Widows' Skirts, Orphans and Family
Farmers
Widows' skirts are something like the Family Farmer
whose farm is lost to the estate tax. (See David Cay
Johnston's book, Perfectly Legal: The Covert Campaign
to Rig Our Tax System to Benefit the Super Rich —
and Cheat Everybody Else, chapter 6.) But Winston
Churchill speaks of the Market Farmer outside Glasgow
much the same way, and implores that we let the widow
rest! (See below.)
The Bible, like most other ethical systems, calls for
us to take care of widows and orphans. But a lot of
things get justified as protections for widows and
orphans which largely serve much larger special
interests. California's Proposition 13 is a contemporary
example.
We don't worry nearly as much about the rack-rented
tenant as we do about the person who claims they will not
be able to afford their property taxes, while the latter
has a huge asset to sell to the next generation, at
prices that will keep them wage slaves for years. What a
system!
The alternative, of course, is to acknowledge that
land is different from houses, that while buildings
shouldn't be taxed at all, land value should be, and
should be taxed rather heavily. Doing so will reduce the
price of land, making it affordable to those who
need it (but they won't buy more than they need for
themselves, or speculate on it) and will put it to good
use, either for housing or for commercial pursuits.
Henry George: The Land Question
(1881)
It is that peasant proprietors would strengthen
the existing system that makes schemes for creating them
so popular among certain sections of the propertied
classes of Great Britain. This is the ground on which
these schemes are largely urged. These small landowners
are desired that they may be used as a buffer and bulwark
against any questioning of the claims of the larger
owners. They would be put forward to resist the shock of
"agrarianism," just as the women are put forward in
resistance to the process-servers. "What! do you propose
to rob these poor peasants of their little homesteads?"
would be the answer to any one who proposed to attack the
system under which the larger landholders draw millions
annually from the produce of labor. ... read
the whole article
Henry George: In
Liverpool: The Financial Reform Meeting at the Liverpool
Rotunda (1889)
That is what we strive for — for the freedom of
all, for self-government to all (hear, hear) — and
for as little government as possible: (Laughter and
cheers) We don't believe that tyranny is a thing alone of
kings and monarchs; we know well that majorities can be
as tyrannous as aristocracies (hear, hear); we know that
mobs can persecute as well as crowned heads. (Hear, hear)
What we ask for is freedom — that in each locality,
large or small, the people of that locality shall be free
to manage the affairs that pertain only to that locality
(hear, hear, and cheers); that each individual shall be
free to manage the affairs that relate to him; that
government shall not presume to say of whom he shall buy
or to whom he shall sell, shall not attempt to dictate to
him in any way, but shall confine itself to its proper
function of preserving the public peace, of preventing
the strong from oppressing the weak, of utilizing for the
public good all the revenues that belong of right to the
public, and of managing those affairs that are best
managed by the whole. (Cheers) Our doctrine is the
doctrine of freedom, our gospel is the gospel of liberty,
and we have faith in it, why should we not? (Cheers)
The Old Argument
The People who say that such terrible things would
follow the institution of the single tax are simply like
the people who had predicted terrible things to follow
the building of railroads and the abolition of chattel
slavery. Why I remember, and Mr. Garrison well remembers,
the day when in the United States all the arguments that
are used in this country against the single tax were used
against the abolition of chattel slavery, even down to
the "poor widow argument."
We used to be told — I was only a boy then
— we used to be told, when William Lloyd Garrison,
father of this man, was the best denounced man on two
continents, that it might be well if we could find the
people who originally brought these slaves from Africa,
to make them give them up. "But," it was urged, "these
negroes are owned by people who paid their money for
them. (Laughter) Would you take away from a man without
any compensation the property that he bought?" (Laughter)
Then we used to be told, as you are told now, about that
hard working mechanic. "Here is a hard working laboring
man. He has toiled early and late, and he has bought a
slave to help him. Are you going to take a man's slave
without compensation and rob him of the products of his
labor?" (Laughter) So they say today of the English
mechanic, or English laborer, who has bought himself a
little bit of land. And then we used to be told: "Here is
a man who worked hard and saved his money, and he
invested in half-a-dozen slaves. He died, and those
slaves are the only means of subsistence the widow has to
support his orphan children. Would you emancipate those
slaves, and let that poor widow and those little orphans
starve to death?" (Laughter)
Slavery and Slavery
It is the old, old story! And no wonder, for property
in land is just as absurd! just as monstrous as property
in human beings. (Hear, hear, and cheers) What difference
does it make whether you enslave a man by making his
flesh and blood the property of another, or whether you
enslave him by making the property of another that
element on which and from which he must live if he is to
live at all? (A voice: "None whatever!" and cheers)
Why, in those old days slave ships used to set out
from this town of Liverpool for the coast of Africa to
buy slaves. They did not bring them to Liverpool; they
took them over to America. Why? Because you people were
so good, and the Englishmen who had got to the other side
of the Atlantic, and had settled there, were so bad? Not
at all. I will tell you why the Liverpool ships carried
slaves to America and did not bring them back to England.
Because in America population was sparse and land was
plentiful. Therefore to rob a man of his labor —
and that is what the slaveowner wanted the slave for
— you had got to catch and hold the man. That is
the reason the slaves went to America. The reason they
did not come here, the reason they were not carried over
to Ireland was that here population was relatively dense,
land was relatively scarce and could easily be
monopolized, and to get out of the laborer all that his
labor could furnish, save only wages enough to keep him
alive even the slaveowner had to give this — it was
only necessary to own land.
What is the difference, economically speaking, between
the slaves of South Carolina, Missouri, Mississippi, and
Georgia and the free peasantry of Ireland or the
agricultural laborer of England? (Cheers) Go to one of
those slave states in the slave days, and there you would
find a planter, the owner of five hundred slaves, living
in elegant luxury, without doing a stroke of work, having
a fine mansion, horses, [and a] carriage — all the
things that work produces, but doing none of it himself.
The people who did the work were living in negro huts, on
coarse food; they were clothed in coarse raiment. If they
ran away, he had the privilege of chasing them back,
tying them up and whipping them and making them work.
Come to this side of the Atlantic, in a place where
you saw the same state of development. There you found
also five hundred people living in little cabins, eating
coarse food, clothed in coarse raiment, working hard, yet
getting only enough of the things that work produces to
keep them in good times, when bad times came having to
appeal to the world for charity. But you found among
those little cabins, too, the lordly mansion of the man
who did no work. (Hear, hear, and groans)
You found the mansion; you did not often find the man.
(Laughter and cheers) As a general rule he was off in
London, or in Paris, enjoying himself on the fruits of
their labor. (Hear, hear) He had no legal right to make
them work for him. Oh! no. If they ran away he could not
put bloodhounds on their track and bring them back and
whip them; but he had, in hunger, in starvation, a ban
dog40 more swift, more keen, more sure than the
bloodhound of the south. (Cheers)
The slaveowner of the south — the owner of men
— had to make those men work for him. He went to
all that trouble. The landlord of Ireland did not have to
make men work for him. He owned the land, and without
land men cannot work; and so men would come to him
— equal children of the Creator, equal citizens of
Great Britain — would come to him, with their hats
in their hands, and beg to be allowed to live on his
land, to be allowed to work and to give to him all the
produce of their work, except enough to merely keep them
alive, and thank him for the privilege. . . . read the whole speech
Winston Churchill: Land Price as a Cause of
Poverty (1909 speech in Parliament)
... I do not think the Leader of the Opposition
could have chosen a more unfortunate example than
Glasgow. He said that the demand of that great community
for land was for not more than forty acres a year. Is
that the only demand of the people of Glasgow for land?
Does that really represent the complete economic and
natural demand for the amount of land a population of
that size requires to live on? I will admit that at
present prices it may be all that they can afford to
purchase in the course of a year. But there are one
hundred and twenty thousand persons in Glasgow who are
living in one-room tenements; and we are told that the
utmost land those people can absorb economically and
naturally is forty acres a year.
What is the explanation? Because the
population is congested in the city the price of land is
high upon the suburbs, and because the price of land is
high upon the suburbs the population must remain congested
within the city. That is the position which we are
complacently assured is in accordance with the principles
which have hitherto dominated civilised
society.
But when we seek to rectify this
system, to break down this unnatural and vicious circle, to
interrupt this sequence of unsatisfactory reactions, what
happens? We are not confronted with any great argument on
behalf of the owner. Something else is put forward, and it
is always put forward in these cases to shield the actual
landowner or the actual capitalist from the logic of the
argument or from the force of a Parliamentary
movement.
Sometimes it is the
widow. But that personality has been used to
exhaustion. It would be sweating in the cruellest sense of
the word, overtime of the grossest description, to bring
the widow out again so soon. She must have a rest for a
bit; so instead of the widow we have the
market-gardener -- the market-gardener liable to be
disturbed on the outskirts of great cities, if the
population of those cities expands, if the area which they
require for their health and daily life should become
larger than it is at present.
What is the position disclosed by the argument? On
the one hand, we have one hundred and twenty thousand
persons in Glasgow occupying one-room tenements; on the
other, the land of Scotland. Between the two stands the
market-gardener, and we are solemnly invited, for the
sake of the market-gardener, to keep that great
population congested within limits that are unnatural and
restricted to an annual supply of land which can bear no
relation whatever to their physical, social, and economic
needs -- and all for the sake of the market-gardener, who
can perfectly well move farther out as the city spreads
and who would not really be in the least injured.
... Read the
whole piece
Charles B. Fillebrown: A Catechism of Natural
Taxation, from Principles of Natural Taxation
(1917)
Q50. How could the landowner escape the alleged
burden of an increase in his land tax?
A. Simply by assuming the legitimate role of a model
landlord, by putting his land to suitable use, in
providing for tenants at lowest possible price the best
accommodations and facilities appropriate to the
situation that money can buy.
... read
the whole article
Upton Sinclair: The
Consequences of Land Speculation are Tenantry and Debt on
the Farms, and Slums and Luxury in the Cities
I know of a woman — I have never had the
pleasure of making her acquaintance, because she lives in
a lunatic asylum, which does not happen to be on my
visiting list. This woman has been mentally incompetent
from birth. She is well taken care of, because her father
left her when he died the income of a large farm on the
outskirts of a city. The city has since grown and the
land is now worth, at conservative estimate, about twenty
million dollars. It is covered with office buildings, and
the greater part of the income, which cannot be spent by
the woman, is piling up at compound interest. The woman
enjoys good health, so she may be worth a hundred million
dollars before she dies.
I choose this case because it is one about which there
can be no disputing; this woman has never been able to do
anything to earn that twenty million dollars. And if a
visitor from Mars should come down to study the
situation, which would he think was most insane, the
unfortunate woman, or the society which compels thousands
of people to wear themselves to death in order to pay her
the income of twenty million dollars?
The fact that this woman is insane makes it easy to
see that she is not entitled to the "unearned increment"
of the land she owns. But how about all the other people
who have bought up and are holding for speculation the
most desirable land? The value of this land increases,
not because of anything these owners do — not
because of any useful service they render to the
community — but purely because the community as a
whole is crowding into that neighborhood and must have
use of the land.
The speculator who bought this land thinks that he
deserves the increase, because he guessed the fact that
the city was going to grow that way. But it seems clear
enough that his skill in guessing which way the community
was going to grow, however useful that skill may be to
himself, is not in any way useful to the community. The
man may have planted trees, or built roads, and put in
sidewalks and sewers; all that is useful work, and for
that he should be paid. But should he be paid for
guessing what the rest of us were going to need?
Before you answer, consider the consequences
of this guessing game. The consequences of land
speculation are tenantry and debt on the farms, and slums
and luxury in the cities. A great part of the
necessary land is held out of use, and so the value of
all land continually increases, until the poor man can no
longer own a home. The value of farm land also increases;
so year by year more independent farmers are
dispossessed, because they cannot pay interest on their
mortgages. So the land becomes a place of
serfdom, that land described by the poet, "where wealth
accumulates and men decay." The great cities fill up with
festering slums, and a small class of idle parasites are
provided with enormous fortunes, which they do not have
to earn, and which they cannot intelligently
spend.
This condition wrecked every empire in the history of
mankind, and it is wrecking modern civilization. One of
the first to perceive this was Henry George, and he
worked out the program known as the Single Tax. Let
society as a whole take the full rental value of land, so
that no one would any longer be able to hold land out of
use. So the value of land would decrease, and everyone
could have land, and the community would have a great
income to be spent for social ends. ...
In Philadelphia, as in all our great cities,
are enormously wealthy families, living on hereditary
incomes derived from crowded slums. Here and
there among these rich men is one who realizes that he
has not earned what he is consuming, and that it has not
brought him happiness, and is bringing still less to his
children. Such men are casting about for ways to invest
their money without breeding idleness and parasitism.
Some of them might be grateful to learn about this
enclave plan, and to visit the lovely village of Arden,
and see what its people are doing to make possible a
peaceful and joyous life, even in this land of
bootleggers and jazz orchestras. read the whole
article
Henry George: The Condition of Labor
— An Open Letter to Pope Leo XIII in response to
Rerum Novarum (1891)
Thus, that any species of property is permitted by the
state does not of itself give it moral sanction. The
state has often made things property that are not justly
property, but involve violence and robbery. For instance,
the things of religion, the dignity and authority of
offices of the church, the power of administering her
sacraments and controlling her temporalities, have often
by profligate princes been given as salable property to
courtiers and concubines. At this very day in England an
atheist or a heathen may buy in open market, and hold as
legal property, to be sold, given or bequeathed as he
pleases, the power of appointing to the cure of souls,
and the value of these legal rights of presentation is
said to be no less than £17,000,000.
Or again: Slaves were universally treated as property
by the customs and laws of the classical nations, and
were so acknowledged in Europe long after the acceptance
of Christianity. At the beginning of this century there
was no Christian nation that did not, in her colonies at
least, recognize property in slaves, and slaveships
crossed the seas under Christian flags. In the United
States, little more than thirty years ago, to buy a man
gave the same legal ownership as to buy a horse, and in
Mohammedan countries law and custom yet make the slave
the property of his captor or purchaser.
Yet your Holiness, one of the glories of whose
pontificate is the attempt to break up slavery in its
last strongholds, will not contend that the moral
sanction that attaches to property in things produced by
labor can, or ever could, apply to property in
slaves.
Your use, in so many passages of your Encyclical, of
the inclusive term “property” or
“private” property, of which in morals
nothing can be either affirmed or denied, makes your
meaning, if we take isolated sentences, in many places
ambiguous. But reading it as a whole, there can be no
doubt of your intention that private property in land
shall be understood when you speak merely of private
property. With this interpretation, I find that the
reasons you urge for private property in land are eight.
Let us consider them in order of presentation. You
urge:
1. That what is bought with rightful property is
rightful property. (RN, paragraph 5) ...
2. That private property in land proceeds from
man’s gift of reason. (RN, paragraphs 6-7.)
...
3. That private property in land deprives no one of the
use of land. (RN, paragraph 8.) ...
4. That Industry expended on land gives ownership in the
land itself. (RN, paragraphs 9-10.) ...
5. That private property in land has the support of the
common opinion of mankind, and has conduced to peace and
tranquillity, and that it is sanctioned by Divine Law.
(RN, paragraph 11.) ...
6. That fathers should provide for their children and
that private property in land is necessary to enable them
to do so. (RN, paragraphs 14-17.) ...
7. That the private ownership of land stimulates
industry, increases wealth, and attaches men to the soil
and to their country. (RN, paragraph 51.) ...
8. That the right to possess private property in land is
from nature, not from man; that the state has no right to
abolish it, and that to take the value of landownership
in taxation would be unjust and cruel to the private
owner. (RN, paragraph 51.)
1. That what is bought with rightful property
is rightful property. (5.)*
Clearly, purchase and sale cannot give, but can only
transfer ownership. Property that in itself has no moral
sanction does not obtain moral sanction by passing from
seller to buyer.
If right reason does not make the slave the property
of the slave-hunter it does not make him the property of
the slave-buyer. Yet your reasoning as to private
property in land would as well justify property in
slaves. To show this it is only needful to change in your
argument the word land to the word slave. It would then
read:
It is surely undeniable that, when a man engages in
remunerative labor, the very reason and motive of his
work is to obtain property, and to hold it as his own
private possession.
If one man hires out to another his strength or his
industry, he does this for the purpose of receiving in
return what is necessary for food and living; he thereby
expressly proposes to acquire a full and legal right, not
only to the remuneration, but also to the disposal of
that remuneration as he pleases.
Thus, if he lives sparingly, saves money, and invests
his savings, for greater security, in a slave, the slave
in such a case is only his wages in another form; and
consequently, a working-man’s slave thus purchased
should be as completely at his own disposal as the wages
he receives for his labor.
Nor in turning your argument for private property in
land into an argument for private property in men am I
doing a new thing. In my own country, in my own time,
this very argument, that purchase gave ownership, was the
common defense of slavery. It was made by statesmen, by
jurists, by clergymen, by bishops; it was accepted over
the whole country by the great mass of the people. By it
was justified the separation of wives from husbands, of
children from parents, the compelling of labor, the
appropriation of its fruits, the buying and selling of
Christians by Christians. In language almost identical
with yours it was asked, “Here is a poor man who
has worked hard, lived sparingly, and invested his
savings in a few slaves. Would you rob him of his
earnings by liberating those slaves?” Or it was
said: “Here is a poor widow; all her husband has
been able to leave her is a few negroes, the earnings of
his hard toil. Would you rob the widow and the orphan by
freeing these negroes?” And because of this
perversion of reason, this confounding of unjust property
rights with just property rights, this acceptance of
man’s law as though it were God’s law, there
came on our nation a judgment of fire and blood.
The error of our people in thinking that what in
itself was not rightfully property could become rightful
property by purchase and sale is the same error into
which your Holiness falls. It is not merely formally the
same; it is essentially the same. Private property in
land, no less than private property in slaves, is a
violation of the true rights of property. They are
different forms of the same robbery; twin devices by
which the perverted ingenuity of man has sought to enable
the strong and the cunning to escape God’s
requirement of labor by forcing it on others.
What difference does it make whether I merely own the
land on which another man must live or own the man
himself? Am I not in the one case as much his master as
in the other? Can I not compel him to work for me? Can I
not take to myself as much of the fruits of his labor; as
fully dictate his actions? Have I not over him the power
of life and death?
For to deprive a man of land is as certainly to kill
him as to deprive him of blood by opening his veins, or
of air by tightening a halter around his neck.
The essence of slavery is in empowering one man to
obtain the labor of another without recompense. Private
property in land does this as fully as chattel slavery.
The slave-owner must leave to the slave enough of his
earnings to enable him to live. Are there not in
so-called free countries great bodies of working-men who
get no more? How much more of the fruits of their toil do
the agricultural laborers of Italy and England get than
did the slaves of our Southern States? Did not private
property in land permit the landowner of Europe in ruder
times to demand the jus primae noctis? Does not the same
last outrage exist today in diffused form in the
immorality born of monstrous wealth on the one hand and
ghastly poverty on the other?
In what did the slavery of Russia consist but in
giving to the master land on which the serf was forced to
live? When an Ivan or a Catherine enriched their
favorites with the labor of others they did not give men,
they gave land. And when the appropriation of land has
gone so far that no free land remains to which the
landless man may turn, then without further violence the
more insidious form of labor robbery involved in private
property in land takes the place of chattel slavery,
because more economical and convenient. For under it the
slave does not have to be caught or held, or to be fed
when not needed. He comes of himself, begging the
privilege of serving, and when no longer wanted can be
discharged. The lash is unnecessary; hunger is as
efficacious. This is why the Norman conquerors of England
and the English conquerors of Ireland did not divide up
the people, but divided the land. This is why European
slave-ships took their cargoes to the New World, not to
Europe.
Slavery is not yet abolished. Though in all Christian
countries its ruder form has now gone, it still exists in
the heart of our civilization in more insidious form, and
is increasing. There is work to be done for the glory of
God and the liberty of man by other soldiers of the cross
than those warrior monks whom, with the blessing of your
Holiness, Cardinal Lavigerie is sending into the Sahara.
Yet, your Encyclical employs in defense of one form of
slavery the same fallacies that the apologists for
chattel slavery used in defense of the other!
The Arabs are not wanting in acumen. Your Encyclical
reaches far. What shall your warrior monks say, if when
at the muzzle of their rifles they demand of some Arab
slave-merchant his miserable caravan, he shall declare
that he bought them with his savings, and producing a
copy of your Encyclical, shall prove by your reasoning
that his slaves are consequently “only his wages in
another form,” and ask if they who bear your
blessing and own your authority propose to “deprive
him of the liberty of disposing of his wages and thus of
all hope and possibility of increasing his stock and
bettering his condition in life”? ... read the whole
letter
Mason Gaffney: The
Taxable Capacity of Land
Making the property tax more progressive
is not just equitable, it raises its revenue capacity.
That is because visible damage to the poor and marginal
puts a cap on any tax. You can't squeeze blood out of a
turnip, and if you try you'll look like the Sheriff of
Nottingham. A land tax won't drive the poor from
their humble huts, because it exempts the huts, and the
sites have low tax valuations. It may tax a few off
valuable land, if their poor huts are there and they
own the land. However, if they own such land, are they
really poor?
They may be "land-poor:" a few
folks always are. They have non-cash assets, but are
illiquid. "Illiquid" may be just a euphemism for "holding
out for more" -- there is always a market at a price.
Even so their plight, genuine or affected, traditionally
evokes sympathy and support. We must address
it.
California, although backward in many
ways, has addressed it effectively. In our special
improvement districts (SIDs), State law allows the
SID to contract with the landowner as
follows.You don't have to pay your annual charge
in cash. If you choose not to, we take an equity in
your property, charging a modest rate of interest. Our
equity accumulates over time. When you die, we sell the
property and take our share; your estate gets the rest.
Should our equity reach 100% during your lifetime, you
stay there for the duration, tax free.
Objectively, it looks like a
good deal for the taxpayer. They can't come out behind,
even if they die soon; if they live long, they come out
ahead. The instructive result is that
very few people take this apparently advantageous
option. UCLA's Donald Shoup has published several
works on the program. One way or another, they manage to
pay on time. Perhaps it attracts the attention of
potential heirs, in a compelling way, but somehow the
cash comes forth. While intending only
to relieve distress, the program seems to have called a
great bluff. The lachrymose plea of the cash-poor widow
is unanswerable in debate, without appearing callous,
doctrinaire, and jackbooted. Meantime wealthy interests,
thoroughly undistressed, hide behind the widow's skirt
and get their way.
We also hear, sometimes, that "it's never
been done," or it's only been done by our drab neighbor
Pennsylvania, for whom familiarity may have bred
contempt? Only "far kine have long horns." Or, whatever
progress ensued there was happening anyway. We are
destiny's tots in the grip of cosmic forces. We rise
and fall with the tide. We cannot control Fate; relax
and accept what the gods dish out. Fatalism: it's a
sure recipe for milling around ineffectually while life
passes us by. ...
Read
the whole
article
Mason Gaffney: Unearned increments and
reality in California's recall election
California homeowners are wallowing in unearned
increments beyond the dreams of avarice, while its
governments are courting bankruptcy. Warren Buffett dared
point this out, and overnight changed from the Oracle of
Omaha into the Numbskull of Nebraska because he does not
understand the "reality of California politics," the
oxymoron du jour.
Most candidates for Governor fled
like startled deer. Buffett's sponsor,
well-tailored Mr. Muscles, recalled meeting a tearful widow
who said she would have been taxed out of her home were it
not for Prop 13. Poor thing, her home had risen in value.
No one asked her name, or whether she knew what she was
talking about, or had her claims audited - being a tearful
widow "on a fixed income" insulates one from reality
checks. The press chimed in with pix of poster
oldsters, gazing from their multi-million dollar perches
over the blue Pacific, fretting about Buffett's solecism
and its possible effect on them, never mind anyone
else.
Fact is, unearned increments ARE income, at the
time they accrue. Illiquid? They are
better than cash income because you can turn them into
cash by borrowing on them, and pay no income tax on the
cash. If you have trouble with that, the tax man himself
will arrange it for you by placing a tax lien on your
appreciated home, rather than foreclose and evict you.
This helps explain why we never
actually see one of these evicted widows suffering from
unearned increments -- they are maudlin figments for
mythmakers. The evictees we do see are renters who
couldn't pay, and had no equity to mortgage. Who cries
for them? ...
Governor Gray Davis, supposedly fighting to close
a deficit, chimed in endorsing Prop 13, citing the
mythical widow again to explain why non-residential
property, about 2/3 of the tax base, should enjoy low
rates. Faced with a negative poll, he backed right down
from his "land tax on wheels," the higher vehicle
registration fee.
- No one has said a word about a severance tax
on oil and gas, although California is the only major
producing state without one.
- No one has crusaded for a severance tax on
water withdrawals, although it would solve both our
revenue and water crises in one stroke.
- No one has said word one about taxing the
taboo lands used for golfing, timber, or farming.
...
Only Cruz Bustamante has proposed
any specifics. He would begin dismantling Prop 13 --
still not menacing the mythical widow -- by raising
assessments on industrial/commercial property. A
whispering campaign right off has it that Bustamante is
leading an Hispanic conspiracy to take over the southwest
and turn "white, European" Americans into a minority to
kick around. We observe mixed marriages on every hand,
and Spain is still European, but this is California,
where "reality" means mythology. May Warren Buffett
continue to get in our faces with facts.
... Read
the whole article
Jeff Smith: Subsidies at Their Worst:
Privileges
Money is the mother's milk of politics. Yet the
milk invested by lobbyists and those they represent is a
drop in the bucket compared to the flow they get back
from the public tit, thanks to the milkmaid state.
Politicians grant well-connected big
businesses: a. direct
cash outlays, such as cash to corporations for
advertising overseas,
b. lucrative contracts, such
as with weaponeers et al campaign contributors,
and
c. tax breaks that burden
would-be competitors, such as tariffs that protect GM
and Ford but not autoworkers. Even if we were to abolish
subsidies (a) and taxes, eliminating the advantage of tax
breaks (c), and negotiate responsible contracts (b),
that'd still leave in place
d. seven subtle privileges,
mere pieces of paper that government grants its customers
at nowhere near market value, positioning the privileged
to claim all the surplus value of society.
1. The corporate charter's salient feature is to
limit the liability of those choosing to profit by
putting others at risk. ...
2. Pollution permits, performance waivers,
land use exemptions -- whether granted by
bureaucracies, legislatures, or courts - are worth much
more than however much government charges and business
pays. ...
3. Patents protect the basement inventor,
right? Wrong. ...
4. Utility franchises create monopolies in
exchange for some public service, such as providing
electricity, phone communication, etc. ...
5. Communication licenses for TV, radio, cell
phones, and the like are given away for free or for far
less than market value, turning recipients into
"instant billionaires" (the business press gleefully
notes). ...
6. Resource leases for public oil, minerals,
forests, and grazing land, are often let at "fire-sale"
prices. ...
7. Land titles do protect
the average homeowners but because they cost virtually
nothing (a paltry filing fee often about $2.00), they
also protect enormously wealthy absentee landlords.
...
Land titles are the granddaddy of all
privileges. Historically, titles preceded all others and
created a class of elite owners with the power to win the
six other indirect subsidies, along with the more direct
ones – grants, contracts, and tax favors. To undo and
reverse this history, it's necessary to collect and share
the natural rents from all seven inconspicuous
privileges.
For these pieces of paper, government
should charge full market value.
...
Getting a
Citizens Dividend would not only eliminate poverty, it'd also erase any
rationale for subsidies - direct or indirect - to the poor
or to the privileged. Repealing the free ride of
privileges would be like repealing capitalism. Without
those subtle detours imposed upon public revenue, owners
would have to work to amass a fortune, and work is one of
the worst ways known to strike it rich.
What you can do: Dry up the milkmaid
state. Dispense with the notion that the state must meddle
in enterprise. Dispense the notion from others, too. Focus
government on its lone raison d'etre - defend rights.
Demand your right to a fair share of natural revenue.
...
Read the whole
article
Michael Hudson and Kris Feder: Real Estate and the
Capital Gains Debate
Wealthy investors have won
congressional support for real estate exemptions in large
part by mobilizing the economic ambitions of homeowners.
Most families’ major asset, after all, is their
home. Two Federal Reserve studies trace the rise in gross
house value from 26 percent of household wealth in 1962
to 30.1 percent in 1983 (falling back to 28.5 percent in
1989). Household real estate assets
substantially exceeded holdings of stocks, bonds and
trust funds (20.5 percent in 1989), liquid assets (17
percent) and total debt (14 percent). The giveaway to
real estate interests is thus presented ostensibly as a
popular middle class measure. The real estate industry
(and the financial sector riding on its shoulders) have
found that the middle classes are willing to cut taxes on
the wealthy considerably, as long as their own taxes are
cut even lightly. It is no surprise that President
Clinton’s first major concession to the pressure
for cutting capital gains taxation is directed at
homeowners, despite the fact that preferences for home
ownership cannot be justified as a boost to
entrepreneurial investment. Such is the foreshortened
economic perspective of our times. Read
the whole article
Henry George:
Concentrations of Wealth Harm America
(excerpt from Social
Problems)
(1883)
This element of monopoly, of appropriation and
spoliation will, when we come to analyze them, be found
largely to account for all great fortunes....
Take the great Vanderbilt fortune. The
first Vanderbilt was a boatman who earned money by hard
work and saved it. But it was not working and saving that
enabled him to leave such an enormous fortune. It was
spoliation and monopoly. As soon as he got money enough he
used it as a club to extort from others their earnings. He
ran off opposition lines and monopolized routes of
steamboat travel. Then he went into railroads, pursuing the
same tactics. The Vanderbilt fortune no
more comes from working and saving than did the fortune
that Captain Kidd buried.
Or take the great Gould fortune. Mr.
Gould might have got his first little start by superior
industry and superior self-denial. But it is not that which
has made him the master of a hundred millions. It was by
wrecking railroads, buying judges, corrupting legislatures,
getting up rings and pools and combinations to raise or
depress stock values and transportation rates.
So, like wise, of the great fortunes
which the Pacific railroads have created. They have been
made by lobbying through profligate donations of lands,
bonds and subsidies, by the operations of Credit Mobilier
and Contract and Finance Companies, by monopolizing and
gouging. And so of fortunes made by such combinations as
the Standard Oil Company, the Bessemer Steel Ring, the
Whisky Tax Ring, the Lucifer Match Ring, and the various
rings for the "protection of the American
workman from the pauper labor of
Europe."
Or take the fortunes made out of
successful patents. Like that element in so many fortunes
that comes from the increased value of land, these result
from monopoly, pure and simple. And though I am not now
discussing the expediency of patent laws, it may be observed, in passing, that in the vast
majority of cases the men who make fortunes out of patents
are not the men who make the inventions.
Through all great fortunes, and, in
fact, through nearly all acquisitions that in these days
can fairly be termed fortunes, these elements of monopoly,
of spoliation, of gambling run. The head of one of the
largest manufacturing firms in the United States said to me
recently, "It is not on our ordinary business that we make
our money; it is where we can get a monopoly." And this, I
think, is generally true.
...
Read the entire
article
Mason Gaffney: The
Partiality of Indexing Capital Gains
Tantamount to
ignoring land is minimizing its weight. Thus one may
acknowledge it indulgently, while actually dismissing it.
In fact, though, land comprises some half the assessed
value of taxable real estate in California, and is not
dismissable. Half the assessed value means more than half
the market value because of assessment discrimination
favoring land. A raft of studies of assessment
discrimination, like the sales/assessment ratio studies of
the U.S. Census, show consistent patterns of discrimination
favoring land. In addition to ordinary assessment
discrimination there is much legislated underassessment,
for land in forest, farm, country club, and other favored
uses.
[An interesting recent case involves Charles H.
Keating, Jr. of Arizona. He and Kemper Marley posed as
farmers to secure "millions of dollars in agricultural
tax breaks on land they planned to develop." The breaks
result from lower assessed land values for "farmers."
[Steve Yozwiak, "Land-tax bill OK reached," The
Arizona Republic, 13 April 89.] ... read the
whole article
Mason Gaffney: Full Employment,
Growth And Progress On A Small Planet: Relieving Poverty
While Healing The Earth
George spoke for the landless,
the tenants, the young, the upwardly mobile, orphans with
nothing to inherit (as opposed to the mythical orphans
who own all the property in the country), the students
and trainees, the exploited workers, the innovators and
entrepreneurs and adventurers who turn their capital and
turn the wheels of capitalism – not so much for
stolid settled burghers and retirees who own land.
Their buildings, yes, he would exempt. But if those buildings rest on land of high social
utility, they are playing the role of land
speculators. Call them Type #3 speculators: the
“passive-aggressive” type. ...
It is not that George or his allies
are against homeownership. Georgist tax
reform makes it easier for first-time buyers to enter the
market, and tends to raise the number of
owner-occupants. However that sometimes entails
inducing Type #3 speculators, melded in among existing
homeowners, to let go of excess land they do not need. That
basic point gets lost when campaigners pitch their message
solely to existing homeowners, lumping them all as a
class.
Folklore and commercial drama make
sympathetic figures of Type #3 speculators.
Environmentalists cozy up to landed gentry as soon as these
set aside some land for wildlife, and abate the bloodlust
of their foxhunting. The challenge for educators and
economists is to explain that their role in the land market
can be just as anti-social as those who are more
transparently aggressive and greedy. It is a mighty
challenge, I allow; but it is what’s out there, and
we must face it, or settle for tokenism that absorbs our
lives and resources while papering over the major
issues.... read the whole article Mason
Gaffney: Land as a
Distinctive Factor of Production
... The dominance of "fusers" is shown by the
prevalence of 2-factor models, wherein the world is
divided into just labor and capital.3 Land is melded with
capital, and simply disappears as a separate category,
along with its distinctive attributes. A number of
economists don't buy it, but don't do anything about it -
acquiescing in error by silence, indifference, passivity,
or anxiety of the professional consequences. They
handle the question by "going into denial," as it were,
resolving a vexing issue by pretending it isn't there.
Anything else spoils the web of interpretation through
which their art seeks to make human experience
intelligible. Truth will not be made manifest by
donning blinders or hedging, especially against such
motivated forces as have an interest in hiding unearned
wealth behind the skirts of capital. ...
Land is not convertible into
other land.
Each unit of land is permanently unique.
Capital, on the other hand, is a homogeneous "pool" over
time: as each unit degrades and yields back its
substance, the owner may reinvest the Capital Consumption
Allowances in anything. Thus, capital is fungible:
one specific item of capital is universally convertible
into any other. Land is not at all fungible: no
specific unit of land is convertible into any
other.
J.B. Clark, as is well known, tried to wipe out
this distinction, which brought him into debate with
Boehm-Bawerk over whether capital has a "period of
production". Frank Knight, following Clark, renewed
the debate with Friedrich von Hayek. The intent of both Clark and Knight was to shelter
land behind the skirts of capital, to counter a popular
movement for taxing land more and capital less.
Students are still required to study these dreary,
mystical exchanges, which seem to have no other
purpose.
The rate of turnover of capital may vary, and
does, over a wide range, from once a day for restaurant
fresh vegetables to once a century for slow growth
timber. Thus, the "valence" with which capital
combines with labor is highly variable. The
land/labor valence is not fixed, but it contains no such
extreme factor as this. ...
read the whole
article
Mason Gaffney:
Privatizing Land Without Giveaway
(1990)
Annual revaluation of land for tax purposes might
seem to impose extra uncertainty on landowners, in
comparison to the lot of lessees on fixed terms. However
it is only the amount of the tax that is uncertain; the
principle of it is known and certain. Furthermore the
principle is such that the tax only rises when exogenous
forces raise the earning potential of land; thus the
added tax is neither arbitrary nor grievous to bear. When
exogenous forces lower earnings, they also lower the tax
burden, so that the fisc shares the risk with
landowners.
Annual revaluation occasionally will
penalize a landowner when the best use of land changes in
the midlife of a durable building. Anticipating that
hazard, landowners in some times and places will avoid long
commitments. This is not such a bad effect, however. Life
is uncertain; economic tides are uncertain; optimal land
use calls for frequent adjustments to new forces and data.
Therefore the most fixed, durable improvement should rarely
be encouraged. It is too ponderous and inflexible, too
likely to be a monument or white elephant that will
obsolesce before it pays off. Some examples are the C&O
Canal, the Great Wall of China, the Edsel plant, the
Maginot Line, and a dozen buildings we could all pick out
in our own cities. In my own neighborhood, near a growing
shopping center, over half the parcels have been cleared
and rebuilt in the last fifteen years, even without any tax
stimulus. In dynamic times and places it is good for
builders to anticipate fairly early demolition and renewal,
and plan accordingly....
read the whole
article Mason
Gaffney: The
Property Tax is a Progressive Tax
(1971)
Another needed correction is the
treatment of realized capital
gains. Say an asset rises slowly for twenty years
and is sold. In the year of sale, reported income is
high, but property taxes are normal or fall. In the first 19 years there were property taxes and
no reported income. This creates a statistical illusion
of regressivity. If accrual of value were treated as
current income, the illusion would be
dispelled.
Another needed
correction is the treatment of normal life-cycles of
accumulation and liquidation. It is normal for the retired
elderly to draw on savings in years of low income, and get
help from children, if needed, to hang onto property the
children will inherit. The property tax which has
not been regressive in a lifetime sense looks regressive
when no correction is made for this statistical illusion.
... read the whole article
Louis Post: Outlines
of Louis F. Post's Lectures, with Illustrative Notes and
Charts (1894) — Appendix: FAQ
Q7. If a man owns a city lot with a $5000 building
on it, what, under the single tax, would hinder another
man, perhaps with hostile intent, from bidding a higher
tax than the first man was able to pay, and thus ousting
him from his building?
A. The question rests upon a misapprehension of
method. The single tax is not a method of nationalizing
land and renting it out to the highest bidder. It is a
method of taxation. And it would not only hinder, it
would prevent the unjust ousting of another from his
building. The single tax falls upon land-owners in
proportion to the unimproved value of their land; and
this value is determined by the real estate market
— by the demands of the whole community — and
not by arbitrary bids. No one could oust a man from his
building by bidding more for the land on which it stood
than the occupier was paying; the single tax would not be
increased in any case unless the land upon which it fell
was in so much greater demand that the owner could let it
for a higher rent.
Q50. Would not the single tax take away the home
place, and so tend to crush out the home
sentiment?
A. When the home place now becomes valuable, it is parted
with.
Q51. Yes; but when the home place is parted with
now, the home owner is compensated by the high price he
gets.
A. Then your question does not turn upon the home
sentiment but upon the dollar sentiment. As a matter of
sentiment, the condition would be no worse in any case
than now, and in many cases far better; as a matter of
dollars, the question is one of justice and not of the
home. Under the single tax any one who wanted a home
could have it, and never be obliged to abandon one home
for another, unless such changes took place in the
neighborhood as to make the place inappropriate for a
home. He could not then, as he does now, play dog in the
manger, saying to the community, "I will not use this
place for appropriate purposes, nor will I allow any one
else to do so."
Q56. Rich man with large mansion; poor widow with
small house on same sized lot adjoining. The two pay the
same tax. Is that right?
A. There is no reason in justice why the community should
not charge poor widows as much for monopolizing valuable
land as it charges rich men. In either case it confers a
special privilege and should be paid what the privilege
is worth. The question is seldom asked in good faith.
Poor widows who live on lots adjoining large mansions are
not numerous, and when they exist they are simply
land-grabbers. In our sympathy for these widows, let us
not forget the vast armies of widows who not only do not
live next to mansions, but have no place in the whole
wide world upon which to rest. ... read the book
|
To share this page with a friend:
right click, choose "send," and add your
comments.
|
|
Red links have not been
visited; .
Green links are pages you've seen
|
Essential Documents pertinent
to this theme:
|
|