Under the Protection of
Government
Louis Post: Outlines of Louis F. Post's
Lectures, with Illustrative Notes and Charts (1894)
— Appendix: FAQ
Q54. Is it right that the owners of land should
pay all the taxes for the support of public institutions,
while the owners of commodities go untaxed?
A. Yes. Public institutions increase the value of land
but not of commodities. Read notes 14 and 18. ...
read the
book
Nic Tideman:
A Bill of Economic Rights and Obligations
Article 3: All persons, in all generations,
have equal rights to natural opportunities, such as the
use of land, natural resources, and the frequency
spectrum. Therefore Congress shall place levies on states
to equalize among states the per capita annual value of
access to natural opportunities, and to compensate for
the harmful effects of activities in states on other
states and on future generations. State legislatures
shall place corresponding levies on their
subdivisions.
Article 4: Congress may place levies on states
to collect from states a portion of the benefits they
receive from national defense, national systems of
infrastructure, research of national significance, or any
private activity that has widespread public benefits.
State legislatures may place corresponding levies on
their subdivisions.
Peter Barnes:
Capitalism 3.0 — Chapter 5: Reinventing the Commons
(pages 65-78)
Common wealth is like the dark matter of the economic
universe — it’s everywhere, but we
don’t see it. One reason we don’t see it is
that much of it is, literally, invisible. Who can spot
the air, an aquifer, or the social trust that underlies
financial markets? The more relevant reason is our own
blindness: the only economic matter we notice is the kind
that glistens with dollar signs. We ignore common wealth
because it lacks price tags and property rights.
I first began to appreciate common wealth when Working
Assets launched its socially screened money market fund.
My job was to write advertisements that spurred people to
send us large sums of money. Our promise was that
we’d make this money grow, without investing in
really bad companies, and send it back — including
the growth, but minus our management fee — any time
the investor requested. It struck me as quite remarkable
that people who didn’t know us from a hole in the
wall would send us substantial portions of their savings.
Why, I wondered, did they trust us?
The answer, of course, was that they didn’t
trust us, they trusted the system in which we
operated. They trusted that we’d prudently manage
their savings not because we’d personally
earned their confidence, but because they knew that if we
didn’t, the Securities and Exchange Commission or
some district attorney would bust us. Beyond that, they
trusted that the corporations we invested in were honest
in computing their incomes and reliable in meeting their
obligations. That trust, and the larger system it’s
based on, were built over generations, and we had nothing
to do with it. In short, although Working Assets provided
a service people willingly paid for, we also profited
from a larger system we’d simply inherited.
I got another whiff of common wealth when Working
Assets considered going public — that is, selling
stock to strangers through an initial public offering.
Our investment banker informed us that, simply by going
public, we’d increase the value of our stock by 30
percent. He called this magic a liquidity
premium. What he meant was that stock that can be
sold in a market of millions is worth more than stock
that has almost no market at all. This extra value would
come not from anything we did, but from the socially
created bonus of liquidity. We’d be reaping what
others sowed. (In the end, we didn’t go public
because we didn’t want to be subjected to Wall
Street’s calculus.)
Trust and liquidity, I eventually realized, are just
two small rivulets in an enormous river of common wealth
that encompasses nature, community, and culture.
Nature’s gifts are all those wondrous things,
living and nonliving, that we inherit from the creation.
Community includes the myriad threads, tangible and
intangible, that connect us to other humans efficiently.
Culture embodies our vast store of science, inventions,
and art. ...
read the whole chapter
Peter Barnes:
Capitalism 3.0 — Chapter 7: Universal Birthrights
(pages 101-116)
Dividends from Common Assets
A cushion of reliable income is a wonderful thing. It
can be saved for rainy days or used to pursue happiness
on sunny days. It can encourage people to take risks,
care for friends and relatives, or volunteer for
community service. For low-income families, it can pay
for basic necessities.
Conversely, the absence of reliable income is a
terrible thing. It heightens anxiety and fear. It
diminishes our ability to cope with crises and
transitions. It traps many families on the knife’s
edge of poverty, and makes it harder for the poor to
rise.
So why don’t we, as Monopoly does, pay everyone
some regular income — not through redistribution of
income, but through predistribution of common property?
One state — Alaska — already does this. As
noted earlier, the Alaska Permanent Fund uses revenue
from state oil leases to invest in stocks, bonds, and
similar assets, and from those investments pays yearly
dividends to every resident. Alaska’s model can be
extended to any state or nation, whether or not they have
oil. We could, for instance, have an American Permanent
Fund that pays equal dividends to long-term residents of
all 50 states. The reason is, we jointly own many
valuable assets.
Recall our discussion about common property trusts.
These trusts could crank down pollution and earn money
from selling ever-scarcer pollution permits. The scarcer
the permits get, the higher their prices would go. Less
pollution would equal more revenue. Over time, trillions
of dollars could flow into an American Permanent
Fund.
What could we do with that common income? In Alaska
the deal with oil revenue is 75 percent to government and
25 percent to citizens. For an American Permanent Fund,
I’d favor a 50/50 split, because paying dividends
to citizens is so important. Also, when scarce ecosystems
are priced above zero, the cost of living will go up and
people will need compensation; this wasn’t, and
isn’t, the case in Alaska. I’d also favor
earmarking the government’s dollars for specific
public goods, rather than tossing them into the general
treasury. This not only ensures identifiable public
benefits; it also creates constituencies who’ll
defend the revenue sharing system.
Waste absorption isn’t the only common resource
an American Permanent Fund could tap. Consider also, the
substantial contribution society makes to stock market
values. As noted earlier, private corporations can
inflate their value dramatically by selling shares on a
regulated stock exchange. The extra value derives from
the enlarged market of investors who can now buy the
corporation’s shares. Given a total stock market
valuation of about $15 trillion, this socially created
liquidity premium is worth roughly $5 trillion.
At the moment, this $5 trillion gift flows mostly to
the 5 percent of the population that own more than half
the private wealth. But if we wanted to, we could spread
it around. We could do that by charging corporations for
using the public trading system, just as investment
bankers do. (For those of you who haven’t been
involved in a public stock offering, investment bankers
are like fancy doormen to a free palace. While the public
charges almost nothing to use the capital markets,
investment bankers exact hefty fees.)
The public’s fee could be in cash or stock.
Let’s say we required publicly traded companies to
deposit 1 percent of their shares each year in the
American Permanent Fund for ten years — reaching a
total of 10 percent of their shares. This would be our
price not just for using a regulated stock exchange, but
also for all the other privileges (limited liability,
perpetual life, copyrights and patents, and so on) that
we currently bestow on private corporations for free.
In due time, the American Permanent Fund would have a
diversified portfolio worth several trillion dollars.
Like its Alaskan counterpart, it would pay equal yearly
dividends to everyone. As the stock market rose and fell,
so would everyone’s dividend checks. A rising tide
would lift all boats. America would truly be an
“ownership society.” ...
read the whole chapter
Peter Barnes:
Capitalism 3.0 — Chapter 8: Sharing Culture (pages
117-134)
One can imagine a culture in which free concerts in
parks, poets in schools and libraries, independent
theaters and filmmakers, and murals and sculptures by
local artists in public spaces thrive alongside corporate
entertainment. There’s no lack of artists
who’d participate in such a culture, or of
nonartists who’d appreciate it. The problem is how
to pay for it.
What we need is a parallel economy for noncorporate
art. Fortunately, models of such an economy exist. For
example, there’s the San Francisco Grants for the
Arts program, funded from a tax on hotel rooms. Since
1961, the program has distributed over $145 million to
hundreds of nonprofit cultural organizations. It’s
a prime reason the city pulses with free concerts,
murals, film festivals, and theater in the park.
Then there’s the Music Performance Trust Fund,
set up in 1948. To settle a dispute with the
musicians’ union, the recording industry agreed to
pay a small royalty from recording sales into a fund
supporting live concerts in parks, schools, and other
public venues. The fund was, and continues to be,
administered by an independent trustee. In 2004 it
sponsored over eleven thousand free concerts throughout
the United States and Canada. Thanks to this system,
sales of corporate-owned music support the living culture
on which the recording industry ultimately depends.
These models could be scaled up. As a revenue source,
consider what companies like Disney get with their
copyrights. They get ninety-five-year protection for
their movies, they get those FBI warnings on our DVDs,
they get the U.S. government extending intellectual
property rights worldwide, and they get police busting
street vendors for selling “pirated” DVDs.
That kind of protection is worth big bucks. Yet the
companies’ price tag for it is exactly zero. (They
do pay taxes, but so does everybody else.)
What if, instead of supplying copyright
protection for free, we charged a royalty on sales of
electronically reproduced music, films, and video games?
This could be supplemented by charging broadcasters for
their exclusive licenses, and advertisers for their
invasions of our brains (see the following
section). The resulting billions could be distributed,
through a National Arts Trust, to local arts councils,
which in turn would support community arts institutions
and artists. Under this system, corporations would give
back to a commons they now take from for free. More art
would be live and local, and more artists would be
employed. We’d have corporate and authentic culture
at the same time. ...
The airwaves, also known as the broadcast spectrum,
are a gift of nature that modern technology has turned
into a valuable resource. As a medium for sharing
information and ideas, airwaves have enormous advantages
over paper and wires. The problem in the early days was
that signals often interfered with one another. If two
nearby transmitters used the same or adjacent
frequencies, a radio listener would hear two sound
streams simultaneously. America’s approach to this
problem (though not Britain’s or Canada’s)
was to give free exclusive local frequencies to private
broadcasters, subject to periodic hearings and
renewal.
The quid pro quo for this gift, according to the
Communications Act of 1934, was that broadcasters would
serve “the public interest, convenience, and
necessity” — whatever that might mean. The
airwaves themselves would remain, in theory, public
property, with the Federal Communications Commission
(again in theory) acting as trustee. ...
read the whole chapter
Peter Barnes:
Capitalism 3.0 — Chapter 9: Building the Commons
Sector (pages 135-154)
Some commons trusts will generate income from the sale
of usage permits. Many others will need income to acquire
property rights, restore degraded habitat, or give
children start-up capital. It’s therefore essential
to encourage a multiplicity of revenue sources. The best
way to do this is through a federal commons tax
credit.
When I was in the solar energy business during the
1970s, our customers benefited from a combination of
federal and state solar tax credits. As I frequently
explained then, a tax credit isn’t the same as a
tax deduction — it’s bigger. A deduction is
subtracted from the amount of income subject to tax; if
your marginal tax rate is 30 percent, a tax deduction
saves you thirty cents on the dollar. By contrast, a tax
credit is subtracted from the amount of taxes you pay,
regardless of your tax bracket. If you owe taxes, it
always saves you one hundred cents on the dollar.
The premise behind a commons tax credit is that
wealthy Americans owe more to the commons than they
currently pay to the government in taxes. That being so,
a commons tax credit would work like this. The federal
government would raise the uppermost tax bracket by a few
percentage points. At the same time, it would give
affected taxpayers a choice: pay the extra money to the
government, or contribute it to one or more qualified
commons trusts. If people do the latter, they get a 100
percent tax credit, thereby avoiding additional taxes.
The message to the wealthy thus is: You have to give back
more. Whether you give it to the IRS or directly to the
commons is up to you. If you want to eliminate the
government middleman, that’s fine.
What qualifies as a commons trust? It’s a trust
that either benefits all citizens more or less equally or
collects money to restore an endangered commons. Social
Security, the American Permanent Fund, the
Children’s Opportunity Trust, and most land and
watershed trusts, would qualify. By contrast, a normal
charity would not.
Contributions to normal charities would remain
deductible from taxable income, but not from taxes owed.
...
read the whole chapter
|
To share this page with a friend:
right click, choose "send," and add your
comments.
|
|
Red links have not been
visited; .
Green links are pages you've seen
|
Essential Documents pertinent
to this theme:
essential_documents
|
|