Declaration of Independence
It isn't news that the process of living up to the
truths America's founding fathers held to be
self-evident is not yet complete. But some people
appear to think we're getting pretty close, and seek to
conserve the system
we've got, unwilling to consider the possibility that
we are falling short on some vital dimensions.
Georgists, however, see a major remaining distortion — and they know
how to remedy that
distortion.
Our founding fathers were all large landowners, and
it would not have occurred to them to limit the rights
of landholders in any way. But at a time when there was
still an open — seemingly limitless—
frontier, their perceptions might have been affected by
that. But they should have known enough about
conditions in Europe to anticipate what America would
be like as population increased.
Only 100 years later, with changes in technology and
the closing of the frontier, Henry George saw
significant poverty in America's cities. He sought the
explanation for what he saw, and recorded his search
— and the remedy
— in Progress
& Poverty.
Henry George: The
Common Sense of Taxation (1881 article)
Evidently this regard for the general good is the true
principle of taxation. The more it is examined the more
clearly it will be seen that there is no valid reason why
we should, in any case, attempt to tax all property. That
equality should be the rule and aim of taxation is true,
and this for the reason given in the Declaration of
Independence, that all men are created equal. But
equality does not require that all men should be taxed
alike, or that all things should be taxed alike. It
merely requires that whatever taxes are imposed shall be
equally imposed upon the persons or things in like
conditions or situations; it merely requires that no
citizen shall be given an advantage, or put at a
disadvantage, as compared with other citizens.
The true purposes of government are well stated in the
preamble to the Constitution of the United States, as
they are in the Declaration of Independence. To insure
the general peace, to promote the general welfare, to
secure to each individual the inalienable rights to life,
liberty, and the pursuit of happiness — these are
the proper ends of government, and are therefore the ends
which in every scheme of taxation should be kept in
mind.
As to amount of taxation, there is no principle which
imposes any arbitrary limit. Heavy taxation is better for
any community than light taxation, if the increased
revenue be used in doing by public agencies things which
could not be done, or could not be as well and
economically done, by private agencies. Taxes could be
lightened in the city of New York by dispensing with
street-lamps and disbanding the police force. But would a
reduction in taxation gained in this way be for the
benefit of the people of New York and make New York a
more desirable place to live in? Or if it should be found
that heat and light could be conducted through the
streets at public expense and supplied to each house at
but a small fraction of the cost of supplying them by
individual effort, or that the city railroads could be
run at public expense so as to give every one
transportation at very much less than it now costs the
average resident, the increased taxation necessary for
these purposes would not be increased burden, and in
spite of the larger taxation required, New York would
become a more desirable place to live in. It is a mistake
to condemn taxation as bad merely because it is high; it
is a mistake to impose by constitutional provision, as in
many of our States has been advocated, and in some of our
States has been done, any restriction upon the amount of
taxation. A restriction upon the incurring of public
indebtedness is another matter. In nothing is the
far-reaching statesmanship of Jefferson more clearly
shown than in his proposition that all public obligations
should be deemed void after a certain brief term —
a proposition which he grounds upon the self-evident
truth that the earth belongs in usufruct to the living,
and that the dead have no control over it, and can give
no title to any part of it. But restriction upon public
debts is a very different thing from restriction upon the
power of taxation, and reasons which urge the one do not
apply to the other. Nor is increased taxation necessarily
proof of governmental extravagance. Increase in taxation
is in the order of social development, for the reason
that social development tends to the doing of things
collectively that in a ruder state are done individually,
to the giving to government of new functions and the
imposing of new duties. Our public schools and libraries
and parks, our signal service and fish commissions and
agricultural bureaus and grasshopper investigations, are
evidences of this.
But while no limit can be properly fixed for the
amount of taxation, the method of taxation is of supreme
importance. A horse may be anchored by fastening to his
bridle a weight which he will not feel when carried in a
buggy behind him. The best ship may be made utterly
unseaworthy by the bad stowage of a cargo which properly
placed would make her the stiffer and more weatherly. So
enterprise may be palsied, industry crushed, accumulation
prevented, and a prosperous country turned into a desert,
by taxation which rightly levied would hardly be
felt.
Now discarding all idea that there rests upon us any
obligation to equally tax all kinds of property, and
assuming for our guidance the true rule, that taxation
should be levied with a view to the promotion of the
general prosperity, the securing of substantial equality,
and the recognition of inalienable rights, let us
consider upon what species of property it may be best
laid. ...
... The possession of wealth is the inducement to the
exertion necessary to the production and maintenance of
wealth. Men do not work for the pleasure of working, but
to get the things their work will give them. And to tax
the things that are produced by exertion is to lessen the
inducement to exertion. But over and above the benefit to
the possessor, which is the stimulating motive to the
production of wealth, there is a benefit to the
community, for no matter how selfish he may be, it is
utterly impossible for any one to entirely keep to
himself the benefit of any desirable thing he may
possess. These diffused benefits when localized give
value to land, and this may be taxed without in any wise
diminishing the incentive to production.
To illustrate: A man builds a fine house or large
factory in a poorly improved neighborhood. To tax this
building and its adjuncts is to make him pay for his
enterprise and expenditure — to take from him part
of his natural reward. But the improvement thus made has
given new beauty or life to the neighborhood, making it a
more desirable place than before for the erection of
other houses or factories, and additional value is given
to land all about. Now to tax improvements is not only to
deprive of his proper reward the man who has made the
improvement, but it is to deter others from making
similar improvements. But, instead of taxing
improvements, to tax these land values is to leave the
natural inducement to further improvement in full force,
and at the same time to keep down an obstacle to further
improvement, which, under the present system, improvement
itself tends to raise. For the advance of land values
which follows improvement, and even the expectation of
improvement, makes further improvement more costly.
See how unjust and short-sighted is this system. Here
is a man who, gathering what little capital he can, and
taking his family, starts West to find a place where he
can make himself a home. He must travel long distances;
for, though he will pass plenty of land nobody is using,
it is held at prices too high for him. Finally he will go
no further, and selects a place where, since the creation
of the world, the soil, so far as we know, has never felt
a plowshare. But here, too, in nine cases out of ten, he
will find the speculator has been ahead of him, for the
speculator moves quicker, and has superior means of
information to the emigrant. Before he can put this land
to the use for which nature intended it, and to which it
is for the general good that it should be put, he must
make terms with some man who in all probability never saw
the land, and never dreamed of using it, and who, it may
be, resides in some city, thousands of miles away. In
order to get permission to use this land, he must give up
a large part of the little capital which is seed-wheat to
him, and perhaps in addition mortgage his future labor
for years. Still he goes to work: he works himself, and
his wife works, and his children work — work like
horses, and live in the hardest and dreariest manner.
Such a man deserves encouragement, not discouragement;
but on him taxation falls with peculiar severity. Almost
everything that he has to buy — groceries,
clothing, tools — is largely raised in price by a
system of tariff taxation which cannot add to the price
of the grain or hogs or cattle that he has to sell. And
when the assessor comes around he is taxed on the
improvements he has made, although these improvements
have added not only to the value of surrounding land, but
even to the value of land in distant commercial centers.
Not merely this, but, as a general rule, his land,
irrespective of the improvements, will be assessed at a
higher rate than unimproved land around it, on the ground
that "productive property" ought to pay more than
"unproductive property" — a principle just the
reverse of the correct one, for the man who makes land
productive adds to the general prosperity, while the man
who keeps land unproductive stands in the way of the
general prosperity, is but a dog-in-the-manger, who
prevents others from using what he will not use
himself.
Or, take the case of the railroads. That railroads are
a public benefit no one will dispute. We want more
railroads, and want them to reduce their fares and
freight. Why then should we tax them? for taxes upon
railroads deter from railroad building, and compel higher
charges. Instead of taxing the railroads, is it not clear
that we should rather tax the increased value which they
give to land? To tax railroads is to check railroad
building, to reduce profits, and compel higher rates; to
tax the value they give to land is to increase railroad
business and permit lower rates. The elevated railroads,
for instance, have opened to the overcrowded population
of New York the wide, vacant spaces of the upper part of
the island. But this great public benefit is neutralized
by the rise in land values. Because these vacant lots can
be reached more cheaply and quickly, their owners demand
more for them, and so the public gain in one way is
offset in another, while the roads lose the business they
would get were not building checked by the high prices
demanded for lots. The increase of land values, which the
elevated roads have caused, is not merely no advantage to
them — it is an injury; and it is clearly a public
injury. The elevated railroads ought not to be taxed. The
more profit they make, with the better conscience can
they be asked to still further reduce fares. It is the
increased land values which they have created that ought
to be taxed, for taxing them will give the public the
full benefit of cheap fares.
So with railroads everywhere. And so not alone with
railroads, but with all industrial enterprises. So long
as we consider that community most prosperous which
increases most rapidly in wealth, so long is it the
height of absurdity for us to tax wealth in any of its
beneficial forms. We should tax what we want to repress,
not what we want to encourage. We should tax that which
results from the general prosperity, not that which
conduces to it. It is the increase of population, the
extension of cultivation, the manufacture of goods, the
building of houses and ships and railroads, the
accumulation of capital, and the growth of commerce that
add to the value of land — not the increase in the
value of land that induces the increase of population and
increase of wealth. It is not that the land of Manhattan
Island is now worth hundreds of millions where, in the
time of the early Dutch settlers, it was only worth
dollars, that there are on it now so many more people,
and so much more wealth. It is because of the increase of
population and the increase of wealth that the value of
the land has so much increased. Increase of land values
tends of itself to repel population and prevent
improvement. And thus the taxation of land values, unlike
taxation of other property, does not tend to prevent the
increase of wealth, but rather to stimulate it. It is the
taking of the golden egg, not the choking of the goose
that lays it.
Every consideration of policy and ethics squares with
this conclusion. The tax upon land values is the most
economically perfect of all taxes. It does not raise
prices; it maybe collected at least cost, and with the
utmost ease and certainty; it leaves in full strength all
the springs of production; and, above all, it consorts
with the truest equality and the highest justice. For, to
take for the common purposes of the community that value
which results from the growth of the community, and to
free industry and enterprise and thrift from burden and
restraint, is to leave to each that which he fairly
earns, and to assert the first and most comprehensive of
equal rights — the equal right of all to the land
on which, and from which, all must live.
Thus it is that the scheme of taxation which conduces
to the greatest production is also that which conduces to
the fairest distribution, and that in the proper
adjustment of taxation lies not merely the possibility of
enormously increasing the general wealth, but the
solution of these pressing social and political problems
which spring from unnatural inequality in the
distribution of wealth.
"There is," says M. de Laveleye, in concluding that
work in which he shows that the first perceptions of
mankind have everywhere recognized a most vital
distinction between property in land and property which
results from labor, — "there is in human affairs
one system which is the best; it is not that system which
always exists, otherwise why should we desire to change
it; but it is that system which should exist for the
greatest good of humanity. God knows it, and wills it;
man's duty it is to discover and establish it." read the whole
article
H.G. Brown:
Significant Paragraphs from Henry George's
Progress & Poverty: 14
Liberty, and Equality of Opportunity (in the unabridged
P&P:
Part X: The Law of Human Progress — Chapter 5: The
Central Truth)
... The reform I have proposed accords with all that
is politically, socially, or morally desirable. It has
the qualities of a true reform, for it will make all
other reforms easier. What is it but the carrying out in
letter and spirit of the truth enunciated in the
Declaration of Independence — the "self-evident"
truth that is the heart and soul of the Declaration
—"That all men are created equal; that they are
endowed by their Creator with certain inalienable rights;
that among these are life, liberty, and the pursuit of
happiness!"
These rights are denied when the equal right to land
— on which and by which men alone can live —
is denied. Equality of political rights will not
compensate for the denial of the equal right to the
bounty of nature. Political liberty, when the equal right
to land is denied, becomes, as population increases and
invention goes on, merely the liberty to compete for
employment at starvation wages. This is the
truth that we have ignored. ...
Our primary social adjustment is a denial of
justice. In allowing one man to own the land on which and
from which other men must live, we have made them his
bondsmen in a degree which increases as material progress
goes on. This is the subtile alchemy that in
ways they do not realize is extracting from the masses in
every civilized country the fruits of their weary toil;
that is instituting a harder and more hopeless slavery in
place of that which has been destroyed; that is bringing
political despotism out of political freedom, and must
soon transmute democratic institutions into anarchy.
It is this that turns the blessings of material
progress into a curse. It is this that crowds human
beings into noisome cellars and squalid tenement houses;
that fills prisons and brothels; that goads men with want
and consumes them with greed; that robs women of the
grace and beauty of perfect womanhood; that takes from
little children the joy and innocence of life's
morning.
Civilization so based cannot continue. The
eternal laws of the universe forbid it. Ruins of
dead empires testify, and the witness that is in every
soul answers, that it cannot be. It is something grander
than Benevolence, something more august than Charity
— it is Justice herself that demands of us to right
this wrong. Justice that will not be denied; that cannot
be put off — Justice that with the scales carries
the sword. Shall we ward the stroke with liturgies and
prayers? Shall we avert the decrees of immutable law by
raising churches when hungry infants moan and weary
mothers weep?
Though it may take the language of prayer, it is
blasphemy that attributes to the inscrutable decrees of
Providence the suffering and brutishness that come of
poverty; that turns with folded hands to the All-Father
and lays on Him the responsibility for the want and crime
of our great cities. ...
Between democratic ideas and the aristocratic
adjustments of society there is an irreconcilable
conflict. Here in the United States, as there in Europe,
it may be seen arising.
- We cannot go on permitting men to vote and forcing
them to tramp.
- We cannot go on educating boys and girls in our
public schools and then refusing them the right to earn
an honest living.
- We cannot go on prating of the inalienable rights
of man and then denying the inalienable right to the
bounty of the Creator. ...
read the whole chapter
Henry George: Salutatory, from the
first issue of The Standard (1887)
I begin the publication of this paper in response to
many urgent requests, and because I believe that there is
a field for a journal that shall serve as a focus for
news and opinions relating to the great movement, now
beginning, for the emancipation of labor by the
restoration of natural rights.
The generation that abolished chattel slavery is
passing away, and the political distinctions that grew
out of that contest are becoming meaningless. The work
now before us is the abolition of industrial slavery.
What God created for the use of all should be utilized
for the benefit of all; what is produced by the
individual belongs rightfully to the individual. The
neglect of these simple principles has brought upon us
the curse of widespread poverty and all the evils that
flow from it. Their recognition will abolish poverty,
will secure to the humblest independence and leisure, and
will lay abroad and strong foundation on which all other
reforms may be based. To secure the full recognition of
these principles is the most important task to which any
man can address himself today. It is in the hope of
aiding in this work that I establish this paper.
I believe that the Declaration of Independence is not
a mere string of glittering generalities. I believe that
all men are really created equal, and that the securing
of those equal natural rights is the true purpose and
test of government. And against whatever law, custom or
device that restrains men in the exercise of their
natural rights to life, liberty, and the pursuit of
happiness I shall raise my voice. ... read the whole
column
Henry George: The Land Question
(1881)
What is the slave-trade but piracy of the worst kind?
Yet it is not long since the slave-trade was looked upon
as a perfectly respectable business, affording as
legitimate an opening for the investment of capital and
the display of enterprise as any other. The proposition
to prohibit it was first looked upon as ridiculous, then
as fanatical, then as wicked. It was only slowly and by
hard fighting that the truth in regard to it gained
ground. Does not our very Constitution bear witness to
what I say? Does not the fundamental law of the nation,
adopted twelve years after the enunciation of the
Declaration of Independence, declare that for twenty
years the slave-trade shall not be prohibited nor
restricted? Such dominion had the idea of vested
interests over the minds of those who had already
proclaimed the inalienable right of man to life, liberty,
and the pursuit of happiness! ... read
the whole article
Henry George: The Wages of
Labor
Though the rich were to “bestow all their goods
to feed the poor and give their bodies to be
burned,” poverty would continue while property in
land continued.
Take the case of the
rich man today who is honestly desirous of devoting his
wealth to the improvement of the condition of labor. What
can he do?
- Bestow his wealth on those
who need it? He may help some who
deserve it, but he will not improve general conditions.
And against the good he may do will be the danger of
doing harm.
- Build churches?
Under the shadow of churches poverty festers and the vice
that is born of it breeds!
- Build schools and
colleges? Save as it may lead men to see the
iniquity of private property in land, increased education
can effect nothing for mere laborers, for as education is
diffused the wages of education sink!
- Establish
hospitals? Why, already it seems to laborers
that there are too many seeking work, and to save and
prolong life is to add to the pressure!
- Build model
tenements? Unless he cheapens house
accommodation he but drives further the class he would
benefit, and as he cheapens house accommodation he brings
more to seek employment, and cheapens wages!
- Institute laboratories,
scientific schools, workshops far physical
experiments? He but stimulates
invention and discovery, the very forces that, acting on
a society based on private property in land, are crushing
labor as between the upper and the nether
millstone!
- Promote emigration from
places where wages are low to places where they are
somewhat higher? If he does, even those whom
he at first helps to emigrate will soon turn on him and
demand that such emigration shall be stopped as reducing
their wages!
- Give away what land he may
have, or refuse to take rent for it, or let it at lower
rents than the market price? He will simply
make new landowners or partial landowners; he may make
some individuals the richer, but he will do nothing to
improve the general condition of labor.
- Or, bethinking himself of
those public-spirited citizens of classic times who spent
great sums in improving their native cities, shall he try
to beautify the city of his birth or
adoption? Let him widen and straighten
narrow and crooked streets, let him build parks and erect
fountains, let him open tramways and bring in railways,
or in any way make beautiful and attractive his chosen
city, and what will be the result? Must it not be that
those who appropriate God’s bounty will take his
also? Will it not be that the value of
land will go up, and that the net result of his
benefactions will be an increase of rents and a bounty to
landowners? Why,
even the mere announcement that he is going to do such
things will start speculation and send up the value of
land by leaps and bounds.
What, then, can the rich man do to improve the
condition of labor?
He can do nothing at all except
to use his strength for the abolition of the great
primary wrong that robs men of their
birthright.
The justice of God laughs at the attempts of men
to substitute anything else for it!
In speaking of measures for improving
social conditions, it seems to us that in the teachings of
morality is to be found the highest practicality, and that
the question, What is wise may always safely be
subordinated to the question, what is right?
But expressed moral truths are
deprived of all practical meaning when accompanied by
unjust sanctions as when the American people, while they
legalised chattel slavery, were accustomed to read solemnly
on every national anniversary the declaration which
asserts: “We hold these truths to be self-evident
that all men are created equal and are endowed by their
Creator with certain inalienable rights; that among these
are life, liberty, and the pursuit of
happiness.”
What did this truth mean on the lips
of men who asserted that one man was the rightful property
of another man who had bought him, who asserted that the
slave was robbing the master in running away, and that the
man or the woman who helped the fugitive to escape, or even
gave him a cup of cold water in Christ’s name, was an
accessory to theft, on whose head the penalties of the
State should be visited? ... read the whole
article
Lindy Davies: Land and Justice
I'm here today as a "Single Taxer". If you don't recall
quite what that is, let me first say that it’s
NOT Steve Forbes’s “flat tax!” No.
The Single Tax is actually a comprehensive program for
economic justice and environmental sustainability. It
was stated most memorably by the American economist
Henry George in his 1879 book Progress and Poverty
— and affirmed by a great many important
thinkers, before and since. The idea is for society to
collect the rental value of land for public revenue
— and to abolish all other taxes on the
production and exchange of wealth. It came to be known
at the “Single Tax” because of this
proposal that the rent of land should be the sole
source of public revenue.
Single Taxers have been ridiculed somewhat, over the
years, for peddling a panacea, offering a cure for
poverty, depressions, urban blight, potholes, the common
cold and the heartbreak of psoriasis. Well, I don’t
claim to have a cure for every bad thing. But I do want
to talk to you making the necessary economic arrangements
to create a just society, in which there would be equal
opportunity for all, and in which we could confidently
look ahead to all our children’s futures.
Single taxers have also caught some grief for always
saying “It’s all about the land!”
But I’m not going to apologize for that! I want
to explain to you why the issues of economic justice and
sustainability actually ARE all about the land.
The theme of this week’s program is Land and
Justice. Those are two words that we use so often that we
tend to take their meanings for granted. It might be
helpful to stop and think about what they truly mean.
Justice is often seen as the fair retribution for
something done wrong, as in "justice was done" when a
criminal is sent to jail. George W. Bush vowed, for
example, to bring the 9-11 terrorists to justice.
However, that conception of justice — in which
one does good, in order to avoid the consequences of not
doing good — is actually an immature one. In the
stages of moral development identified by psychologist
Lawrence Kohlberg, this is called the "conventional"
stage. Maturity comes in the "post-conventional" stage,
when we come to value doing good so as to contribute to
our community, or, even, doing good for its own sake.
Jesus was hip to that, in his scorn for the
loudly-praying pharisees on the street corners. They
already have their reward, he said. He set much greater
store by good deeds done without thought of reward:
"whatever you do to the least of my brothers and sisters,
you to do me also." And, even more to the point, the
prophet Micah enjoins us to "Do justice and love
mercy."
So, what is "doing justice," in this positive sense?
If I do something nice for the least of my brothers and
sisters, have I done justice? If I send them a handmade
quilt?
Not really. I think the least of my brothers and
sisters, cold though they might be, would resent my
presuming to know exactly how to handle their problem;
perhaps they'd rather make their own quilt, or build a
fireplace, or move to a warmer place.
Justice must have to do with freedom. To do justice,
then, is to secure, in Thomas Jefferson's words, people's
inalienable rights: life, liberty and the pursuit of
happiness.
The most basic of those rights is life. (In this day
and age, though, even that is controversial... There's a
great deal of passionate contention about the troubling
special cases of the very beginning, or the very end of
life — but it seems to me that we ought to pay more
attention to every single human being's right to
live!)
Be that as it may: we all pretty much understand
basically what human life is, and what its basic
requirements are: food, clothing and shelter.
...
Now it is interesting to note that the economic vision
presented in the bible is not a precursor of communism.
Two of the ten commandments explicitly support the
institution of private property, and the prophets
consistently railed against landlords and rulers who
robbed the people of the fruits of their labor. The laws
of Leviticus, which Jesus said he "came not to destroy
but to fulfill," envisioned a community in which everyone
was secure in his own home and property, "beneath his
vine and fig tree".
(Incidentally, the quote on the American Liberty Bell,
from Leviticus, chapter 25, was a direct reference to
these principles : "Proclaim liberty throughout the land
and to all the people thereof." It was a reference to the
Jubilee, and the freedom it provided was from debt and
servitude.)
The division is clear: there is to be a sacred right
of private property in the things that are made by
people. But people were not to own the things that were
made by God. The 7th commandment sums up both principles
in 4 words: Thou shalt not steal.
Modern society has looked away from these principles,
calling them quaint, naive, inapplicable to the
complexities of our time — yet, modern society
finds itself mired in chronic economic and social
problems for which it can find no solutions — and
which threaten to pull down all the advances of
civilization into a dark age — occasioned by some
combination of war, financial implosion or ecological
collapse.
If there is any way out of this dark future, it can
only come by way of solving the problem of land and
justice.
Fortunately, there exists a plan for that.
This plan takes the shape of a "fiscal reform",
because it applies a definition of the relationship
between the individual and the society that is consistent
with both economic efficiency and moral law. It calls for
us to respect the right of labor to create and to save
wealth, and we acknowledge that the value of land is
created not by its “owners”, but by the
entire community.
Therefore, we will abolish all taxes on income,
products and sales — and collect the full rental
value of land and other natural resources for public
revenue. ...
Eventually, I believe that human society will adopt
the biblical and georgist wisdom, and organize itself as
it must, to achieve justice, efficiency and
sustainability.
Eventually we will have tried everything else. That's
how Clarence Darrow — one of the reform's many
prominent supporters — saw things. He said this:
“The “single tax” is so simple, so
fundamental, and so easy to carry into effect that I have
no doubt that it will be about the last reform the world
will ever get. People in this world are not often
logical.”
True enough. Yet I have to believe that eventually the
obvious truth will start to dawn on us. ... read the whole
speech
Henry George: The Land Question
(1881)
What I want to impress upon those who may read
this book is this:
The land question is nowhere a mere local
question; it is a universal question. It involves the
great problem of the distribution of wealth, which is
everywhere forcing itself upon attention.
It cannot be settled by measures which in their
nature can have but local application. It can be settled
only by measures which in their nature will apply
everywhere.
It cannot be settled by half-way measures. It can
be settled only by the acknowledgment of equal rights to
land. Upon this basis it can be settled easily and
permanently.
If the Irish reformers take this ground, they will
make their fight the common fight of all the peoples;
they will concentrate strength and divide opposition.
They will turn the flank of the system that oppresses
them, and awake the struggle in its very intrenchments.
They will rouse against it a force that is like the force
of rising tides.
What I urge the men of Ireland to do is to
proclaim, without limitation or evasion, that the land,
of natural right, is the common property of the whole
people, and to propose practical measures which will
recognize this right in all countries as well as in
Ireland.
What I urge the Land Leagues of the United States
to do is to announce this great principle as of universal
application; to give their movement a reference to
America as well as to Ireland; to broaden and deepen and
strengthen it by making it a movement for the
regeneration of the world – a movement which shall
concentrate and give shape to aspirations that are
stirring among all nations.
Ask not for Ireland mere charity or sympathy. Let
her call be the call of fraternity: "For
yourselves, O brothers, as well as for us!" Let her
rallying cry awake all who slumber, and rouse to a common
struggle all who are oppressed. Let it breathe not old
hates; let it ring and echo with the new
hope!
In many lands her sons are true to her; under many
skies her daughters burn with the love of her. Lo! the
ages bring their opportunity. Let those who would honor
her bear her banner to the front!
The harp and the shamrock, the golden sunburst on
the field of living green! emblems of a country without
nationality; standard of a people downtrodden and
oppressed! The hour has come when they may lead the van
of the great world-struggle. Types of harmony and of
ever-springing hope, of light and of life! The hour has
come when they may stand for something higher than local
patriotism; something grander than national independence.
The hour has come when they may stand forth to speak the
world's hope, to lead the world's advance!
Torn away by pirates, tending in a strange land a
heathen master's swine, the slave boy, with the spirit of
Christ in his heart, praying in the snow for those who
had enslaved him, and returning to bring to his
oppressors the message of the gospel, returning with good
to give where evil had been received, to kindle in the
darkness a great light–this is Ireland's patron
saint. In his spirit let Ireland's struggle be. Not
merely through Irish vales and hamlets, but into England,
into Scotland, into Wales, wherever our common tongue is
spoken, let the torch be carried and the word be
preached. And beyond! The brotherhood of man stops not
with differences of speech any more than with seas or
mountain-chains. A century ago it was ours to speak the
ringing word. Then it was France's. Now it may be
Ireland's, if her sons be true.
But wherever, or by whom, the word must be spoken,
the standard will be raised. No matter what the Irish
leaders do or do not do, it is too late to settle
permanently the question on any basis short of the
recognition of equal natural right. And, whether the Land
Leagues move forward or slink back, the agitation must
spread to this side of the Atlantic. The Republic, the
true Republic, is not yet here. But her birth-struggle
must soon begin. Already, with the hope of her, men's
thoughts are stirring.
Not a republic of landlords and peasants; not a
republic of millionaires and tramps; not a republic in
which some are masters and some serve. But a republic of
equal citizens, where competition becomes cooperation,
and the interdependence of all gives true independence to
each; where moral progress goes hand in hand with
intellectual progress, and material progress elevates and
enfranchises even the poorest and weakest and
lowliest.
And the gospel of deliverance, let us not forget
it: it is the gospel of love, not of hate. He whom it
emancipates will know neither Jew nor Gentile, nor
Irishman nor Englishman, nor German nor Frenchman, nor
European nor American, nor difference of color or of
race, nor animosities of class or condition. Let us set
our feet on old prejudices, let us bury the old hates.
There have been "Holy Alliances" of kings. Let us strive
for the Holy Alliance of the people.
Liberty, equality, fraternity!
Write them on the banners. Let them be for sign and
countersign. Without equality, liberty cannot be; without
fraternity, neither equality nor liberty can be
achieved.
- Liberty–the full freedom of each bounded
only by the equal freedom of every other!
- Equality–the equal right of each to the
use and enjoyment of all natural opportunities, to all
the essentials of happy, healthful, human
life!
- Fraternity–that sympathy which links
together those who struggle in a noble cause; that would
live and let live; that would help as well as be helped;
that, in seeking the good of all, finds the highest good
of each!
"By this sign shall ye conquer!"
"We hold these truths to be
self-evident–that all men are created equal; that
they are endowed by their Creator with certain
unalienable rights; that among these are life, liberty,
and the pursuit of happiness!"
It is over a century since these words rang out.
It is time to give them their full, true meaning. Let the
standard be lifted that all may see it; let the advance
be sounded that all may hear it. Let those who would fall
back, fall back. Let those who would oppose, oppose.
Everywhere are those who will rally. The stars in their
courses fight against Sisera!... read the whole
article
Peter Barnes:
Capitalism 3.0 — Chapter 7: Universal Birthrights
(pages 101-116)
The Idea of Birthrights
John Locke’s response to royalty’s claim
of divine right was the idea of everyone’s inherent
right to life, liberty, and property. Thomas Jefferson,
in drafting America’s Declaration of Independence,
changed Locke’s trinity to life, liberty, and the
pursuit of happiness. These, Jefferson and his
collaborators agreed, are gifts from the creator that
can’t be taken away. Put slightly differently,
they’re universal birthrights.
The Constitution and its amendments added meat to
these elegant bones. They guaranteed such birthrights as
free speech, due process, habeas corpus, speedy public
trials, and secure homes and property. Wisely, the Ninth
Amendment affirmed that “the enumeration in the
Constitution, of certain rights, shall not be construed
to deny or disparage others retained by the
people.” In that spirit, others have since been
added.
If we were to analyze the expansion of American
birthrights, we’d see a series of waves. The first
wave consisted of rights against the state. The second
included rights against unequal treatment based on race,
nationality, gender, or sexual orientation. The third
wave — which, historically speaking, is just
beginning — consists of rights not against things,
but for things — free public education, collective
bargaining for wages, security in old age. They can be
thought of as rights necessary for the pursuit of
happiness.
What makes this latest wave of birthrights strengthen
community is their universality. If some Americans could
enjoy free public education while others couldn’t,
the resulting inequities would divide rather than unite
us as a nation. The universality of these rights puts
everyone in the same boat. It spreads risk,
responsibility, opportunity, and reward across race,
gender, economic classes, and generations. It makes us a
nation rather than a collection of isolated
individuals.
Universality is also what distinguishes the commons
sector from the corporate sector. The starting condition
for the corporate sector, as we’ve seen, is that
the top 5 percent owns more shares than everyone else.
The starting condition for the commons sector, by
contrast, is one person, one share.
The standard argument against third wave universal
birthrights is that, while they might be nice in theory,
in practice they are too expensive. They impose an
unbearable burden on “the economy” —
that is, on the winners in unfettered markets. Much
better, therefore, to let everyone — including poor
children and the sick — fend for themselves. In
fact, the opposite is often true: universal birthrights,
as we’ll see, can be cheaper and more efficient
than individual acquisition. Moreover, they are always
fairer.
How far we might go down the path of extending
universal birthrights is anyone’s guess, but
we’re now at the point where, economically
speaking, we can afford to go farther. Without great
difficulty, we could add three birthrights to our
economic operating system: one would pay everyone a
regular dividend, the second would give every child a
start-up stake, and the third would reduce and share
medical costs. Whether we add these birthrights or not
isn’t a matter of economic ability, but of attitude
and politics.
Why attitude? Americans suffer from a number of
confusions. We think it’s “wrong” to
give people “something for nothing,” despite
the fact that corporations take common wealth for nothing
all the time. We believe the poor are poor and the rich
are rich because they deserve to be, but don’t
consider that millions of Americans work two or three
jobs and still can’t make ends meet. Plus, we think
tinkering with the “natural” distribution of
income is “socialism,” or “big
government,” or some other manifestation of evil,
despite the fact that our current distribution of income
isn’t “natural” at all, but rigged from
the get-go by maldistributed property.
The late John Rawls, one of America’s leading
philosophers, distinguished between pre distribution of
property and re distribution of income. Under income re
distribution, money is taken from “winners”
and transferred to “losers.” Understandably,
this isn’t popular with winners, who tend to
control government and the media. Under property pre
distribution, by contrast, the playing field is leveled
by spreading property ownership before income is
generated. After that, there’s no need for income
redistribution; property itself distributes income to
all. According to Rawls, while income re distribution
creates dependency, property predistribution
empowers.
But how can we spread property ownership without
taking property from some and giving it to others? The
answer lies in the commons — wealth that already
belongs to everyone. By propertizing (without
privatizing) some of that wealth, we can make everyone a
property owner.
What’s interesting is that, for purely
ecological reasons, we need to propertize (without
privatizing) some natural wealth now. This twenty-first
century necessity means we have a chance to save the
planet, and as a bonus, add a universal birthright. ...
read the whole chapter
Nic Tideman: A Bill
of Economic Rights and Obligations
Our nation was founded on the idea that we are all
created equal, that we are endowed by our Creator with
certain inalienable rights, and that among these are
life, liberty, and the pursuit of happiness.
In living, expressing our liberty, and pursuing
happiness we sometimes conflict with one another, so we
need a shared understanding of the extent of the sphere
of equal rights given to every person, and beyond that
sphere our obligation to respect the rights of others.
This Bill is concerned with the economic aspects of these
rights and obligations. ... read the whole
article
|
To share this page with a friend:
right click, choose "send," and add your
comments.
|
|
Red links have not been
visited; .
Green links are pages you've seen
|
Essential Documents pertinent
to this theme:
|
|