The Property Tax is a Progressive Tax
by M. Mason Gaffney
Resources for the Future, Inc.,
Washington, D.C.
[Reprinted from the
Proceedings of the Sixty-Fourth Annual Conference on
Taxation,
sponsored by the National Tax Association,
1971.1
Introduction
"The regressive property tax" has become a common block
phrase among economists and in the popular press. President
Nixon's support for revenue-sharing is increasingly based
on the need to protect the poor from heavy property taxes.
Some prominent tax economists are favoring even sales taxes
to make the tax system more progressive, by lowering the
property tax. (1) Even local income
taxes, which are mainly payroll taxes, are being advanced
to relieve property and the poor.
1 Joseph Pechman, "Fiscal
Federalism for the 1970's,' National Tax Journal 24 (3):
281-90 (September 1971), p. 284.
I find this implausible. To own property is to be rich,
in the measure that one owns, and to tax the quality of
richness should not be presumed to burden the poor more
than the rich. As to the elderly, it is only traditional
for interest groups to hide behind selected widows, and one
should rarely take such appeals at face value. And so I
propose critically to examine the bases for alleging the
property tax to be regressive.
The Founding Fathers regarded property taxes as
redistributive and equalitarian. James Madison wrote:
In England, at this day, if elections were open to all
classes of people, the property of landed proprietors
would be unsure. ... Landholders ought to have a share in
the government, to support these invaluable interests, .
. . . They ought to be so constituted as to protect the
minority of the opulent against the majority.(2)
Madison also wrote ". . . the most common and
durable source of factions has been the various and unequal
distribution of property." He foresaw that the landless
majority might use government to redistribute property. "To
secure ... private rights against the danger of such a
faction ... is then the great object...... (3)
2 Cited in Louis Hacker, Triumph
of American Capitalism (New York: Columbia University
Press, 1947). p. 187. (Hacker does not give the original
source.)
3 The Federalist #73, cited in Charles Beard, An
Economic Interpretation of the Constitution (New York:
The Macmillan Co., 1935), pp. 156-58. (Later note added,
4/99. Correct source is The Federalist #10 - check
Beard.)
The constitutional safeguard which the Founders
established is the "regulation of apportionment."
"Representatives and direct taxes shall be apportioned
among the several States which may be included within this
Union, according to their respective numbers, . . . ."
(4 )
4Article 1, sec. 2, clause 3;
and sec. 9, cl. 4.
It was designed to win the support of property owners
by assuring them that the new federal government would be
financed mainly by excise taxes rather than property taxes
(5) and that when property taxes
were used, states above average in property per capita
would be spared.(6 )
5 A. Hamilton, The Federalist
#12.
6 Charles Beard, An Economic Interpretation of the
Constitution, op. cit., p. 169. See also pp. 100-03, on
Hamilton's support from speculators in western
lands.
Property qualifications on
voting were widespread at this time. In the opinion
of conservative people they barely sufficed to exclude from
the suffrage such shiftless persons as had no visible
interest in keeping down the taxes." (7) Throughout the 19th century the suffrage
was extended (it is not universal even yet), and government
functions increased. Public schools became popular, and
increasingly tax-financed. E.R.A. Seligman seems to
perceive the property tax as redistributive in opposing
exclusive reliance on it: ". . . it involves some risk for
a small class to pay the taxes and for a large class to
vote on them...... (8) (Ironically,
Seligman is known as a proponent of the ability ethic of
taxation.) A common argument for sales
and income taxes over property taxes is their "broad base,"
discouraging the poor from voting for public extravagance.
"Broad-based" seems quite like "regressive."
7 John Fiske, The Critical
Period of American History (Cambridge: The Riverside
Press, 1888), p. 70.
8 Essays in Taxation (London: Macmillan and Co.
Ltd., ?th ed. 1919), p. 78.
Property qualifications for the vote are not dead.
Special improvement district boards throughout the west are
elected by landowners alone (notably excepting California
Wright Act Irrigation Districts). The prevailing argument
for limited suffrage is that so nicely distilled by
Seligman supra.(9) In the
settlement of the west, the county property tax was
traditionally the fiscal means by which small settlers and
homesteaders asserted some public equity in the lands of
large absentees, ranches, and speculators. In some areas, owners covering whole counties (like
Kenedy County, Texas) refused to sell to immigrants, to
keep them from voting and raising county taxes -- which the
big owners evidently perceived as redistributive.
Company towns like Arvin, California, have been kept
unincorporated to keep migrant laborers from using the
property tax on the owners. All of northern Maine is
unincorporated, ostensibly because Great Northern and a few
other paper companies want to avoid letting immigrant
voters tax their property. Similarly, industrial tax
enclaves in metropolitan areas keep out resident voters. In
the Southeast half the poor have been disenfranchised
because of poll taxes and race. The southeast relies less
on the property tax than other regions. If the property tax
were regressive the dominant minority would seem rationally
to have imposed it on the disenfranchised poor. Instead
they pioneered the state sales tax.
9 See Wells Hutchins, Irrigation
Districts, US. Department of Agriculture Technical
Bulletin #254, 1931, pp. 15-16.
H.D. Simpson has pointed out how property owners favored
the "contract" as opposed to "organic" theory of
government. Under the contract theory, property could be
charged only for benefits received (rather narrowly
construed). Under organic theory, the public asserts its
equity for redistributive ends, taxing ad valorem without
reference to the source of value. "The opponents of
expansion (of public services), representing largely the
property classes who would have to carry the cost of these
expansions and who would participate least in their
benefits, necessarily fell back on the Benefit Theory, . .
." (10) The benefit or contract
theory lives today under the saying that property should
only pay for services to property, not services to people.
The animus is that property taxes to finance schools are
redistributive. Services to property are often opposed,
too. Property taxes to finance any mass system that favors
small over large holdings inspire resistance in the spirit
of attorney Maxwell's image of water districts as
"Communism and confiscation under guise of law."
(11) Such language suggests these
taxes were viewed as progressive, and the history of
irrigation shows they were indeed the weapon of small
farmers against large.(12)
10 H. D. Simpson, 'Historical Development
of the Property Tax from the Legal Viewpoint," American
Economic Review (September, 1939), pp. 457-67, p.
462.
11 Fallbrook v. Bradley, 1895, 164 U.S.
112.
12 Albert Henley, "Land Value Taxation by
California Irrigation Districts," in A. Becker (ed.),
Land and Building Taxes (Madison: University of Wisconsin
Press, 1969), pp. 137-46.
It is quite a wrench to shift from this historical
perspective to the modern image of the property tax as
regressive. But times have changed, and even the modern
examples could be exceptional and atavistic. Also, today we
have the income tax as a reference datum. Allegations of property tax regressivity usually
imply a contrast with the income tax, lacking in Madison's
day and weak in Seligman's. Current and recurrent proposals
for property tax relief entail substituting income tax (and
other state and federal tax) revenues for property taxes.
To meet the argument in its strongest general form,
therefore, we must compare property and income.
To define and narrow the issue I am
making, I here define the property tax as one levied at a
uniform rate on the base of the capital value of property
as revealed by the current market. This is a
property tax reduced to its essence, stripped of the
regressivity that may result from maladministration and
Balkanization, which are not the issues I raise here
because they are not peculiar to the property tax.
Maladministration often entails
regressive assessment, a serious problem. But all taxes are
applied regressively, and for about the same unhappy
reasons related to legal costs and financing politics. The
income tax may be the worst administered of the lot, in
this respect. It is an unbalanced literature that would
compare a badly run property tax with an idealized income
tax.
As to Balkanization, this is
not inherent in the property tax as such, but in local
taxation as such. A local income tax
similarly lets tax havens attract the rich by low
rates. Wisconsin municipalities, indeed, have a
local income tax (state-collected and returned). Since the
rates are common, regressivity takes the indirect form of
higher services and lower local property taxes in the
favored enclaves, but it is nonetheless a feature of local
income taxation. California, on the other hand, may move to
a statewide property tax in response to the recent state
Supreme Court decision, bringing in to finance education
not only the property of Emeryville and the Cities of
Commerce and Industry, but also rich, undertaxed farm,
timber, recreational, and above all, mineral-bearing real
estate.
To hang the tax enclave problem on the
property tax as such would, therefore, be an example of the
fallacy of identification, one which I seek to avoid here
by focusing on property value -- the ideaized tax base --
rather than collections.
Today's common concept of regressivity
owes much to an early work by Musgrave, Carroll, Cook, and
Frane.(13) Their selection of data sources, assumptions,
concepts and methods set a pattern followed in many later
studies which repeated the general finding, with individual
variations. It is my thesis that the finding is inherent in
the sources, assumptions, concepts and methods, not in the
subject. To demonstrate this I make four points:
- property ownership is much more concentrated than
income;
- the property tax is not primarily shifted forward, as
assumed;
- the studies commit basic errors of correlation
analysis with systematic biases toward their conclusion;
and
- the studies misdefine both income and property, again
with systematic bias toward their finding.
13 "Distribution of Tax Payments by
Income Groups: A Case Study for 1948," IV, National Tax
Journal (1): 1-53, March, 195 1. For a list of others
see Dick Netzer, Economics of the Property Tax
(Washington, D.C., Brookings Institution, 1966), pp.
247 ff., and the Netzer book itself, Chap. III.
A. Property Ownership Is More Concentrated
Than Income
To begin, a large share of the adult population -- half,
as a rough measure -- are renters and own no meaningful
value of taxable property at all. Most of these essentially
propertyless adults do earn taxable wage income. (We
consider later whether property taxes are shifted onto
them.)
Savings rise with income, faster than income. With
savings one acquires property, and we would naturally
expect therefore higher income groups to own property in
proportion to their greater saving, which is a
disproportionately high share of their high incomes. And we
would also expect a high share of high incomes to come from
property.
Musgrave et al. support this. They rank 1948 U.S.
"Spending Units" by income and group them, using Treasury
sources of data. The highest class got 23% of the income,
but 78% of dividend income and 45% of rental income, and
only 12% of the wage and salary income.(14) Other sources might be cited, too.
14 Musgrave, et al, op. cit., Table 1, p.
11.
Musgrave et al. omitted capital gains. These are
probably the most concentrated source of income, and of
course property-derived. Realized gains swell from
virtually nothing at the $10,000 income level to about half
of income at the million dollar level.(15) Unrealized accrued gains, which we should
include in a proper Haig-Simons income concept, are
probably larger yet, and more concentrated. There are no
easy data on this, but several a priori and indirect
reasons to think them concentrated. The rich have a
comparative advantage in waiting for deferred cash. They
are known to favor growth stocks, undistributed profits,
speculative landholdings and unripe minerals, major sources
of unrealized accruals.
15 Business Week, March 29, 1969, p. 96,
"Making the Burden More Equal," citing the Brookings
Institution.
Among those who do own material amounts of property,
concentration is high relative to that of income. The top
10% of income receivers, as income is usually defined and
reported, get about 30% of all income. Every study of
property owners shows figures in another ballpark
altogether. Table 1 summarizes what several such studies
show about the top group. Note that most of these figures
show only concentration among those who own enough property
to be counted, thus understating concentration among the
whole population.
TABLE 1. -Share of Wealth Held by Top
Wealthholders
|
Investigator
|
Kind of Wealth
|
% of Holders in Top Group(s)
|
% of Wealth in Top Group(s)
|
FTC a
|
U.S. Estates, 1926
|
0.1
|
8.5
|
"
|
U.S. Estates, 1926
|
2.5
|
46
|
Smith and Calvert b
|
U.S. Wealth, 1958
|
1
|
24
|
Lampman c
|
U.S. Wealth, 1961
|
1
|
28
|
U.S. Census d
|
U.S. Farm Acreage, 1949
|
2.3
|
43
|
R. Nader el al. e
|
Calif. Acreage, 1971
|
<.01
|
14
|
M. Gaffney f
|
Milwaukee, CBD, east side, assessed value,
1968
|
10
|
60
|
M. Gaffney g
|
Milwaukee Industrial Real Estate, assessed
value, 1960
|
10
|
89
|
1
|
59
|
Same, land area
|
10
|
75
|
TNEC h
|
U.S. Corporate Shares
|
3
|
50
|
Crockett and
Friend i
|
U.S. CorporateShares, 1960
|
0.1
|
20
|
1
|
50
|
Judiciary Comm., U.S. Senate j
|
Shares of GM, 1956
|
<.01
|
33
|
Lydall and Lansing k
|
U.S. Net Worth, 1953
|
10
|
56
|
U.S.D.I. k
|
Federal Coal Leases, 773,000 acres, 1970
|
10 holders
|
49
|
a U.S. Federal
Trade Commission, National Wealth and Income, Senate
Doc. No. 126, 1926, p. 59.
b James Smith and Staunton Calvert,
"Estimating the Wealth of Top Wealth-holders from
Estate Tax Returns," American Statistical
Association, 1965 Proceedings of the Business and
Economic Statistical Section, Table 5, p.
258.
c Robert Lampman, The Share ot the
Top Wealth Holders in National Wealth (Princeton:
Princeton University Press, 1962), updated to 1961 by
Lampman in Business Week, "Rich Get Richer -but not
for Long," January 27, 1962, p. 3 1.
d 1950 U.S. Census of Agriculture,
Vol. 2, Ch. 10, p. 775.
e Robert FeUmeth (ed.), "Power and
Land in California" (Washington: Center for Study of
Responsive Law (1971)), Preliminary Draft (mimeo),
Vol. 1, p. I-17.
f Data taken from City of Milwaukee
assessment rolls and ranked by Patricia Bevic,
research assistant.
g I ranked 626 City of Milwaukee
industrial ffi= by value, data collected by Norbert
Stefaniak.
h Temporary National Economic
Committee, Monograph 29, Distribution of Ownership of
the Largest 200 Non-financial Corps. (Washington:
GPO, 1940), pp. 37 ff. and Monograph 30, Survey of
Shareholders In 1710 Corps, P. 50.
i James Crockett and Erwin Friend,
"Characteristics of Stock Ownership," American
Statistical Association, 1963 Proceedings, reported
in Milwaukee Sentinel, September 18,
1963.
j Bigness and Concentration of
Economic Power-a Case Study of General Motors. Staff
Report, Subcommittee on Antitrust and Monopoly,
Committee on the Judiciary, U.S. Senate, 84th Cong.,
1st Sess. (Washington: GPO, 1956), P. 7.
k Harold Lydall and John Lansing,
"A Comparison of the Distribution of Personal Income
and Wealth in the US. and Gt. Britain,' AER 49 (1):
43-67 (March 1959), (using data from University of
Michigan Survey of Consumer Finance).
l U.S. Department of the Interior,
'Working Paper' (unpublished), cited in Milwaukee
Journal, August 29, 1971. |
Wealth is measured by value in all cases except where
acreage is specified (rows 4, 5). Here, some will object
that the acreage measure overstates concentration, on the
premise that large holdings of acreage are below average in
unit value. But even if they are, to accept that objection
from this premise would be a splendid case of regression
fallacy. When we move to the value measurement we must
rerank the owners on the new basis, and the new top group
would consist in part of different individuals. And there
is no way to know whether the new top group would have a
higher or lower share, short of actually reranking,
regrouping, and recounting.
Most data sources don't do this for us, but a few such
comparisons may be found. A special U.S. Census study of
the ownership of rented farms in 1900 measured them both by
area and land value. By area, the top 45% had 83%. By
value, the top 45% had 85%.16 In
1951 Danish farming: by area, the top 2% had 14%; by value,
the top 1.3% had 14%.(17) For
Milwaukee industrial real estate, I ranked firms in 1960 by
both land area and land value (my mass appraisal). By area,
the top 10% had 75%; by land value, 76%. For the Milwaukee
CBD (east side) 1968, I ranked owners by area and land
assessment (City Tax Commissioner's appraisal). By area,
the top 10% had 48%; by assessed value, 60%. (Preliminary,
subject to adjustment.)
16 U.S. Census of Agriculture 1900, Part
1, pp. xc, xcil
17 Danmark's Statistik Arbog, 1953, p.
50.
These scraps of evidence show there is no presumption
that acreage rankings overstate concentration of wealth as
a general rule, although they doubtless do in some
regions.
Corporate shares are not taxable property, but of course
corporate income is mostly derived from taxable
property.(18) Some will object that
corporations have many owners and should not be treated as
single units. That is true, but again, it smacks of
regression fallacy. Wealthy owners also have many
corporations, and in general corporate shares are the most
concentrated kind of asset.
18 For an exegesis on this point, cf. the
writer's "Adequacy of Land as a Tax Base," in Daniel
Holland (ed.), The Assessment of Land Value (Madison:
University of Wisconsin Press, 1970).
Ownership of large property gives one control of other
assets. Property is borrowing power and credit rating: all
studies show interest rates to be very regressive with size
and quality of collateral, and terms easier. But simple
borrowing is only the beginning. With great wealth one goes
into banking and exerts multiple leverage. The story has
been told many times, if not as well, since Brandeis'
Other Peoples' Money: collateral,
leverage, conglomerates, interlocking directorates,
mergers, lender suasion, industrial leadership, pyramiding,
the Wallenberg Grip, subcontracting market power, control
of dealerships, . . . . Control is power and status
(psychic income), and control is a source of additional
income, as revealed by the premium prices of shares during
battles for control.
Data in Table 1 probably understate
concentration, for four general reasons: omitting
the unpropertied, accepting and reporting regressive
assessments, accepting the bias in partial inventories, and
accepting and reporting straw owners as separate
owners.
1. Omitting the unpropertied. Few families have
no income, so income data cover most people. Many have too
little property to count, however, so many studies omit
them. General asset ownership studies use the
estate-multiplier technique. Here the minimum is $60,000.
Corporate shareholder data omit most people, because most
own no stock. Farm data omit hired labor, treat tenants as
owners, and say nothing about former 'croppers now crowded
in city ghettos.
My Milwaukee CBD data are in percentage terms relating
only to other owners. But the whole east side area studied
has only 401 owners of record, while some hundred thousand
people work and pay sales taxes there.
2.
Accepting regressive assessments as fact. Regressive
assessment is not universal, but some kinds of property are
systematically assessed regressively and, if not overtly,
at least openly enough so assessors under questioning do
not deny but explain and defend the practice. Unsubdivided
land in large tracts is usually given a lower assessed unit
value, specifically because the holding is large. The
result may be seen by ranking Milwaukee industries by value
of land (estimated from reported area adjusted by mass
appraisal technique). The top 10% have 76% of the land
value, but only 61% of the assessed land value. Thus
the Table 1 datum, based on assessed value (of land and
buildings), probably understates concentration.
This factor also affects findings of studies using U.S.
Treasury data. For IRS practice gives weight to locally
assessed values in appraisals for Federal estate and income
taxation. The notion that malassessment only affects local
taxes is a myth.
Another factor is the watering of prices charged to the
poor in and around ghettos. A speculator often buys cheap
and sells for what looks like a huge markup. But the buyer
has no cash. The seller takes his profit in an inflated and
risky second trust, which be quickly sells at a large
discount. The sage assessor knows how to dehydrate watered
prices if he wants to, but there is pressure to maintain
tax revenues from these areas, often resulting in watered
assessments on the poor.
Of course, if property assessments are regressive,
property taxes are based on them anyway, not on true
values. But I distinguish tax concept from tax
administration, as noted. This is important for policy.
A regressively conceived tax remains regressive under
the best of management. If the property tax is progressive
in essential concept, then it needs reform and new life
rather than the gas chamber.
Regressive assessment is usually explained by assessors
on grounds of regressive use of property. Large holdings
are generating less activity per dollar of value. In
Oregon, for example, larger timber holdings are overtly
assessed lower with the rationale they are worth less
because of the owners' slower cutting schedule. But note
this says activity-based taxes (sales and income) are then
less progressive than property taxes. Thus the very
explanation of regressive assessment is a phenomenon that
shows the property tax, properly administered, to be
Progressive relative to income and sales taxes.
3. The bias in partial inventories. Any wealth
inventory short of universal will usually understate
concentration because larger holders are more diversified.
The largest owners in one city, region, industry, or other
class are most likely to have holdings outside the
class.
As to housing, it is the rich
who have second homes, hobby farms, summer resorts, tax
shelters, ski houses, Caribbean hideaways, lake frontage,
and advance sites for future building. Yet studies of
income and housing, from which some would damn the property
tax, compare a full statement of income (at least wage
income) with housing narrowly defined. Walter Morton (p.
143) goes so far as to judge the entire property tax on the
basis of housing alone. He not only omitted second homes,
but other property comprising half the total: commerce,
industry, rental, vacant, farm, forest, mineral, water, and
miscellaneous. Again, ownership of these is concentrated
among those ranking high in the housing scale.
Studies of foreign-owned farms in America have shown
them to be larger than owner-occupied holdings. The 1900
Census of Agriculture (a high water mark in good
government statistics) reported on farm landlords.
I take this to be a universal tendency, deducible a
priori from the fact that it doesn't pay to range far
abroad to invest only a small sum. As U.S. residents change
from colonials into the world's absentee owners, this
universal tendency is clear. It is our largest oil firms,
the international majors, who cover the entire U.S. with
marketing and the world with mineral holdings. The largest
holdings in any one jurisdiction, industry, or other narrow
class of property, thus are usually owned by those with
large holdings outside. With every passing year of mergers
and conglomeration this grows more true.
Thus my data on Milwaukee's CBD understate
concentration. The third largest holder on the west side
there for example is the Schlitz Company, yet the area
omits the brewery that made Milwaukee famous, millions of
dollars in the controlling family's vast speculative
suburban landholdings, and large worldwide interests.
Smaller owners have outside interests too, but on the whole
are less diversified.
Again, the data on industry take no account that the
large firms either have or are branch plants. Increasingly
they are merged into conglomerates. In Wisconsin, Udell
finds recent conglomeration has resulted in large drops in
activity-based income taxes from the merged properties.
Conglomeration is partly motivated, indeed, to avoid income
taxes. That means the corporate income tax is regressive in
practice.(20)
20 Jon Udell, Social and Economic
Consequences of the Merger Movement in Wisconsin
(Madison: Bureau of Business Research, 1969).
Many popular recent studies omit all property but
housing, following Walter Morton. The better studies, as by
Musgrave and Netzer, avoid this outright blunder. But wide
currency and credibility have gone recently to a study by
Daniel Lucas for the D.C. Government, based entirely on
housing - first home only - and hypothetical housing at
that.(21) The Wisconsin Department
of Revenue released a study in May "in defense of Governor
Lucey's use of the income tax to provide property tax
relief' with the same blunder.(22)
This study follows the precedent of a 1959 release by the
University of Wisconsin School of Commerce.(23)
21 D. Lucas, "Major Tax Burdens in
Washington Compared With Those in the 25 Largest Cities,"
D.C. Government, press release, December 1970.
22 Milwaukee Journal, May 25, 1971.
23 University of Wisconsin Tax Study
Commission, Wisconsin's State and Local Tax Burden
(Madison: University of Wisconsin School of Commerce,
1959).
Many writers exempt corporate shares from taxable
wealth, faulting the property tax for not reaching such
"intangibles." Yet most corporate assets are very tangible
at a price. In most jurisdictions the largest property
taxpayers are corporations.(24)
Studies based on individual ownership alone and omitting
corporate wealth are simply not relevant.
24 M. Mason Gaffney, loc. cit.
A large genre of partial inventories is the farm study,
of which every Agricultural Experiment Station must have
issued one or more. Hardly anyone wealthy enough to own a
large farm today lacks nonfarm income. One cannot afford to
keep a large farm without using it as an income tax shelter
- that is the "highest and best use" under our income tax
law. Studies purporting to compare "farm income" with farm
property taxes are founded on the obsolete premise that
"farmers" are a separate class of people, and have no
value.
4. Accepting straw owners as separate owners.
Large land assemblies are habitually arranged through straw
owners. Thus one large owner often appears on records as
several small ones. The Milwaukee CBD study, as reported,
is premised on one certain block's having several separate
owners, as recorded. Some time after the First Wisconsin
Bank announced it was building on the assembled
site,(25) we did not find it listed
as owner.(26) Nor did we find
Northwestern Mutual Life listed for more than its home
office, although Gordon Davidson, director of real estate,
stated the company had been acquiring land in our area
"over the years." (27) Small
owners, on the other hand, are not likely to appear as
large ones. Wealthy families wear several guises: banks,
insurance companies, corporations, estates, utilities, etc.
Property is assigned to children and relatives to split
income. Rarely are these veils pierced by formal
quantitative studies. Even the ICC has never found out who
owns the railroads. But we can be quite certain ownership
is held more closely in fact than on paper.
25 Milwaukee Sentinel, February 14,
1969.
26 Report by Patricia Bevic, Research
Assistant, March, 1969.
27 Milwaukee Sentinel, February 14,
1969.
B. The Property Tax is not Primarily Shifted
Forward
With a base so concentrated, it requires some creative
methods to find the property tax regressive. One is to
assume general forward shifting. Then the property owner is
exempt, except as a homeowner. Tenants do not escape. No
one does. The property tax becomes a general consumption
tax, and therefore regressive. I submit several reasons why
the property tax is not shifted forward.
1. All studies have greatly
understated the share of land in real estate value.
Some overlook it altogether. The good ones assign it a
value, and allow for nonshifting, but the value is much too
low. They are all pre-Douglas Commission Report, and
rendered obsolete by Manvel's study of how high a share
land values are.28
Manvel's study plus my Milwaukee study plus Gustafson's
California data support a land share of 40% and up, much
higher than the 15% or so used by Musgrave et al. At
present the assessed value of land is 40-50% of the total
in Washington, D.C., California, and some other
jurisdictions that have updated assessments.
28 Allen D. Manvel, "Trends in the Value
of Real Estate and Land, 1956-66," in National Committee
on Urban Problems, Three Land Research Studies, Research
Report #12 (Washington: GPO, 1968), pp. 1-17
It is true that in most jurisdictions land is
underassessed, and Musgrave's numbers were reasonable in
their day as a statement of what assessors were doing. As
noted, however, maladministration should be blamed on
administrators, not on the property tax per se. And
Musgrave omitted three important points.
- One, the share of land in real estate tends to
rise with value of holdings.(29) So nonshiftability of the property tax
rises with wealth.
- Two, the share of land in real estate is lowest in
owner-occupied residences, where the shifting assumption
has no effect on progressivity. Land share is
highest, normally over half, in commerce, where the
assumption is critical. In Milwaukee, 40% of all retail
land space is in gas stations! The property tax on
downtown and other retail landowners with wide parking
lots in good locations is one of the most progressive
imaginable, but Musgravian assumptions convert it into a
regressive sales tax.
-
Three, taxes on land actually have some positive
effect on supply. They are not simply neutral, but
apply leverage prompting earlier and more intensive use
of land. To assume non-shifting understates their
impact on landowners. They weaken his market position
vis-a-vis non-owners, making them doubly progressive.
This is a fortiori true of
mineral bearing lands. Here, property tax critics often
forecast panic liquidation if rates rise. They overdraw
the point, but there is a point there, and it is in the
reverse of forward shifting.
29 President's Commission on Urban
Housing, Report on Urban Housing (Washington: GPO,
1968), p. 351; M. Gaffney, "Land Speculation,"
unpub@hed Ph.D. dissertation, University of California,
1956, pp. 210-17; 1940 Census of Agriculture, Vol. 3,
p. 80; R. Hurd, Principles of City Land Values (New
York: Record and Guide, 1902), p. 102.
2. Taxes on buildings are not mostly shifted
forward. There is no reason to assume forward shifting
of taxes on capital, and I find no persuasive rationale in
Musgrave et al, or Morton. Netzer mugwumps the
issue.
To be simply shifted forward, a tax would have to be
proportional to output. Taxes on capital are not
proportional to output, but to one input. They fall
differentially hard on capital intensive operations and
industries, which could not recoup from customers without
raising prices relative to labor-intensive competitors.
Capital-intensity varies over a very wide range -- see any
issue of Fortune's annual analysis of the top 500
corporations. And it is the large firms that own more
capital per unit of output. That is, the use of property is
regressive, so that activity-based taxes are regressive
relative to taxes on capital. Even if there be some
tendency toward forward shifting it would be very uneven,
the more capital-intensive firms being less able to
shift.
But of alternative shifting hypotheses, forward shifting
seems the least likely. It would only make sense if the tax
were levied on one industry, exempting others, thus
reducing supply and raising real price. But the property
tax is a general tax on capital. It cannot be analyzed with
tools of partial equilibrium. It chases capital out of
capital-intensive and into labor-intensive uses. The tax on
buildings (not on land) encourages land-intensive use, too,
i.e. a low capital/land ratio.
Where we go from here depends on what we are
analyzing.
- If it is an open economy like the typical local
taxing body, then wage rates and interest rates are fixed
exogenously, leaving only land to bear any local tax. The
local tax on capital thus is largely shifted to land. The
shifting is differential, owing to different capital/land
ratios; and density is reduced. But the point here is
that the tax is not shifted off property and is not made
regressive.
- If it is federal revenue-sharing we analyze, the
rules change. Now the proposal would affect property
taxes nationwide. Here we cannot assume that interest and
wage rates are fixed exogenously.
In a completely closed economy, capital should bear most
of the tax on capital. If it cannot emigrate, its escape
routes are limited to dissaving and tax-exempt public
works. Supply being fairly inelastic, capital has to accept
a lower rate of return after taxes. If capital did not
absorb the tax, the tax rate added to the pre-tax interest
rate would drive capital out of capital-intensive and into
labor-intensive uses. In the latter it complements labor,
raising demand for labor, preventing a shift of the tax to
labor.
But the U.S. economy is not entirely closed. Capital now
emigrates, not without cost, but more freely than labor.
Thus the position of capital vis-a-vis labor is stronger
than in a completely closed economy, and labor does suffer
from the tax. But the position vis-a-vis land is strong
too. So the capital tax as a national institution is borne
by land and capital and labor, all three. Thus property
still bears much, and probably most of the capital
tax.(80) Remember now, that the
other half of the property tax falls directly on land and
stays. Putting it all together, it seems most likely that
the property tax is indeed largely what it purports to be,
a tax on property.
30 Adding the property tax rate to the
interest rate affects the allocation of new investments
in much the same way as raising interest rates by the
amount of the property tax rate. This forces capital into
labor-intevsive forms, moderating the damage to labor by
increasing demand for labor. Saving capital also involves
substituting land, but this is tightly limited, because
using more private land would require more social
overhead capital (like longer streets). And saving
capital entails lowering longevity of capital, which
substitutes labor for land, as explained by Wicksell in
Value, Capital and Rent.
The case for forward shifting is
strongest with utilities, and rails, not for analytical but
institutional reasons. Here, however, a simple
forward shift would only result if we took regulatory piety
at face value, as no one does who really looks into the
matter. We cannot develop that here. But note that the rate
required to attract capital into utilities is lowered by
taxes on non-utility property. Thus indirectly, if
regulation works at all, utilities bear the property tax
too, at least in part.
The case for forward shifting seems weak with timber,
livestock, and all appreciating capital in the short run,
since it hastens liquidation. But this is only short run,
and a partial analysis. In the long run the tax drives
capital out of capital-intensive uses. The case is
really weak where cartels are engaged in
underutilizing capital or land - the common condition
according to students of industrial organization. These
holding actions are extremely vulnerable to the property
tax. Far from being shifted forward, the tax forces idle
capital and land into use, increasing supply and lowering
prices. All cartels are characterized by
excess capacity -- that is of the essence. When you
consider that half the wells in Texas are surplus -- need I
go on? In a cartelized society like ours the forward
shifting thesis is not just shaky but ludicrous. Untaxing
property, as by revenue sharing, would strengthen the hand
of every cartel now locking up excess capacity. It is not
the property tax but the lack of one that would be shifted
forward in higher prices.
. The Need to Correct for Regression Fallacy, or Which
Top 10% Do You Mean?
Most studies of property tax regressivity stumble
squarely into the pratfall of regression fallacy. The
problem in brief is this. Income and property are
positively related but the scatter of points is loose, with
great individual residuals from any fitted curve, and a
high error of estimate. We want to know which rises faster
as they rise together. The answer depends on which we
arbitrarily select as the ranking variable. Let us say we
rank by income on the abscissa and find the top 10% have
30% of the income and 25% of the property (a hypothetical
number). It looks as though the property tax is regressive.
But now rank them by property on the ordinate. The top 10%
are now a different group -we have taken a stratum of
points at right angles to the original column. Some of the
humble have been exalted, and the mighty laid low. This top
10% has say 50% of the property and 25% of the income, and
the property tax looks progressive (in terms of
income).(31)
31 Good discussions of regression fallacy
are in Allen Wallis and Harry Roberts, Statistics
(Glencoe: The Free Press, 1956), preceding p. 263;
Lawrence Klein, Introduction to Econometrics (Englewood
Cliffs: Prentice-Hall, 1962), pp. 68-69; George Stigler,
'Labor Productivity and Size of Farm: A Statistical
Pitfall," Journal of Farm Economics 28: 21-25 (1946); and
A. E. Waugh, Elements of Statistical Method (New York:
McGraw-Hill, 1943). pp. 387-89.
When the Census of Housing ranks families by
income, rent payments do not keep up with
income.(32) But ranking them by
value of dwelling units, value quintuples while income only
doubles.(33) That is the difference
a technical detail or two can make.
32 U.S. Census of Housing, 1960, Table
A-3.
33 Op. cit., Table B-3, p. 14.
So which top 10% do we mean? Most studies have
uncritically chosen income as the proper ranking variable,
by assumption, thus practically preordaining the conclusion
- and largely invalidating it.
The Chicago school of permanent income hypothesizers
have counterattacked sharply on the housing salient.
Margaret Reid (34) undertook to
narrow the scatter of points by removing random
year-to-year income changes. She related housing to a
definition of permanent income, and came up with
income-elasticity of demand for housing well above
unity.
34 M. Reid, Housing and Income (Chicago:
University of Chicago Press, 1962).
One of Reid's methods of avoiding regression fallacy was
the interarea comparison, where data are grouped by a
neutral variable (neighborhood) which is neither housing
nor income. Brodsky has repeated this for Census Tracts of
the District of Columbia. His findings strike me because he
is a geographer who is not concerned with the permanent
income or regressivity question and presents his findings
just as interesting facts. He finds residential improvement
values rise with the 1.3 power of income; land values rise
with the 1.8 power.(35) Muth has
refined and expanded Reid's method!;. He now suggests 1.2
or 1.3 as correct income-elasticities of demand for
housing.(36) Lee has criticized
Reid's methods and come up with an elasticity of about .81.
However, Lee's data were too small a sample to lean on
heavily, and more important they excluded land.
(37) We
have seen that land is the most progressive share of
housing, so this biases Lee's findings downwards.
35 H. Brodsky, 'Residential Land and
Improvement Values in a Central City," Land Economics 46
(3): 229-47 (August 1970), p. 239.
36 R. Muth, "Permanent Income,
Instrumental Variables, and the Income Elasticity of
Housing Demand" (MS, n.d., ca. 1971, pp. 1-40).
37 Tong Lee, "Housing and Permanent
Income," Review ot Economics and Statistics 50 (4):
480-90 (November 1968), p. 487.
Another needed correction is the
treatment of realized capital
gains. Say an asset rises slowly for twenty years
and is sold. In the year of sale, reported income is high,
but property taxes are normal or fall. In
the first 19 years there were property taxes and no
reported income. This creates a statistical illusion of
regressivity. If accrual of value were treated as current
income, the illusion would be dispelled.
Another needed correction is the
treatment of normal life-cycles of accumulation and
liquidation. It is normal for the retired elderly to draw
on savings in years of low income, and get help from
children, if needed, to hang onto property the children
will inherit. The property tax which has not been
regressive in a lifetime sense looks regressive when no
correction is made for this statistical illusion.
But these are only glancing blows. The
central question is, why rank by income at all -any concept
of income? When we do that we accept
income-fundamentalism, a kind of philosophical imperialism
where Adjusted Gross Income on Form 1040 is the basic
reference datum against which to measure and judge
everything. "Similar circumstances" mean similar AGI, and
similar circumstances deserve similar taxes. In effect this
means we judge the property tax on the basis of how closely
it resembles the income tax, in every detail. Since nothing
resembles the income tax so much as the income tax, the
property tax looks inferior.
Again, the concept called "income-elasticity of demand
for wealth" contains implicit income - Chauvinism. It
implies one-way causation: income causes wealth. But wealth
also causes income, and as Klein points out that changes
the rules for relating them. No longer can income be the
simple ranking variable.
38 Klein, op. cit., p. 68.
If the property tax had no rationale of its own we would
be forced to accept income fundamentalism. But if the
property tax has a rationale, then it is legitimate to rank
by wealth, and fault the income tax for failing to tax
large properties adequately. Here is an outline rationale
for the property tax.
1. "Ability-to-pay"
derives from wealth as well as current income. James
Tobin, Arnold Zellner, Taylor and Houthakker, Harold
Somers, and others have stressed this lately. The old
cliche that "taxes are paid out of income" is as empty as
the one that we consume "out of income." We spend money,
and it is not labelled.
2. The property tax
asserts a public equity in land which was won and is
defended by joint efforts, and whose value derives from
public works and spillovers, not from the owners'
efforts. It exempts human effort, thus rewarding
service to the community and denying the state any equity
in the bodies of its citizens whose freedom and dignity is
thus enhanced in their capacity as human beings, as
distinct from owners of wealth.
3. Property taxes reduce
the differential effect of inherited wealth on the current
generation. They strike directly at concentration of
economic and other power based on wealth, promoting
competition and equal opportunity. Property as collateral
is a source of invisible income (credit rating). Taxing
property reduces the differential advantage of the rich in
credit rationing.
4. Property income of a
given dollar value places the receiver on a higher welfare
plane than labor income, because he needn't work for
it. $10,000 a year received by dint of working long
hours in a coal mine with black lung disease is not the
same as $10,000 plus a life of ease.
5. The property tax is needed to plug
loopholes in the income tax, which is inexorably
devolving into a payroll tax.
If one finds that rationale compelling, then the proper
approach is to rank by wealth. Doing so, one finds that
property is used regressively, i.e., the larger holdings
generate less taxable sales and income per dollar of
wealth. Thus in the Milwaukee industries reported in Table
1, ranking by value, the top 10% who have 89% of the value
have only 69% of the employees.
If one likes the property tax rationale partly but not
wholly, then he may follow Wallis and Roberts (39) who tell us that to avoid regression
fallacy a valid way to compare two populations is to
compare their standard deviations or other measure of
variability. If there is less income than property in
the upper groups, the variability of the income
distribution will be less. But we have already seen that is
so (Table 1). Table I only gives the top group, but in each
case I have computed Gini (or Lorenz concentration) ratios
for the entire distribution, and they are as you would
expect much higher than for income. (The Gini ratio is, in
my experience, closely correlated with the coefficient of
dispersion.)
39 Ibid., p.??
The more we correct for regression fallacy, then, the
more progressive the property tax looks.
D. On Defining Income and Wealth
Dick Netzer, like others, uses AGI as the reference
standard against which to match the property tax and find
it regressive.(40) A certain
citizen in 1970 reported no AGI, but heavy property taxes,
which might make the property tax quite regressive were it
not Ronald Reagan. Yet he is not alone, and it seems harsh
to select a measure that makes the property tax regressive
because it is the only tax many rich men pay. General
Oppenheimer has written a fine set of manuals on how to
reach Zero AGI by losing money farming,(41) and they work so well that taxable farm
income is down to about $3 billions while the USDA
estimates farm income at $14 billions.(42) I do not think that AGI will do.
40 Op. cit., p. 49.
41 H.L. Oppenheimer, Cowboy Economics,
1966; Cowboy Litigatton, 1968; Cowboy Arithmetic, 1964
(Danville, Illinois: Interstate Printers and Publishers)
-
42 Hendrik S. Houthakker, "The Great Farm
Tax Mystery," Challenge, January and February, 1967, pp.
12-13 and 38-39; Edward Reinsel, Farm and Off-farm Income
Reported on Federal Tax Returns, ERS-383 (Washington:
GPO, 1968).
It is not just farming. Property is the paramount tax
shelter. How does it cover thee? Let me count the ways.
There is
- expensing of intangibles and soil and water
conservation,
- percentage depletion,
- capital gains rates,
- deferred realization,
- non-distribution of profits,
- nonrealization,
- conversion of interest into cost recovery by watered
sales prices,
- accelerated depreciation,
- multiple depreciation,
- de facto expensing of capital improvements,
- deduction of interest,
- covert write-off of undepreciated land value,
- deferral of tax beyond date of sale, and many
others.
At the same time, property is a large source of income
that is not counted in AGI. Unrealized accruals and imputed
income are the most obvious, and each is a huge item.
Thus the ownership of property tends on a large scale
to reduce AGI and increase real income. When we rank by
AGI, property owners move into lower brackets than they
belong; non-owners move into higher brackets. Property
tax payments move into the lower brackets, pre-ordaining a
finding of regressivity which is totally illusory.
At least two studies have sought to correct for the
Reagan Effect. Both corrected only partially, and with
spectacular results.
- The Survey Research Center made the tax progressive
simply by including imputed income.(43)
- Brainin and Germanis do a similar job with California
data.(44)
43 Survey Research Center, Income and
Wealth in the U.S. (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1962).
44 David Brainin and John J. Germanis,
Comments on "Distribution of Property, Retail Sales and
Personal Income Tax Burdens in California: an Empirical
Analysis of Inequity in Taxation,' National Tax Journal,
March 1967, pp. 106-112.
Another common method is to define property tax payments
as only the net burden after deducting payments from
taxable income. This is to impute a regressive feature of
the income tax to the property tax. That would be wrong at
best, but more so when one is comparing the property tax
with the income tax itself.
If one does choose to evaluate the two taxes jointly, he
should note above all that the Federal Government has moved
far toward abandoning the taxation of property income. That
is the cumulative effect of a hundred loopholes, available
to property but not to the poor stiff with his W-2 Form.
Equity suggests that state and local treasuries move in on
this unpreempted tax base.
Definition of the property tax base is also a source of
serious error in a number of studies based on cash rents.
Netzer for example assumes that property
taxes are proportional to rents. They aren't. The base is
not rent but capital value. The poor live in declining
neighborhoods and buildings nearing abandonment, where
capital value is a very low multiple of rent. Rents
include high costs for collection, turnover, damage, loss
of status, maintenance and repairs, and general
unpleasantness. In Milwaukee's "Inner
Core" or slum area the rule of thumb is you pay 30 months'
rent to buy a dwelling unit. Tenant incomes are low,
but higher than such capital values. The rich live in new
buildings of long future life in appreciating
neighborhoods. Incomes are high, but normally less than
half of lot or acreage plus house values.
It is true that slums are often overassessed, but again,
maladministration is the fault of administrators. The
property tax in concept is progressive precisely because it
is based on capital value. Owners of appreciating property
often complain that capital value as a base hits them
harder than would current income or service flow as a base,
and they are right. That is precisely what makes the
property tax, correctly administered, so progressive.
|
To share this page with a friend:
right click, choose "send," and add your
comments.
|
|
Red links have not been
visited; .
Green links are pages you've seen
|
|