, or other
electric system, is to that system, a means by which
exertion of one kind in one place may be transmitted into
satisfaction of another kind in another place, and thus
the efforts of individual units be conjoined and
correlated so as to yield satisfactions in most useful
place and form, and to an amount enormously exceeding
what otherwise would be possible. — The Science
of Political Economy —
unabridged: Book III, Chapter 11, The Production of
Wealth: The Office of Exchange in Production •
unabridged
Chapter 9, The Office of Exchange in Production
WE should keep our own market for our
own producers, seems by many to be regarded as the
same kind of a proposition as, We should
keep our own pasture for our own cows; whereas, in
truth, it is such a proposition as, We
should keep our own appetites for our own cookery,
or, We should keep our own
transportation for our own legs.—
Protection or Free Trade, Chapter 11: The Home
Market and Home Trade -
econlib
THE protection of the masses has in all times been the
pretense of tyranny — the plea of monarchy, of
aristocracy, of special privilege of every kind. The
slave owners justified slavery as protecting the slaves.
British misrule in Ireland is upheld on the ground that
it is for the protection of the Irish. But, whether under
a monarchy or under a republic, is there an instance in
the history of the world in which the "protection" of the
laboring masses has not meant their oppression? The
protection that those who have got the law-making power
into their hands have given labor, has at best always
been the protection that man gives to cattle — he
protects them that he may use and eat them. —
Protection or Free Trade — Chapter 2,
Clearing Ground
econlib
IT is never intimated that the land-owner or the
capitalist needs protection. They, it is always assumed,
can take care of themselves. It is only the poor
workingman who must be protected. What is labor that it
should so need protection? Is not labor the creator of
capital, the producer of all wealth? Is it not the men
who labor that feed and clothe all others? Is it not
true, as has been said, that the three great orders of
society are "workingmen, beggarmen, and thieves?" How,
then, does it come that workingmen alone need protection?
— Protection or Free Trade — Chapter
2, Clearing Ground
econlib -|- abridged
WHAT should we think of human laws framed for the
government of a country which should compel each family
to keep constantly on their guard against every other
family, to expend a large part of their time and labor in
preventing exchanges with their neighbors, and to seek
their own prosperity by opposing the natural efforts of
other families to become prosperous? Yet the protective
theory implies that laws such as these have been imposed
by the Creator upon the families of men who tenant this
earth. It implies that by virtue of social laws, as
immutable as the physical laws, each nation must stand
jealously on guard against every other nation and erect
artificial obstacles to national intercourse.—
Protection or Free Trade, Chapter 4: Protection
as a Universal Need
econlib
TO attempt to make a nation prosperous by preventing it
from buying from other nations is as absurd as it would
be to attempt to make a man prosperous by preventing him
from buying from other men. How this operates in the case
of the individual we can see from that practice which,
since its application in the Irish land agitation, has
come to be called "boycotting." Captain Boycott, upon
whom has been thrust the unenviable fame of having his
name turned into a verb, was in fact "protected." He had
a protective tariff of the most efficient kind built
around him by a neighborhood decree more effective than
act of Parliament. No one would sell him labor, no one
would sell him milk or bread or meat or any service or
commodity whatever. But instead of growing prosperous,
this much-protected man had to fly from a place where his
own market was thus reserved for his own productions.
What protectionists ask us to do to ourselves in
reserving our home market for home producers, is in kind
what the Land Leaguers did to Captain Boycott. They ask
us to boycott ourselves. — Protection or Free
Trade, Chapter 11: The Home Market and Home Trade -
econlib
WHEN not caused by artificial obstacles, any tendency in
trade to take a certain course is proof that it ought to
take that course, and restrictions are harmful because
they restrict, and in proportion as they restrict. To
assert that the way for men to become healthy and strong
is for them to force into their stomachs what nature
tries to reject, to regulate the play of their lungs by
bandages, or to control the circulation of their blood by
ligatures, would be not a whit more absurd than to assert
that the way for nations to become rich is for them to
restrict the natural tendency to trade. —
Protection or Free Trade, Chapter 6: Trade -
econlib
MEN of different nations trade with each other for the
same reason that men of the same nation do —
because they find it profitable; because they thus obtain
what they want with less labor than they otherwise could.
— Protection or Free Trade, Chapter 6:
Trade -
econlib -|- abridged
TRADE is not invasion. It does not involve aggression on
one side and resistance on the other, but mutual consent
and gratification. There cannot be a trade unless the
parties to it agree, any more than there can be a quarrel
unless the parties to it differ. England, we say, forced
trade with the outside world upon China and the United
States upon Japan. But, in both cases, what was done was
not to force the people to trade, but to force their
governments to let them. If the people had not wanted to
trade, the opening of the ports would have been useless.
— Protection or Free Trade, Chapter 6:
Trade -
econlib
TRADE does not require force. Free trade consists simply
in letting people buy and sell as they want to buy and
sell.. It is protection that requires force, for it
consists in preventing people from doing what they want
to do. — Protection or Free Trade, Chapter
6: Trade -
econlib -|- abridged
IF all the material things needed by man could be
produced equally well at all points on the earth's
surface, it might seem more convenient for man the
animal, but how would he have risen above the animal
level? As we see in the history of social development,
commerce has been and is the great civilizer and
educator. The seemingly infinite diversities in the
capacity of different parts of the earth's surface lead
to that exchange of productions which is the most
powerful agent in preventing isolation, in breaking down
prejudice, in increasing knowledge and widening thought.
These diversities of nature, which seemingly increase
with our knowledge of nature's powers, like the
diversities in the aptitudes of individuals and
communities, which similarly increase with social
development, call forth powers and give rise to pleasures
which could never arise had man been placed like an ox in
a boundless field of clover. The "international law of
God" which we fight with our tariffs — so
shortsighted are the selfish prejudices of men — is
the law which stimulates mental and moral progress; the
law to which civilization is due. —
Social Problems — Chapter 19: The First Great
Reform.
AND will not the community gain by thus refusing to
kill the goose that lays the golden eggs; by thus
refraining from muzzling the ox that treadeth out the
corn; by thus leaving to industry, and thrift, and skill,
their natural reward, full and unimpaired? For there is
to the community also a natural reward. The law of
society is, each for all, as well as all for each. No one
can keep to himself the good he may do, any more than he
can keep the bad. Every productive enterprise, besides
its return to those who undertake it, yields collateral
advantages to others. If a man plant a fruit tree, his
gain is that he gathers the fruit in its time and season.
But in addition to his gain, there is a gain to the whole
community. Others than the owner are benefited by the
increased supply of fruit; the birds which it shelters
fly far and wide; the rain which it helps to attract
falls not alone on his field; and, even to the eye which
rests upon it from a distance, it brings a sense of
beauty. And so with everything else. The building of a
house, a factory, a ship, or a railroad, benefits others
besides those who get the direct profits. Nature laughs
at a miser. He is like the squirrel who buries his nuts
and refrains from digging them up again. Lo! they sprout
and grow into trees. In fine linen, steeped in costly
spices, the mummy is laid away. Thousands and thousands
of years thereafter, the Bedouin cooks his food by a fire
of its encasings, it generates the steam by which the
traveler is whirled on his way, or it passes into far-off
lands to gratify the curiosity of another race. The bee
fills the hollow tree with honey, and along comes the
bear or the man. —
Progress & Poverty
— Book IX, Chapter 1, Effects of the Remedy: Of the
Effect upon the Production of Wealth
CONSIDER the effect of such a change upon the labor
market. Competition would no longer be one-sided, as now.
Instead of laborers competing with each other for
employment, and in their competition cutting down wages
to the point of bare subsistence, employers would
everywhere be competing for laborers, and wages would
rise to the fair earnings of labor. For into the labor
market would have entered the greatest of all competitors
for the employment of labor, a competitor whose demand
cannot be satisfied until want is satisfied — the
demand of labor itself. The employers of labor would not
have merely to bid against other employers, all feeling
the stimulus of greater trade and increased profits, but
against the ability of laborers to become their own
employers upon the natural opportunities freely opened to
them by the tax which prevented monopolization. —
Progress & Poverty
— Book IX, Chapter 1, Effects of the Remedy: Of the
Effect upon the Production of Wealth
... go to "Gems from
George"
Mark Twain Archimedes
As I owned all the land, they would of course,
have to pay me rent. They could not reasonably expect me
to allow them the use of the land for nothing. I am not a
hard man, and in fixing the rent I would be very liberal
with them. I would allow them, in fact, to fix it
themselves. What could be fairer? Here is a piece of
land, let us say, it might be a farm, it might be a
building site, or it might be something else - if there
was only one man who wanted it, of course he would not
offer me much, but if the land be really worth anything
such a circumstance is not likely to happen. On the
contrary, there would be a number who would want it, and
they would go on bidding and bidding one against the
other, in order to get it. I should accept the highest
offer - what could be fairer? Every
increase of population, extension of trade, every advance
in the arts and sciences would, as we all know, increase
the value of land, and the competition that would
naturally arise would continue to force rents upward, so
much so, that in many cases the tenants would have little
or nothing left for themselves. ... Read the
whole piece
Louis Post: Outlines
of Louis F. Post's Lectures, with Illustrative Notes and
Charts (1894)
2. THE PRODUCTION OF
WEALTH
When considered in connection with primitive modes of
production, the vital importance of this truth is
self-evident. 55 If those modes prevailed, involuntary
poverty would be readily traced either to direct
enslavement through ownership of Labor, or to indirect
enslavement through ownership of Land. 56 There could be
no other cause. If both causes were absent, every
individual might, if he wished, enjoy all the Wealth that
his own powers were capable of producing in 'the
primitive modes of production and under the limitations
of common knowledge that belonged to his
environment.57
But in the civilized state this principle is so
entangled in the complexities of division of labor and
trade as to be almost lost in the maze. Many, even of
those who recognize it, fail to grasp it as a fundamental
truth. Yet it is no less vital in civilized than in
primitive modes of production.
a. Division of Labor
The essential difference between primitive and
civilized modes of production is not in the accumulation
of capital which characterizes the latter, but in the
greater scope and minuteness of its division of labor.58
Capital is an effect of division of labor rather than a
cause. Division of labor, by enhancing labor power and
relieving man from the perpetual pursuit of mere
subsistence, utilizes capital and makes civilization
possible.59
58. It is his failure to realize this
that accounts for the theory of the socialist that
laborers in the civilized state are dependent upon
accumulated capital as well as upon land for
opportunities to produce. See ante, note 49, and post,
note 81.
59. Here are two men at a given point.
Each has an errand to do a mile to the east, and each
has one to do a mile to the west. If each goes upon his
own errand each will travel a mile out and a mile back
in one direction and the same in the other, making four
miles' travel apiece, or eight miles in all. But if one
does both errands to the east and the other does both
to the west, they will travel but two miles apiece, or
four in all. By division of labor they free half their
energy and half their time for devotion to other work,
or to study, or to play, as their inclinations
dictate.
The productive power of division of labor may be
illustrated by considering it as a means for utilizing
differences of soil and climate. If, for example, the
soil and the climate of two sections of a country, or of
two different countries (for the effects of division of
labor are not dependent upon political geography 60),
differ inversely, one being better adapted to the
production of corn than of sugar, and the other, on the
contrary, being better adapted to the production of sugar
than of corn, they will yield more wealth in corn and
sugar with division of labor than without it.
6o. No more than are the effects of a
healthful climate. Protectionists who argue that there
should be free trade between villages, cities, counties
and states in the same nation, but protection for
nations, thus making the effect of trade to depend upon
the invisible political boundary line that separates
communities, are like the colored woman who, when her
house, without being physically removed, had been
politically shifted from North Carolina to Virginia by
a change of the boundary line, expressed her
satisfaction in the remark that she was very glad of
it, because she "allus yearn tail dot dat yah Nof Kline
was an a'mighty sickly State," and she was glad that
she didn't "live dyeah no me'!"
Let us imagine a Mainland and an Island, which, as to
the adaptability of their soil and climate to the
production of corn and sugar, so differ that if the
people of each should raise their own corn and their own
sugar they would produce, with a given unit of labor
force, but 22 of Wealth — 11 in corn and 11 in
sugar. Thus: [chart]
Production in that manner would ignore the
opportunities afforded by nature to man for utilizing
differences of soil and climate; but by such a wise
division as Labor would adopt in similar circumstances,
if unrestrained, the same unit of labor force almost
doubles the product. Thus: [chart]
Nor is it alone because it utilizes differences of
soil and climate that division of labor is so effective.
Its effectiveness is enhanced in still higher degree by
its lessening of the labor force necessary to accomplish
any industrial result, whether in mining, manufacturing,
transporting, store-keeping, professional employments,
agriculture, or the incidental occupations. Minute
division of labor, instead of accounting for poverty in
the civilized state, makes it all the more unaccountable.
...
b. Trade
But division of labor is dependent upon trade. If
trade were wholly stopped there would be no division of
labor; 61 if it be interfered with, division of labor is
obstructed. 62 In the last preceding chart, which
illustrates the effect of division of labor without
trade, the Mainland gets 20 of corn, but no sugar, and
the Island gets 20 of sugar, but no corn. Yet each wants
both sugar and corn; and if they freely trade, their
wants in these respects will be better satisfied than if
each raises its own corn and sugar.
61. Men who devoted themselves to
specialties, unable to exchange their products for the
objects of their desire, which alone would be the
motive for their special labor, would abandon
specialties and resort to less civilized methods of
supplying their wants.
62. Division of labor, whether adopted to
take advantage of the different varieties of land or to
secure the benefits of special skill in labor, cannot
continue without trade; and to the degree that trade is
impeded, to that degree division of labor will
languish. It is only under absolute free trade between
all people and in respect of all products that division
of labor can flourish. Any interference with it is
economically an enslavement of labor in a degree
proportioned to the degree of interference.
Compare the first chart of this series with the
following: 63 [chart]
The comparison 64 illustrates the advantage to each
individual, community and country, of division of labor
and trade over more primitive modes of production. It is
like the difference between raising weights by direct
application of power, and by means of block and
tackle.65
63. It will be seen from this chart that
the people of the two places, by dividing their given
expenditure of labor in such a manner as to utilize the
natural advantage peculiar to each place, secure a
clear profit of 18. And this is a substantial profit,
consisting not merely of figures upon paper, but of
real wealth — artificial external objects which
serve to satisfy human desires.
64. The people of the Mainland have now
sent 10 of their corn to the Island, and the people of
the Island have paid for it by sending 10 of their
sugar to the Mainland.
For simplicity. the cost of effecting the
trade is omitted. It does not affect the principle. If
the cost were so high that more sugar and corn could be
got without division of labor than with, division of
labor would be abandoned as unprofitable; if low enough
to admit of any profit at all, the trading would go on,
unless restrained, precisely as if it involved no cost.
It may be well to state, however, that the nearer we
get to no cost in trading, the better are we off.
Hence, any tariff on trading, whether domestic or
foreign, like railroad and shipping rates for freight,
is prejudicial; for tariffs add to the cost of trading
just as freight rates do. Protection has that for its
object. When it does not add enough to the price of a
foreign product to prevent importation it fails of its
purpose. And though revenue tariffs have no such object
they produce the same effect, only in minor degree.
65. If every man were obliged, unassisted
by the co-operation of others, to supply his own needs
directly by his own labor, few could more than meagerly
satisfy even the simplest of those desires which we
have in common with lower animals. Though each labored
diligently the aggregate of wealth would be exceedingly
small compared with the necessities of those who wished
to consume it, while in variety it would be very
limited and in quality of the poorest kind. But by
division of labor, which has been carried to marvelous
lengths and is still developing, productive power is so
enormously increased that the annual wealth products of
the present time, in quantity and quality, in variety,
usefulness and beauty, almost appear to be the work of
giants and fairies.
And what this series of charts illustrates regarding
two places and two forms of wealth, is true in principle
of all places and all forms of wealth. That every one is
better served when each does for others what relatively
he does best, in exchange for what relatively they do
best, is as true of communities and nations as it is of
individuals. Indeed, it is true of communities and
nations because it is true of individuals; for it is
individuals that trade, and not communities or nations as
such.66
66. Mankind as a whole may be likened to
a great man, with eyes to see, brain to invent and
direct, nerves for intercommunication, and various
muscles for various actions. As different parts of the
bodies of men do different things, each part
contributing co-operatively to a general result, so it
is with the body politic, whose different parts —
individual men — contribute in different ways to
the common good. Trade is to the body politic what
digestion is to the physical body. To prohibit it is to
deprive the great man of his stomach; to restrict it is
to give him dyspepsia.
Says Emerson in the "American Scholar,"
an oration delivered at Cambridge in 1837: "It is one
of those fables which out of an unknown antiquity
convey an unlocked-for wisdom, that the gods, in the
beginning, divided man into men, that he might be more
helpful to himself; just as the hand was divided into
fingers, the better to answer its ends."
Reflection upon the labor-saving power of
trade makes it clear that the notion of protectionists
that free trade is prejudicial to home industry has no
foundation. It would interfere with "home industries"
that could be better conducted elsewhere; but by that
very fact it would strengthen the industries that
belonged at home.
When we decide to buy foreign goods we do
not thereby decide to employ foreign labor instead of
American labor; we decide that the American labor shall
be employed in making things to trade for what we buy,
instead of making the things that we buy. And we get a
better net result or we wouldn't do it.
Free trade and labor-saving machinery,
which belong in the same industrial category, increase
the aggregate wealth of the country where they
flourish. Whether or not they tend to impoverish
individuals or classes, depends upon the manner in
which the increased wealth is distributed. If they do
so tend, the remedy surely does not lie in the
direction of obstructing trade and smashing machines so
that less wealth may be produced with given labor, but
in altering the conditions that promote unjust
distribution.
c. The Law of Division of Labor and
Trade
Now, what is it that leads men to conform their
conduct to the principle illustrated by the last chart?
Why do they divide their labor, and trade its products? A
simple, universal and familiar law of human nature moves
them. Whether men be isolated, or be living in primitive
communities, or in advanced states of civilization, their
demand for consumption determines the direction of Labor
in production.67 That is the law. Considered in
connection with a solitary individual, like Robinson
Crusoe upon his island, it is obvious. What he demanded
for consumption he was obliged to produce. Even as to the
goods he collected from stranded ships — desiring
to consume them, he was obliged to labor to produce them
to places of safety. His demand for consumption always
determined the direction of his labor in production.68
And when we remember that what Robinson Crusoe was to his
island in the sea, civilized man as a whole is to this
island in space, we may readily understand the
application of the same simple law to the great body of
labor in the civilized world.69 Nevertheless, the
complexities of civilized life are so likely to obscure
its operation and disguise its relations to social
questions like that of the persistence of poverty as to
make illustration desirable.
67. The term " production" means not
creation but adaptation. Man cannot add an atom to the
universe of matter; but he can so modify the condition
of matter, both in respect of form and of place, as to
adapt it to the satisfaction of human desires. To do
this is to produce wealth.
"Consumption" is the ultimate object of
all production. We produce because we desire to
consume. But consumption does not mean destruction. Man
has no more power to destroy than to create. His power
in consumption, like his power in production, is
limited to changing the condition of things. As by
production man changes things from natural to
artificial conditions to satisfy his desires, so by
consumption he changes things from artificial to
natural conditions in the process of satisfying his
desires.
Production is the drawing forth of
desired things, of Wealth, from the Land; consumption
is the returning back of those things to the Land.
"All labor is but the movement of
particles of matter from one place to another." —
Dick's Outlines, p. 25.
Production consists merely in changing
things — Ely's Intro., part ii, ch. i; Mill's
Prin., book i, ch. i, sec. 2.
"As man creates no new matter but only
utilities, so he destroys no matter, but only
utilities. Consumption means the destruction of a
utility." — Ely's Intro., part v. ch. i., p.
268.
Production means "drawing forth." —
Jevons's Primer, sec. 17.
"Man cannot create material things. . .
His efforts and sacrifices result in changing the form
or arrangement of matter to adapt it better for the
satisfaction of wants." — Marshall's Prin., book
ii, ch. iii, sec. i.
"It is sometimes said that traders do not
produce; that while the cabinet maker produces
furniture, the furniture dealer merely sells what is
already produced. But there is no scientific foundation
for this distinction." — Id.
"As his [man's] production of material
products is really nothing more than a rearrangement of
matter which gives it new utilities, so his consumption
of them is nothing more than a disarrangement of matter
which diminishes or destroys its utilities." —
Id.
"In like manner as by production is meant
the creation not of substance but of utility, so by
consumption is meant the destruction of utility and not
of substance or matter." — Say's Trea., book ii,
ch. i.
"All that man can do is to reproduce
existing materials under another form, which may give
them a utility they did not before possess, or merely
enlarge one they may have before presented. So that in
fact there is a creation not of matter but of utility ;
and this I call production of wealth. . . There is no
actual production of wealth without a creation or
augmentation of utility."— Say's Trea., book i,
ch. i.
68. It is highly significant that while
Robinson Crusoe had unsatisfied wants he was never out
of a job.
69. Demand for consumption is satisfied
not from hoards of accumulated wealth, but from the
stream of current production. Broadly speaking there
can be no accumulation of wealth in the sense of saving
up wealth from generation to generation. Imagine a
man's satisfying his demand for eggs from the
accumulated stores of his ancestors! Yet eggs do not
differ in this respect from other forms of wealth,
except that some other forms will keep a little longer,
and some not so long.
The notion that a saving instinct must be
aroused before the great and more lasting forms of
wealth can be brought forth is a mistake. Houses and
locomotives, for example, are built not because of any
desire to accumulate wealth, but because we need houses
to live in and locomotives to transport us and our
goods. It is not the saving, but the serving, instinct
that induces the production of these things; the same
instinct that induces the production of a loaf of
bread.
Artificial things do not save. No sooner
are the processes of production from land complete than
the products are on their way back to the land. If man
does not return them by means of consumption, then
through decay they return themselves. Mankind as a
whole lives literally from hand to mouth. What is
demanded for consumption in the present must be
produced by the labor of the present. From current
production, and from that alone, can current
consumption be satisfied.
"Accumulated wealth" is, in fact, not
wealth at all in any great degree. It is merely titles
to wealth yet to be produced. A share in a mining
company, for example, is but a certificate that the
owner is legally entitled to a proportion of the wealth
to be produced in the future from a certain mine.
Titles to future wealth may be both
morally and legally valid. This is so when they
represent past labor or its products loaned in free
contract for future labor or its products; for example,
a contract for the delivery of goods of any kind today
to be paid for next week. or next month, or next year,
or in ten years, or later.
They may be legally but not morally
valid. This is so when they represent the product of a
franchise (whether paid for in labor or not) to exact
tribute from future labor; for example, a franchise to
confiscate a man's labor through ownership of his body,
as in slavery, or a franchise to confiscate the
products of labor in general through ownership of
land.
Or they may be both legally and morally
invalid, as when they are obtained by illegal force or
fraud from the rightful owner. ...
The poverty of Food-makers as to clothing is thus
removed. They are working all they care to at
food-making, their own chosen employment, and they are
paid in clothing, their own chosen compensation. So long
as Personal Servants withdraw food and Clothing-makers
supply clothing, Food-makers cannot be poor. With them
business will be brisk, labor will be in demand, and
wages will be high. That all the other workers may enjoy
the same prosperity we shall see in a moment.
Clothing-makers pour clothing into the commercial
reservoir because they wish to take something out, and
know that in this way they can get a larger quantity and
better quality of what they require than if they
undertake to make it themselves. They are skilled in
making clothing; they are not skilled in other ways.
Accordingly they utilize the claim against Personal
Servants, which has passed to their credit in exchange
for clothing, by drawing from the commercial reservoir
the particular commodity they desire. Suppose it to be
shelter. They proceed as Personal Servants and
Food-makers have already done, and so set Shelter-makers
at work. Shelter-makers in turn utilize the claim against
Personal Servants which has now been credited to them, by
taking luxuries out of the reservoir. This sets
Luxury-makers at work. Luxury-makers then pass the claim
over in exchange for services, and Personal Servants
redeem it by rendering such services as Luxury-makers
demand.72 Everybody is now paid for his own products with
the products of others; and by demanding more food,
Personal Servants may perpetuate the interchange
indefinitely.73 And Personal Servants will continue to
demand more food until their wants as to food are wholly
and finally satisfied.74
72. The mechanism of these exchanges
should be explained.
Personal Servants upon demanding food may
pay money for it. The retailers might thereupon pass
the money along, and it would ultimately return to
Personal Servants. Or the Personal Servants may give
notes payable at a future time, which being endorsed
over would at last be redeemed by them in services. Or
they may give checks on banks, which assumes previous
work done by them or the discounting of their notes by
the banks. As the world's exchanges are almost wholly
adjusted by means of checks, and other commercial paper
which is in economic effect the same as checks, let us
illustrate that mode by a series of charts adapted from
Jevons.
We will begin with two traders, A and B.
They have no money, but every time that one demands
anything of the other he must offer in exchange
something that the other wants. There must be what is
called "a double coincidence" of demand and supply;
each must want what the other has. This is primitive
barter. It may be represented by the following chart
:
In the civilized state, even in its
beginnings, primitive barter must be obstructive to
trade, and it gives way to the use of currency —
some common medium which is taken for goods not because
the taker wants it but because he knows that be can
readily exchange it for the goods that he does want.
With currency in use, when A wants anything of B he is
not obliged to find something that B wants. All he
needs is currency. Thus currency reduces the friction
of trading.
But as the volume of trade augments,
demand for currency increases; and because it is
scarce, or troublesome or dangerous to transmit, or all
together, easier means of exchange are resorted to, and
bookkeeping takes the place of currency as currency
took the place of primitive barter. At this stage, when
A wants anything of B, B charges him; and when B wants
anything of A, A charges him. Their mutual accounts
being adjusted, the small balance is paid with
currency. Thus the demand for currency is greatly
lowered by bookkeeping, and the friction of trading is
correspondingly reduced.
Now let us bring in two more traders, C
and D:
Though all four of these traders keep
mutual accounts, the settlement of balances requires
more currency than before, and scarcity of currency,
together with the danger and expense of transmission,
evolves an extension of bookkeeping. A common
bookkeeper, called a "Bank," is employed, and all need
for currency disappears:
Balances are now settled by checks, and
all accounts are adjusted in the central ledger at the
bank.
But the introduction of another group of
traders, another community, renews the demand for
currency, and another bank appears. Thus:
And now the two banks are in the same
position that A and B were in before any bank came.
They keep mutual accounts, but they must have currency
to settle their balances. And if we bring in more
communities the demand for currency further increases.
Thus:
Now the four banks are in the same
situation that A, B, C and D were in before there were
any banks. This evolves a bank of banks — a
clearing-house.
All necessity for currency once more
disappears.
These charts illustrate the principle by
which mutual trading is effected. In practice, the need
of currency is never wholly done away with, but the
tendency is constantly in the direction of doing away
with it. And it is said that over ninety per cent of
the trading transactions of the world are adjusted in
this manner, and less than ten per cent by means of
currency.
The clearing-house principle extends over
the civilized world. In illustration of this, observe
the following chart:
These five cities are like the five banks. The
bookkeeping of each city is conducted by local banks
and clearing-houses, and the central bookkeeping by
those of the market town of the world, which at present
is London.
In this way the mobility of labor is in
effect enormously increased. Labor in every corner of
the world is brought into close trading relations with
labor everywhere else, so that only war, pestilence,
protection, and land monopoly interfere with the full
freedom of its movement.
73. Personal Servants, on the basis of
their employment by Luxury-makers, demand more food,
which keeps Food-makers at work; Food-makers demand
more clothing, which keeps Clothing-makers at work;
Clothing-makers demand more shelter, which keeps
Shelter-makers at work; Shelter-makers demand more
luxuries, which keeps Luxury-makers at work;
Luxury-makers demand more services, which keeps
Personal Servants at work. And so on indefinitely.
If now we add progressive invention, so
that every one produces more and more wealth with less
and less labor, instead of finding poverty upon the
increase, instead of being harried by periodical "hard
times," we shall find business brisk and every one
becoming richer and richer. That is to say, though all
labor less than before, each obtains better results
from others while giving better results in
exchange.
And should we improve the verisimilitude
of the illustration by bringing in the fact that all
workers in civilized society are specialists in a much
more minute degree than the division into
Clothing-makers, Food-makers, etc., would imply —
that every one who works does over and over some one
thing in one of these branches, as the making of shoes
or the baking of bread, or even only part of a thing,
as the cutting of shoe soles, and that while giving out
a great deal of his own product he demands in pay a
little of every other kind of product — the same
effect would naturally result.
Every man who demands anything for
consumption thereby determines the direction of labor
toward the production not only of that thing, but also
of all the artificial materials and implements, from
the simplest tool to the most expensive and complex
machine, that are used in its production. The actual
process is much more intricate than that of the charts,
but the charts illustrate the principle so that any
intelligent person who understands them can apply
— it to the most complex affairs of industrial
life.
"This principle is so simple and obvious
that it needs no further illustration, yet in its light
all the complexities of our subject disappear, and we
thus reach the same view of the real objects and
rewards of labor in the intricacies of modern
production that we rained by observing in the first
beginnings of society the simpler forms of production
and exchange. We see that now, as then, each laborer is
endeavoring to obtain by his exertions the satisfaction
of his own desires; we see that although the minute
division of labor assigns to each producer the
production of but a small part, or perhaps nothing at
all, of the particular things he labors to get, yet, in
aiding in the production of what other producers want,
he is directing other labor to the production of the
things he wants — in effect, producing them
himself. And thus, if he makes jackknives and eats
wheat, the wheat is really as much the produce of his
labor as if he had grown it for himself and left
wheat-growers to make their own jackknives." —
Progress and Poverty. book i, ch. iv.
74. There is no end to man's wants.
"The demand for quantity once satisfied,
he seeks quality. The very desires that he has in
common with the beast become extended, refined,
exalted. It is not merely hunger, but taste, that seeks
gratification in food; in clothes, he seeks not merely
comfort, but adornment; the rude shelter becomes a
house; the undiscriminating sexual attraction begins to
transmute itself into subtle influences, and the hard
and common stock of animal life to blossom and to bloom
into shapes of delicate beauty." — Progress and
Poverty, book ii, ch. iii.
A labor agitator was arguing the labor
question with a rich man, the judge of his county, when
the judge as a clincher asked:
"what do workingmen want, anyway, that
they haven't got?"
Promptly the agitator replied with the
counter-question
"Judge, what have you got that you don't
want?"
...
Let us now complete this chart. When we began it a
distinction was noted between Personal Servants, who
render mere intangible services, and the other classes,
who produce tangible wealth. But essentially there is no
difference. By referring to the chart and observing the
course of the arrows, Food-makers are seen working for
Personal Servants precisely as Personal Servants work for
Luxury-makers. We may therefore abandon the distinction.
This makes it no longer necessary to mention particular
classes of products in the chart; it is enough to
distinguish the different kinds of labor.76 Thus:
76. "This, then, we may say is the great
law which binds society — 'service for service.'
"— Dick's Outlines, p. 9.
For simplicity the workers have been divided into
great classes, and each class has been supposed to serve
only one other class. But the actual currents of trade
are much more complex. It would be practically impossible
to follow them in detail, or to illustrate their
particular movements in any simple way. And it is
unnecessary. The principle illustrated in the chart is
the principle of all division of labor and trade, however
minute the details and intricate the movement; and any
person of ordinary intelligence who wishes to understand
will need only to grasp the principle as illustrated by
the chart to be able to apply it to the experiences of
everyday industrial life. All legitimate trade is the
interchange of Labor for Labor.77
77. In the light of this principle how
absurd are some of the explanations of hard times.
Overproduction! when an infinite variety
of wants are unsatisfied which those who are in want
are anxious and able to satisfy for one another.
Hatters want bread, and bakers want hats, and farmers
want both, and they all want machines, and machinists
want bread and hats and machines, and so on without
end. Yet while men are against their will in partial or
complete idleness, their wants go unsatisfied! Since
producers are also consumers, and production is
governed by demand for consumption, there can be no
real overproduction until demand ceases. The apparent
overproduction which we see — overproduction
relatively to "effective demand" — is in fact a
congestion of some things due to an abnormal
underproduction of other things, the underproduction
being caused by obstructions in the way of labor.
Scarcity of capital! when makers of
capital in all its forms are involuntarily idle.
Scarcity of capital, like scarcity of money, is only an
expression for lack of employment. But why should there
be any lack of employment while men have unsatisfied
wants which they can reciprocally satisfy?
Too much competition! when competition
and freedom are the same. It is not freedom but
restraint, not competition but protection, that
obstructs the action and reaction of demand and supply
which we have illustrated in the chart.
... read the
book
Nic Tideman: A Bill of Economic Rights and
Obligations
Article 6: People have the right to trade
freely with persons in all other localities, subject only
to restrictions of the localities of the trading persons.
Every locality has an obligation to allow goods to pass
freely through its territory, except that, to the extent
that the passage of goods causes cost, those costs may be
recovered.
Nic
Tideman: Basic Tenets
of the Incentive Taxation Philosophy
When the principle that the value of
government-assigned opportunities should be received by the
public treasury is violated, the result is "privilege,"
which from its Latin roots means "private law," that
is, law that permits one person to do what others are not
permitted to do. Thus what we stand for
is an end to privilege.
Numerous examples of privilege are
incorporated in our institutions.
- Farm legislation restricts the growing of
tobacco to those who have been assigned acreage
allotments.
- For numerous commodities, trade legislation
limits shipments from individual countries to specified
quotas.
- In many cities, only persons who have been
given permits are allowed to operate taxis, and new
permits are not issued.
- To operate a radio or television station
requires a license, and there are no opportunities for
new licenses to be issued.
- In most cities, construction of commercial or
multi-family residential structures requires zoning
permission that is granted to some and not to
others.
- But the single most important category of
privilege is land titles.
This list of examples of privilege,
which is by no means exhaustive, contains some privileges,
such as acreage allotments and import quotas, that would be
best reformed by eliminating restrictions and permitting
all to do what now only some may do. For other privileges,
such as broadcast licenses and land titles, great
productivity results from the social understanding that a
specified individual will have the use of a given resource.
For these privileges, the best reform is the introduction
of the requirement that any person who is assigned such an
opportunity must pay to the public treasury an annual fee
equal to what the opportunity would be worth to someone
else. ... Read the
whole article
Weld Carter:
An Introduction to
Henry George
However, what is the effect on production of taxes
levied on products and of taxes levied on the value of
land?
Of taxes levied on products, George
said: "The present method of taxation operates upon
exchange like artificial deserts and mountains; it costs
more to get goods through a custom house than it does to
carry them around the world. It operates upon energy, and
industry, and skill, and thrift, like a fine upon those
qualities. If I have worked harder and built myself a good
house while you have been contented to live in a hovel, the
taxgatherer now comes annually to make me pay a penalty for
my energy and industry, by taxing me more than you. If I
have saved while you wasted, I am mulct, while you are
exempt. If a man build a ship we make him pay for his
temerity, as though he had done an injury to the state; if
a railroad be opened, down comes the taxcollector upon it,
as though it were a public nuisance; if a manufactory be
erected we levy upon it an annual sum which would go far
toward making a handsome profit. We say we want capital,
but if anyone accumulate it, or bring it among us, we
charge him for it as though we were giving him a privilege.
We punish with a tax the man who covers barren fields with
ripening grain, we fine him who puts up machinery, and him
who drains a swamp. How heavily these taxes burden
production only those realize who have attempted to follow
our system of taxation through its ramifications, for, as I
have before said, the heaviest part of taxation is that
which falls in increased prices" (1879, rpt. 1958, p.
434).
Turning to taxation levied on the
value of land, George went on to say:
For this simple device of placing all
taxes on the value of land would be in effect putting up
the land at auction to whosoever would pay the highest rent
to the state. The demand for land fixes its value, and
hence, if taxes were placed so as very nearly to consume
that value, the man who wished to hold land without using
it would have to pay very nearly what it would be worth to
anyone who wanted to use it.
And it must be remembered that this
would apply, not merely to agricultural land, but to all
land. Mineral land would be thrown open to use, just as
agricultural land; and in the heart of a city no one could
afford to keep land from its most profitable use, or on the
outskirts to demand more for it than the use to which it
could at the time be put would warrant. Everywhere that
land had attained a value, taxation, instead of operating,
as now, as a fine upon improvement, would operate to force
improvement (1879, rpt. 1958, p. 437).
A few pages before this he had told
us that, "It is sufficiently evident that with regard to
production, the tax upon the value of land is the best tax
that can be imposed. Tax manufactures, and the effect is to
check manufacturing; tax improvements, and the effect is to
lessen improvement; tax commerce, and the effect is to
prevent exchange; tax capital, and the effect is to drive
it away. But the whole value of land may be taken in
taxation, and the only effect will be to stimulate
industry, to open new opportunities to capital, and to
increase the production of wealth" (1879, rpt. 1958, p.
414).
In other words, according to George,
taxation of products checks production, whereas taxation of
land values stimulates production. ... read the
whole article
Karl Williams: Social Justice In Australia:
ADVANCED KIT - Part 2
FREE TRADE OR
PROTECTION?
"That's free enterprise, friends:
freedom to gamble, freedom to lose. And the great thing
-- the truly democratic thing about it -- is that you
don't even have to be a player to lose." - Barbara
Ehrenreich (1941- ), American author and
columnist
Lots of provisos can be added later, but this is
the basic position: we believe in free trade only if it's
fair trade. Today it's is hardly ever fair and it's far
from free, since it is dominated by ruling monopolies in
all the larger economies such as the US, Japan, Germany,
the UK, etc - but it can be.
The great advantages of free trade were never more
eloquently spelt out than by Henry George himself, but
these benefits have been overshadowed and confused by the
way the threatening aspects of globalisation have spread
in recent years. Globalisation has appeared all the more
menacing because of the way the plutocrats who control
transnational organisations have been calling for the
last barriers to free trade to be removed. The trouble
is, they don't give a damn about freedom! Instead of
allowing real free trade, the big boys seek to further
strengthen their monopoly privileges and political
influence in order to produce greater disparities in
wealth.
MANY DISADVANTAGES OF FREE
TRADE
Cultural diversity is one of the things that
undoubtedly makes life more interesting, and its erosion
by unrestrained free trade would be an irretrievable
loss. Who wants McDonald's and other global chain stores
in every shopping centre? This evaluation obviously
requires difficult value judgments to be weighed against
the possible economic benefits. But cultural heritage and
diversity have been grossly undervalued by the bean
counters who ignore it for not having a $ tag
on.
National independence and security can be
threatened by free trade, in that a country can become
too dependent on trading partners to provide essential
goods and services up to basic foodstuffs.
There are often hidden environmental costs to free
trade, especially when goods are transported over vast
distances and exporters are not paying the full costs of
using scarce resources and of polluting the global
commons. Furthermore, recent trade agreements have been
based on environmental standards coming down to the
lowest common denominator when they could just as easily
have been based on the highest.
Perhaps the loudest outcry against free trade and
globalisation has been against the increasing
exploitation by transnationals of "factory fodder" in
developing nations. Even the threat of the physical
transfer of industrial plant to low wage countries
further erodes the bargaining power and wages of workers
in the West.
And transnationals can bully their way and
dominate markets with monopoly or cartel powers, often
playing off nations against each other to extract all
sorts of tax concessions. But, when the time comes to pay
what little tax is owed, transfer pricing allows them to
shift their profits to low-taxing offshore locations.
Furthermore, the rapid movement of capital in and out of
nations exacerbates economic uncertainty and
instability.
BUT DON'T DISCOUNT ECONOMIC
PROSPERITY!
Having made these admissions, we must hasten to
add that free trade has given rise to enormous economic
prosperity. The efficiencies from fully utilising each
nation's natural advantages are evident in any
supermarket or electrical goods store. Self-sufficiency
has enormous costs, keeping people working far longer
than they need to. Those who cry loudest for
protectionist policies are often the most wasteful and
inept domestic producers, who are effectively subsidised
by the public.
But will Geonomics address the current problems of
free trade, and bring about fair trade? Let's examine the
problems one by one.
HOW GEONOMICS FITS
IN
Concerning the erosion of cultural diversity,
Geonomics can help a little. The LVT assessment process
can assist in quantifying the intangible cultural
benefits of, say, retaining a traditional inn rather than
replacing it with a global-franchise motel. In the end
each community, knowing the cultural costs of certain
moves towards free trade, would decide how badly it wants
to preserve its culture and how far to cash in on it
without underselling its cultural heritage.
Geonomics would easily solve the rest of the
problems arising from free trade. The collection of full
resource rentals would prevent any underselling of the
environment. Exploitation of Third World factory fodder
could never continue after addressing the root cause of
unemployment. The way Geonomics opens up a multitude of
domestic investment opportunities in both the public and
private sectors would no longer coerce developing
countries to beg for investment by transnational
monopolies. And transnational tax avoidance would most
clearly end - no one can hide land or evade the tax
assessed on it!
"If Max gets to Heaven he won't
last long. He will be chucked out for trying to pull off
a merger between Heaven and Hell...after having secured a
controlling interest in key subsidiary companies in both
places, of course." - H. G. Wells, (1866-1946),
referring to Lord Beaverbrook.
...
Read the entire
article
Henry George: Justice
the Object -- Taxation the Means (1890)
Bring almost any article of wealth to this country
from a foreign country, and you are confronted at once
with a tax. Is it not from a common sense standpoint a
stupid thing, if we want more wealth — if the
prosperous country is the country that increases in
wealth, why in Heaven's name should we put up a barrier
against the men who want to bring wealth into this
country? We want more dry-goods (if you don't know, your
wives surely will tell you). We want more clothing; more
sugar; more of all sorts of the good things that are
called "goods;" and yet by this system of taxation we
virtually put up a high fence around the country to keep
out these very things. We tax that convenient man who
brings goods into the country.
If wealth be a good thing; if the
country be a prosperous country — that is, increasing
in wealth — well, surely, if we propose to restrict
trade at all, the wise thing would he to put the taxes on
the men who are taking goods out of the country, not upon
those who are bringing goods into the country.
We Single Tax men would sweep away
all these barriers. We would try to keep out small-pox and
cholera and vermin and plagues. But we would welcome all
the goods that anybody wanted to send us, that anybody
wanted to bring home. We say it is stupid, if we want more
wealth, to prevent people from bringing wealth to the
country. We say, also, that it is just as stupid to tax the
men who produce wealth within the country. Read the
entire article
Dan Sullivan: Are you a Real Libertarian, or a
ROYAL Libertarian?
The English free-trader Cobden remarked that "you
who free the land will do more for the people than we who
have freed trade." Indeed, how can anyone speak of free
trade when the trader has to pay tribute to some favored
land-entitlement holder in order to do business?
This imperfect policy of
non-intervention, or laissez-faire, led straight to a
most hideous and dreadful economic exploitation;
starvation wages, slum dwelling, killing hours,
pauperism, coffin-ships, child-labour -- nothing like it
had ever been seen in modern times ... People began to
say, if this is what State abstention comes to, let us
have some State intervention.
But the state had
intervened; that was the whole trouble. The State had
established one monopoly--the landlord's monopoly of
economic rent--thereby shutting off great hordes of
people from free access to the only source of human
subsistence, and driving them into factories to work for
whatever Mr. Gradgrind and Mr. Bottles chose to give
them. The land of England, while by no means nearly
all actually occupied, was
all legallyoccupied; and this
State-created monopoly enabled landlords to satisfy their
needs and desires with little exertion or none, but it
also removed the land from competition with industry in
the labor market, thus creating a huge, constant and
exigent labour-surplus. [Emphasis Nock's] --Albert J.
Nock, "The Gods' Lookout" February 1934
... Read the
whole piece
Bill Batt: The
Compatibility of Georgist Economics and Ecological
Economics
During the late 19th century, the burden of
various direct taxes was not so large that many common
people felt their acute impact. It was, however, a time
of extreme disparities between the poor and the wealthy,
and the single tax was a means by which to redress some
of those disparities. It would also foster the
availability of employment by making labor more
attractive relative to land and capital investment. In a
word, people would more likely have to earn their money.
The fruits of land wealth, distributed among people
equally in the form of government services, would go far
toward both enhancing economic opportunity and correcting
inequality.
Georgists today adhere to much the same points of
view, although there are some significant differences.
George himself was an ardent free
trader, mainly because he believed that the single tax
should supplant tariffs. After Ricardo, he
accepted the idea of comparative advantage that arose
from trade, but only after land (resource) rents were
collected so as to preclude the raping of the natural
environments of countries rich in such resources. He also
believed that population growth was good — the more
the better, and took special pains to refute Malthus. But
one should also recall that he was living at a time when
the expanse of the American continent was still open to
any homesteader who chose to do so. Population growth was
not a problem at that time. These elements of
George’s thought are inconsequential to his
followers today. Yet it is important to
note that Georgists are not socialists; they do not
subscribe to the view that society should own the means
of production. These should remain privately owned by and
large (except perhaps as today’s economic theory
would call for, i.e., natural monopolies, public goods,
and other government instruments). They are, rather,
free-marketers in the full sense of the world, even more
ardently than many contemporary American
conservatives. He believed that removing the
accretion of economic rent from landsites would restore
self-regulating equilibrium of the marketplace, thus
obviating the need for the heavy hand of government
controls. ... read the whole
article
Judge Samuel Seabury: An Address delivered upon the
100th anniversary of the birth of Henry George
WE are met to celebrate the 100th anniversary of the
birth of Henry George. We meet, therefore, in a spirit of
joy and thanksgiving for the great life which he devoted
to the service of humanity. To very few of the children
of men is it given to act the part of a great teacher who
makes an outstanding contribution toward revealing the
basic principles to which human society must adhere if it
is to walk in the way which leads to freedom. This Henry
George did, and in so doing he expressed himself with a
clarity of thought and diction which has rarely been
surpassed.
... The second principle to which I wish to refer is
Henry George's advocacy of freedom of trade among the
nations — not free trade introduced overnight, but
freedom of trade as an end toward which the nations
should move. When he wrote his great work on "Protection
or Free Trade," he demolished the protectionist argument
and in chapter after chapter he showed the absurdities to
which the protectionist principle led if carried to its
logical conclusion. But even he, penetrating as his
vision was, could not foresee that mankind was heading
for a world order of economic nationalism and isolation,
based upon the principle of protection carried to its
utmost extreme. And yet that it is precisely the doctrine
which is now currently accepted. If it becomes general,
it can serve only to sow the seeds of destruction of that
measure of civilization which we now have and force a
lowering of the standard of living throughout the
world.
There are two ways by which the people of one nation
can acquire the property or goods of the people of
another nation. These are by war and by trade. There are
no other methods. The present tendency among civilized
people to outlaw trade must drive the states which
prescribe such outlawry to acquire the property and goods
of other peoples by war. Early in man's struggle for
existence the resort to war was the common method
adopted. With the advancement of civilization men
resorted to trade as a practical substitute for war. The
masses of men wish to trade with one another. The action
of the states alone prevents them from so doing. In
prohibiting trade, the state gives an importance to
territorial boundaries which would not exist if freedom
of trade existed. In accentuating the importance of mere
boundary disputes, rather than assuring the right of
peoples to trade with one another, the nations put the
emphasis upon the precise issue which is, itself, one of
the most prolific causes of war.
All the great modern states are turning away from
freedom of trade, and indeed, from trade itself, and
forbidding their people the right to earn their own
livelihood and to associate freely with one another in
industry. In order to accomplish this end they are
compelled to regiment the lives of their people under
state bureaucracies and this can be accomplished only by
a despotic state. If the powers of the modern states are
to be augmented by conferring upon them the right to run
all industry, despotism is inevitable. A dictator may, by
reducing the standard of living and regimenting the
people, run all industry within the state over which he
rules, but a democracy, which, if it is to be true to
itself, must preserve individual initiative, can not do
so without transforming itself into a dictatorship. ...
read the whole
speech
Henry Ford
Talks About War and Your Future - 1942 interview
Albert Jay Nock — Henry George: Unorthodox
American
George was moreover the terror of the political
routineer. When the Republicans suddenly raised the
tariff issue in 1880 the Democratic committee asked him
to go on the stump. They arranged a long list of
engagements for him, but after he made one speech they
begged him by telegraph not to make any more. The nub of
his speech was that he had heard of high-tariff Democrats
and revenue-tariff Democrats, but he was a no-tariff
Democrat who wanted real free trade, and he was out for
that or nothing; and naturally no good bi-partisan
national committee could put up with such talk as that,
especially from a man who really meant it.
Yet, on the other hand, when the official free-traders
of the Atlantic seaboard, led by Sumner, Godkin, Beecher,
Curtis, Lowell, and Hewitt, opened their arms to George,
he refused to fall in. His free-trade speeches during
Cleveland’s second campaign were really devoted to
showing by implication that they were a hollow lot, and
that their idea of free trade was nothing more or less
than a humbug. His speeches hurt Cleveland more than they
helped him, and some of George’s closest associates
split with him at this point. In George’s view,
freedom of exchange would not benefit the masses of the
people a particle unless it were correlated with freedom
of production; if it would, how was it that the people of
free-trade England, for example, were no better off than
the people of protectionist Germany! None of the official
free-traders could answer that question, of course, for
there was no answer. George had already developed his
full doctrine of trade in a book, published in 1886,
called Protection or Free Trade — a book
which, incidentally, gives a reader the best possible
introduction to Progress and Poverty.
...read the whole
article
|
To share this page with a friend:
right click, choose "send," and add your
comments.
|
|
Red links have not been
visited; .
Green links are pages you've seen
|
Essential Documents pertinent
to this theme:
|
|