Edwin Cannan
Mason Gaffney: A Cannan Gets the
Range
Edwin Cannan (1861-1935) is
best known for his 1904 edition of The
Wealth of Nations. His other best-known work is a
History of Theories of Production and
Distribution, 1893. His book most relevant here is
History of Local Rates in England,
1896. He was Professor at the London School of Economics,
1907-26, although a large inherited fortune let him
reside at Oxford and dabble at London part-time. He
criticized both Marshall and Keynes, although without
much effect. His later work drew little enthusiasm.
In 1907 Cannan fired off a round at local rating of
site values. It hit home. First he recited the logic of
what today we call the "tragedy of the commons" (it was
common coin long before Garrett Hardin). Then he pointed
out that a city taxing only site values to provide free
public services would attract too many people and too
much capital. A city is an "open economy," free to
immigration of everything but land, something like an
open range or fishery. Even if all
cities tax only site values, cities with more rents per
head may support public services at higher levels, and so
attract immigrants. This distorts locational decisions,
attracting people to jobs of lesser productivity where
they may gain from better public services. This is
"Cannan's Law."
There are three bad results from Cannan's Law.
- One is an uneconomical distribution of
population, as cities with more rentable lands attract
more of mobile labor and capital than they should.
That is not to deny that people are attracted to New
York for good economic reasons. Rather, it is that
distributing economic rent freely to all comers
attracts people above and beyond the good economic
reasons. Thus, people move to New York to earn high
wages, well and good; but in addition they may receive
a high quality college education from CCNY, the "poor
man's Harvard," paid from local property taxes. In the
glory days of the Mesabi iron range, children of
immigrant Finnish miners there in Hibbing, Minnesota,
enjoyed some of the best schooling in the country, paid
from local property taxes on iron ore. In Alaska and
Alberta, workers receive high wages to overcome the
harsh climate, remote locations, and other
disamenities. That is economically sound, but in
addition they get a cash dividend each year from the
overflowing oil revenues. All that tends to draw more
people, like flies swarming to fresh pie, than the
wages warrant.
- A second bad result is what economists call
"dissipation of economic rent." To make it simple,
consider a rich but crowded fishery where another
fishing boat added to the crowd will not raise the
total catch at all, but simply take fish from other
crews who were already there. Interlopers will keep
entering until the average boat and crew just make
costs, leaving no net rent for anyone. This has long
been standard economic lore. As Cannan writes, if a
locality uses its rents to benefit all its
"inhabitants," people will flock to the richest places
until there is no further gain to immigrants because
they have wiped out all the rent.
- A third bad result of Cannan's Law is to lower
the incentive of local governments to provide public
services that are open to all comers. It fosters
local institutions and attitudes that are harshly
hostile to newcomers and outsiders, especially to the
poor, young, homeless, hungry, and vagrant. As Woody
Guthrie, the Okie bard, sang of California, "Believe it
or not, you won't find it so hot, if you ain't got that
do-re-mi." That was in 1935; it is truer today.
Cannan goes on to say that if we are to tax site
values, the tax should be national. It is not clear how
sincere he is -- his style is carping, condescending,
elitist and unsympathetic. Still, his logic implies it,
and he does say it, however grudgingly. On this point the
great Alfred Marshall agreed, in a positive spirit
(positive, that is, for Marshall, a famously "two-handed"
economist). ... read the whole
article
Mason Gaffney: Canada's System of Revenue
Sharing
Cannan's Law
The last time I discussed this subject was in Las
Vegas before a tax group. I started out by saying 'I hope
there are no Canadians here!' It would be vain to say
that to this group, so I'll say I hope there are no sober
Canadians here, at least none who possess a high degree
of expertise on this subject, because I may have to skip
over some of the high spots. I lay some claim to being
Canadian myself, I should say. I have two children who
have dual citizenship because they originated in Canada,
or possibly three children depending on where you stand
on the right-to-life controversy. But at any rate I would
like to emphasise that the Canadian
system of revenue distribution, fiscal sharing, or
equalisation as we call it in Canada, is much more based
on correct principle than the one you find in the United
States. By 'correct principles' I mean the ones I
just enunciated.
At any rate, let's begin by looking at the
similarities between the federal systems in the United
States and Canada. In both countries we find something
called 'vertical balancing' which means that the
senior governments send money to the junior governments.
We find also something called 'horizontal
balancing' which means that the payments are made
more to the poorer governments, those that are poorer on
a per capita basis, than to richer ones. We have the
principle that the Crown may not tax the Crown. We've an
economic principle, which I'll call Cannan's Law. The cannan here is not a
weapon, but an economist of very little note, Edwin
Cannan, who however did make one very important point. He
made it in the period when the single tax in England was
on everyone's lips. And if you read the Economic
Journal, the stuffy, establishmentarian journal of
the economics profession, it's full of criticisms of the
Single Tax.
No respectable English economist could fail to write
at least one article criticising the Single Tax. And
Edwin Cannan criticised it in the following way. He said,
in effect, local taxation of land makes private land an
open range. His idea was something like Garret Hardin's
idea of the 'tragedy of the commons'. Or I should put it
the other way around because Hardin came later and he
obviously borrowed from those who wrote earlier. But
the general idea is, you may think you have tenure
control of land but if the municipal government can tax
that land and use that money to finance public welfare
services, public education and other things that are open
to all comers, then you will end up with an uneconomical
distribution of population. You'll have more people
clustered around the honey pot in places like Vancouver
where there's a lot of economic rent per capita than you
will in areas with less economic rent per capita.
So we found in the mining country of Northern
Minnesota back in the days when iron ore was worth
something. They had the best schools in the mid-west
there at the iron mines and all those Finnish miners'
kids got first rate educations. You run into them
everywhere now: they've become an awful nuisance -- very
well educated though.
All this tends to distort the economical allocation of
population and also to reduce the incentive of local
government to provide public services that are open to
all comers. That I refer to as Cannan' s Law. And you
find that, of course, in all countries. It's an economic
law. ... read the
whole article
|
To share this page with a friend:
right click, choose "send," and add your
comments.
|
|
Red links have not been
visited; .
Green links are pages you've seen
|
Essential Documents pertinent
to this theme:
|
|