Algorithms
Peter Barnes:
Capitalism 3.0 — Chapter 4: The Limits of
Privatization (pages 49-63)
It’s tempting to believe that private owners, by
pursuing their own self-interest, can preserve shared
inheritances. No one likes being told what to do, and
words like statism conjure fears of bureaucracy
at best and tyranny at worst. By contrast,
privatism connotes freedom.
In this chapter, we look at Garrett Hardin’s
second alternative for saving the commons: privatism, or
privatization. I argue that private corporations,
operating in unconstrained markets, can allocate
resources efficiently but can’t preserve them. The
latter task requires setting aside some supplies for
future generations — something neither markets nor
corporations, when left to their own devices, will do.
The reason lies in the algorithms and starting conditions
of our current operating system.
The Algorithms of Capitalism 2.0
If you’ve ever used a computer spreadsheet, you
know what an algorithm is. Each cell in the spreadsheet
contains a set of instructions: take data from other
cells, manipulate the data according to a formula, and
display the result. The instructions within each cell are
algorithms.
If you think of the economy as a huge spreadsheet,
with each cell representing a producer, consumer, or
property owner, you can see that the behavior of the
whole is driven by the algorithms in the cells. Our
current operating system is dominated by three algorithms
and one starting condition. The algorithms are:
(1) maximize return to capital,
(2) distribute property income on a per-share basis,
and
(3) the price of nature equals zero.
The starting condition is that the top 5 percent of the
people own more property shares than the remaining 95
percent.
The first algorithm is what drives corporations. It
tells them to sell as much as they can, pay as little as
possible for labor, resources, and waste disposal, and
make shareholders happy every quarter. It focuses the
minds of managers every day. If they work in marketing,
they wake up thinking about how to sell more; if
there’s no demand for their product, they must
create some. If they work in finance, they worry about
margins and leverage. If they’re in labor
relations, they bargain hard, replace long-term employees
with temps, and shift jobs to places where wages are
lower. All the while, the CEO feeds sweet numbers to Wall
Street.
The second and third algorithms then mesh with the
first. It’s the combination of these algorithms
that causes the wheels of capitalism to devour nature and
widen inequality among humans. At the same time, nothing
in the algorithms requires or encourages corporations,
either individually or collectively, to preserve
anything.
This doesn’t mean people inside corporations
don’t think about protecting nature, raising their
workers’ pay, or giving something back to society.
Often, they do. It does mean their room for actually
doing such things is too narrow to make a difference. Nor
does it mean that, from time to time, some brave
mavericks don’t briefly flout the corporate
algorithm. They do that, too. What I’m saying is
that, in the great majority of cases, the corporate
algorithm and its brethren are obeyed. For all practical
purposes, the publicly traded corporation is a slave to
its algorithm. ...
read the whole chapter
Peter Barnes:
Capitalism 3.0 — Chapter 5: Reinventing the Commons
(pages 65-78)
Thus far I’ve argued that Capitalism 2.0 —
or surplus capitalism — has three tragic flaws: it
devours nature, widens inequality, and fails to make us
happier in the end. It behaves this way because
it’s programmed to do so. It must make thneeds,
reward property owners disproportionately, and distract
us from truer paths to happiness because its algorithms
direct it to do so. Neither enlightened managers nor the
occasional zealous regulator can make it behave much
differently. ...
read the whole chapter
Peter Barnes:
Capitalism 3.0 — Chapter 8: Sharing Culture (pages
117-134)
The larger lesson of this chapter is that all three
branches of the commons — nature, community, and
culture — are under similar assault from
corporations, and all need to be fortified. The means of
fortification will vary with the particular commons. When
commons are scarce or threatened, we ought to limit
aggregate use, assign property rights to trusts, and
charge market prices to users. When commons are limitless
(like culture, the Internet, and potentially the
airwaves), our challenge is the opposite: to provide the
greatest benefit to the greatest number at the lowest
cost. To create scarcity where it doesn’t need to
exist diminishes rather than enlarges our well-being.
In both limited and unlimited commons, corporate and
commons algorithms clash. In limited commons, the
corporate algorithm says: use as much as you can as
quickly as you can, because if you don’t, someone
else will. The commons algorithm, by contrast, says:
preserve the asset for future generations, enhance it
whenever possible, and live off income rather than
principal. In unlimited commons, the corporate algorithm
says: restrict use and charge what the market will bear.
The commons algorithm, by contrast, says: the more users
the merrier, and the cheaper the better. In both
situations, the commons algorithm conflicts head-on with
the corporate one, and that’s just fine. Indeed,
it’s precisely the point.
Commons algorithms need to be unleashed in real-time
markets, where they can duke it out with their corporate
counterparts. Managers in each sector will know what to
do, and the public will know what to expect. If
corporations keep winning, then add more property to the
commons. Eventually, we’ll get the best of both
worlds, and when there’s conflict, more balanced
outcomes than we get today. We’ll also gain clarity
about the real costs of current practices.
After we fortify, we should enhance; just as we take
from the commons, so should we give back. Art and music
can be reproduced by corporations, but they don’t
come from corporations; they come from the commons. Folk
music, country music, jazz, blues, garage bands —
these are the roots of our musical heritage. We must
nourish the soil in which these roots grow. This, not
copyright extension, is the way to enrich culture. ...
read the whole chapter
|
To share this page with a friend:
right click, choose "send," and add your
comments.
|
|
Red links have not been
visited; .
Green links are pages you've seen
|
Essential Documents pertinent
to this theme:
essential_documents
|
|