Politicians
Peter Barnes:
Capitalism 3.0 — Chapter 6: Trusteeship of Creation
(pages 79-100)
Accountability and Democracy
The question I’m most often asked about commons
trusteeship is: How can we be sure trustees won’t
succumb to corporate influence, just as politicians have?
My answer is that, while there can be no guarantees, the
odds of escaping corporate capture are much better with
trustees than with elected officials.
The key reason is accountability. In the world of
corporations, accountability is quite clear: directors
must be loyal to shareholders. In the world of
government, accountability is less clear. Elected
officials must uphold the Constitution, but that’s
about it. If there are conflicts between workers and
employers, polluters and pollutees, voters and donors, or
future generations and current ones, whose side should
politicians be on? There are no requirements or even
guidelines. Elected officials, as sovereign political
actors, are free to do as they please.
The fact that politicians operate this way is no
accident; it’s what the Founders had in mind. The
job of democratic government isn’t to take,
consistently, one side or another. Rather, it’s to
resolve disputes among factions peaceably, without
trampling minorities. James Madison made this plain in
the Federalist Papers. Voters can “fire”
elected officials at regular intervals if a majority so
chooses, but they can’t expect loyalty to any
particular constituency between elections. It’s
this absence of built-in loyalty that opens the door to
corporate influence, a force the Founders didn’t
— and couldn’t — foresee.
The decision-making of judges, it should be noted,
isn’t as untethered as that of legislators and
executive officeholders. Their duty is to uphold not just
the skeletal bones of the Constitution but the full flesh
and blood of the law, with its thousands of pages and
interpretations. They may, on occasion, interpret anew,
but unless they’re among a Supreme Court majority,
all such reinterpretations are subject to review.
Trustees are in the same boat as judges, rather than
the wide-open waters in which politicians swim. Their
hands are constrained both by the law and by their
fiduciary duty to beneficiaries. This isn’t to say
they have no room to wiggle: equally loyal trustees may
differ over what’s in the best interest of
beneficiaries. Still, they are subject to court review,
and they can’t betray their beneficiaries too
brazenly.
The tricky thing here is that the beneficiaries to
whom we want commons trustees to be loyal — future
generations, nonhumans, and ecosystems — are
voiceless and powerless. We must therefore take extra
care when we set up commons trusts. For example, we
should install strict conflict-of-interest rules for
trustees and managers. We should require that all
relevant information about the trusts — including
audited financial reports — are freely available on
the Internet. We should ensure that, if a commons trust
fails, its assets are transferred to a similar trust
rather than privatized. We should build in internal
watchdogs and ombudsmen. And we should authorize external
advocates, such as nonprofit organizations, to represent
nonliving beneficiaries who, by their very nature,
can’t take trustees to court. Most states assign
this function to their attorneys general, but this is
insufficient given the political pressures attorneys
general are subject to.
With regard to the manner of selecting trustees,
there’s no single method. Trustees might be
elected, appointed by outsiders, or be self-perpetuating
like the boards of many nonprofits. This is as it should
be; we don’t live in a one-size-fits-all world. The
important thing is that, once selected, trustees should
have secure tenure, and — like judges —
lengthy terms. Indeed, trustees should be like judges in
other ways: professional, impeccably honest,
well-compensated, and honored. Being a commons trustee
should be a distinguished and attractive calling.
It might be argued that, by shielding trustees from
direct political influence, we’d make them —
and commons trusts generally — undemocratic. The
same could be said, however, for our courts. The fact is,
there are certain decisions, both economic and judicial,
that should be shielded from politics and markets.
Moreover, neither government nor corporations represent
the needs of future generations, ecosystems, and nonhuman
species. Commons trusts can do this. In that sense,
they’d expand rather than constrict the boundaries
of democracy. ...
read the whole chapter
Jeff Smith and Kris Nelson: Giving Life to the Property Tax
Shift (PTS)
John Muir is right. "Tug on any one thing and find
it connected to everything else in the universe." Tug on
the property tax and find it connected to urban slums,
farmland loss, political favoritism, and unearned equity
with disrupted neighborhood tenure. Echoing Thoreau, the
more familiar reforms have failed to address this
many-headed hydra at its root. To think that the root
could be chopped by a mere shift in the property tax base
-- from buildings to land -- must seem like the epitome
of unfounded faith. Yet the evidence shows that state and
local tax activists do have a powerful, if subtle, tool
at their disposal. The "stick" spurring efficient use of
land is a higher tax rate upon land, up to even the
site's full annual value. The "carrot" rewarding
efficient use of land is a lower or zero tax rate upon
improvements. ...
And by taxing land, society impels
owners who had been speculatively withholding or
underutilizing theirs to develop or offer their parcels
for development. Hence the newly-available land comes
from recycled sites, not from open
space.
The PTS not only lowers the price of land,
it also lowers the cost of buildings. Untaxing
structures, besides reducing their cost, also augments
their supply. More buildings means lower prices and
rents. As the prices of both buildings and land drop,
more people are able to purchase a home, apartment, or
condominium.
Ethically, the PTS
simplifies the revenue system, leaving fewer decisions to
be made by politicians in favor of their backers. All the
essential facts are open to public scrutiny: the land's
owner, value, use, and levy. And since mere speculation
would no longer be profitable, owners would have less
monetary motive to try to unduly influence the political
process. ...
The PTS reduces the profit from land, making
land use less of a political football. Developers will
have less money to spend on distorting the democratic
process. Then society can more easily resolve land use
issues. ...
A big problem needs a big solution
which in turn needs a matching shift of our prevailing
paradigm. Geonomics -- advocating that we share the
social value of sites and natural resources and untax
earnings -- does just that.
Read the whole
article
|
To share this page with a friend:
right click, choose "send," and add your
comments.
|
|
Red links have not been
visited; .
Green links are pages you've seen
|
Essential Documents pertinent
to this theme:
|
|