Boston
Several books on Land Value Taxation have used Boston
as an example.
Louis Post: Outlines of Louis F. Post's
Lectures, with Illustrative Notes and Charts (1894)
II. THE SINGLE TAX AS A
FISCAL REFORM
1. DIRECT AND INDIRECT
TAXATION
Taxes are either direct or indirect; or, as they have
been aptly described, "straight" or "crooked." Indirect
taxes are those that may be shifted by the first payer
from himself to others; direct taxes are those that
cannot be shifted.5
5. "Taxes are either direct or indirect.
A direct tax is one which is demanded from the very
persons who, it is intended or desired, should pay it.
Indirect taxes are those which are demanded from one
person in the expectation and intention that he shall
indemnify himself at the expense of another." —
John Stuart Mill's Prin. of Pol. Ec., book v, ch. iii,
sec. I.
"Direct taxes are those which are levied
on the very persons who it is intended or desired
should pay them, and which they cannot put off upon
others by raising the prices of the taxed article.. . .
Indirect taxes on the other hand are those which are
levied on persons who expect to get back the amount of
the tax by raising the price of the taxed article."
— Laughlin's Elements, par. 249.
Taxes are direct "when the payment is
made by the person who is intended to bear the
sacrifice." Indirect taxes are recovered from final
purchasers. — Jevons's Primer, sec. 96.
"Indirect taxes are so called because
they are not paid into the treasury by the person who
really bears the burden. The payer adds the amount of
the tax to the price of the commodity taxed, and thus
the taxation is concealed under the increased price of
some article of luxury or convenience." —
Thompson's Pol. Ec., sec. 175.
The shifting of indirect taxes is accomplished by
means of their tendency to increase the prices of
commodities on which they fall. Their magnitude and
incidence 6 are thereby disguised. It was for this reason
that a great French economist of the last century
denounced them as "a scheme for so plucking geese as to
get the most feathers with the least squawking."7
6. Jevons defines the incidence of a tax
as "the manner in which it falls upon different classes
of the population." — Jevons's Primer, sec.
96.
Sometimes called "repercussion," and refers "to the
real as opposed to the nominal payment of taxes."
— Ely's Taxation, p. 64.
7. Though his language was blunt, the
sentiment does not essentially differ from that of
"statesmen" of our day who meet all the moral and
economic objections to indirect taxation with the one
reply that the people would not consent to pay enough
or the support of government if public revenues were
collected from them directly. This means nothing but
that the people are actually hoodwinked by indirect
taxation into sustaining a government that they would
not support if they knew it was maintained at their
expense; and instead of being a reason for continuing
indirect taxation, would, if true, be one of the
strongest of reasons for abolishing it. It is
consistent neither with the plainest principles of
democracy nor the simplest conceptions of morality.
Indirect taxation costs the real tax-payers much more
than the government receives, partly because the
middlemen through whose hands taxed commodities pass are
able to exact compound profits upon the tax,8 and partly
on account of extraordinary expenses of original
collection;9 it favors corruption in government by
concealing from the people the fact that they contribute
to the support of government; and it tends, by
obstructing production, to crush legitimate industry and
establish monopolies.10 The questions it raises are of
vastly more concern than is indicated by the sum total of
public expenditures.
8. A tax upon shoes, paid in the first
instance by shoe manufacturers, enters into
manufacturers' prices, and, together with the usual
rate of profit upon that amount of investment, is
recovered from wholesalers. The tax and the
manufacturers' profit upon it then constitute part of
the wholesale price and are collected from retailers.
The retailers in turn collect the tax with all
intermediate profits upon it, together with their
:usual rate of profit upon the whole, from final
purchasers -- the consumers of shoes. Thus what appears
on the surface to be a tax upon shoe manufacturers
proves upon examination to be an indirect tax upon shoe
consumers, who pay in an accumulation of profits upon
the tax considerably more than the government
receives.
The effect would be the same if a tax
upon their leather output were imposed upon tanners.
Tanners would add to the price of leather the amount of
the tax, plus their usual rate of profit upon a like
investment, and collect the whole, together with the
cost of hides, of transportation, of tanning and of
selling, from shoe manufacturers, who would collect
with their profit from retailers, who would collect
with their profit from shoe consumers. The principle
applies also when taxes are levied upon the stock or
the sales of merchants, or the money or credits of
bankers; merchants add the tax with the usual profit to
the prices of their goods, and bankers add it to their
interest and discounts.
For example; a tax of $100,000 upon the
output of manufacturers or importers would, at 10 per
cent as the manufacturing profit, cost wholesalers
$110,000; at a profit of 10 per cent to wholesalers it
would cost retailers $121,000, and at 20 percent profit
to retailers it would finally impose a tax burden of
$145,200 — being 45 per cent more than the
government would get. Upon most commodities the number
of profits exceeds three, so that indirect taxes may
frequently cost as much as 100 per cent, even when
imposed only upon what are commercially known as
finished goods; when imposed upon materials also, the
cost of collection might well run far above 200 percent
in addition to the first cost of maintaining the
machinery of taxation.
It must not be supposed, however, that
the recovery of indirect taxes from the ultimate
consumers of taxed goods is arbitrary. When shoe
manufacturers, or tanners, or merchants add taxes to
prices, or bankers add them to interest, it is not
because they might do otherwise but choose to do this;
it is because the exigencies of trade compel them.
Manufacturers, merchants, and other tradesmen who carry
on competitive businesses must on the average sell
their goods at cost plus the ordinary rate of profit,
or go out of business. It follows that any increase in
cost of production tends to increase the price of
products. Now, a tax upon the output of business men,
which they must pay as a condition of doing their
business, is as truly part of the cost of their output
as is the price of the materials they buy or the wages
of the men they hire. Therefore, such a tax upon
business men tends to increase the price of their
products. And this tendency is more or less marked as
the tax is more or less great and competition more or
less keen.
It is true that a moderate tax upon
monopolized products, such as trade-mark goods,
proprietary medicines, patented articles and copyright
publications is not necessarily shifted to consumers.
The monopoly manufacturer whose prices are not checked
by cost of production, and are therefore as a rule
higher than competitive prices would be, may find it
more profitable to bear the burden of a tax that leaves
him some profit, by preserving his entire custom, than
to drive off part of his custom by adding the tax to
his usual prices. This is true also of a moderate
import tax to the extent it falls upon goods that are
more cheaply transported from the place of production
to a foreign market where the import tax is imposed
than to a home market where the goods would be free of
such a tax — products, for instance, of a farm in
Canada near to a New York town, but far away from any
Canadian town. If the tax be less than the difference
in the cost of transportation the producer will bear
the burden of it; otherwise he will not. The ultimate
effect would be a reduction in the value of the
Canadian land. Examples which may be cited in
opposition to the principle that import taxes are
indirect, will upon examination prove to be of the
character here described. Business cannot be carried on
at a loss — not for long.
9. "To collect taxes, to prevent and
punish evasions, to check and countercheck revenue
drawn from so many distinct sources, now make up
probably three-fourths, perhaps seven-eighths, of the
business of government outside of the preservation of
order, the maintenance of the military arm, and the
administration of justice." — Progress and
Poverty, book iv, ch: v
10. For a brief and thorough exposition
of indirect taxation read George's "Protection or Free
Trade," ch. viii, on " Tariffs for Revenue."
Whoever calmly reflects and candidly decides upon the
merits of indirect taxation must reject it in all its
forms. But to do that is to make a great stride toward
accepting the single tax. For the single tax is a form of
direct taxation; it cannot be shifted.11
11. This is usually a stumbling block to
those who, without much experience in economic thought,
consider the single tax for the first time. As soon as
they grasp the idea that taxes upon commodities shift
to consumers they jump to the conclusion that similarly
taxes upon land values would shift to the users. But
this is a mistake, and the explanation is simple. Taxes
upon what men produce make production more difficult
and so tend toward scarcity in the supply, which
stimulates prices; but taxes upon land, provided the
taxes be levied in proportion to value, tend toward
plenty in supply (meaning market supply of course),
because they make it more difficult to hold valuable
land idle, and so depress prices.
"A tax on rent falls wholly on the
landlord. There are no means by which he can shift the
burden upon anyone else. . . A tax on rent, therefore,
has no effect other than its obvious one. It merely
takes so much from the landlord and transfers it to the
state." — John Stuart Mill's Prin. of Pol. Ec.,
book v, ch. iii, sec. 1.
"A tax laid upon rent is borne solely by
the owner of land." — Bascom's Tr., p.159.
"Taxes which are levied on land . . .
really fall on the owner of the land." — Mrs.
Fawcett's Pol. Ec. for Beginners, pp.209, 210.
"A land tax levied in proportion to the
rent of land, and varying with every variation of
rents, . . . will fall wholly on the landlords."
— Walker's Pol. Ec., ed. of 1887, p. 413, quoting
Ricardo.
"The power of transferring a tax from the
person who actually pays it to some other person varies
with the object taxed. A tax on rents cannot be
transferred. A tax on commodities is always transferred
to the consumer." — Thorold Rogers's Pol. Ec.,
ch. xxi, 2d ed., p. 285.
"Though the landlord is in all cases the
real contributor, the tax is commonly advanced by the
tenant, to whom the landlord is obliged to allow it in
payment of the rent." — Adam Smith's Wealth of
Nations, book v, ch. ii, part ii, art. i.
"The way taxes raise prices is by
increasing the cost of production and checking supply.
But land is not a thing of human production, and taxes
upon rent cannot check supply. Therefore, though a tax
upon rent compels land-owners to pay more, it gives
them no power to obtain more for the use of their land,
as it in no way tends to reduce the supply of land. On
the contrary, by compelling those who hold land on
speculation to sell or let for what they can get, a tax
on land values tends to increase the competition
between owners, and thus to reduce the price of land."
— Progress and Poverty, book viii, ch. iii, subd.
i.
Sometimes this point is raised as a
question of shifting the tax in higher rent to the
tenant, and at others as a question of shifting it to
the consumers of goods in higher prices. The principle
is the same. Merchants cannot charge higher prices for
goods than their competitors do, merely because they
pay higher ground rents. A country storekeeper whose
business lot is worth but few dollars charges as much
for sugar, probably more, than a city grocer whose lot
is worth thousands. Quality for quality and quantity
for quantity, goods sell for about the same price
everywhere. Differences in price are altogether in
favor of places where land has a high value. This is
due to the fact that the cost of getting goods to
places of low land value, distant villages for example,
is greater than to centers, which are places of high
land value. Sometimes it is true that prices for some
things are higher where land values are high. Tiffany's
goods, for instance, may be more expensive than goods
of the same quality at a store on a less expensive
site. But that is not due to the higher land value; it
is because the dealer has a reputation for technical
knowledge and honesty (or has become a fad among rich
people), for which his customers are willing to pay
whether his store is on a high priced-lot or a
low-priced one.
Though land value has no effect upon the
price of good, it is easier to sell goods in some
locations than in others. Therefore, though the price
and the profit of each sale be the same, or even less,
in good locations than in poorer ones, aggregate
receipts and aggregate profits are much greater at the
good location. And it is out of his aggregate, and not
out of each profit, that rent is paid, For example: A
cigar store on a thoroughfare supplies a certain
quality of cigar for fifteen cents. On a side street
the same quality of cigar can be bought no cheaper.
Indeed, the cigars there are likely to be poorer, and
therefore really dearer. Yet ground rent on the
thoroughfare is very high compared with ground rent on
the sidestreet. How, then, can the first dealer, he who
pays the high ground rent, afford to sell as good or
better cigars for fifteen cents than his competitor of
the low priced location? Simply because he is able to
make so many more sales with a given outlay of labor
and capital in a given time that his aggregate profit
is greater. This is due to the advantage of his
location, and for that advantage he pays a premium in
higher ground rent. But that premium is not charged to
smokers; the competing dealer of the side street
protects them. It represents the greater ease, the
lower cost, of doing a given volume of business upon
the site for which it is paid; add if the state should
take any of it, even the whole of it, in taxation, the
loss would be finally borne by the owner of the
advantage which attaches to that site — by the
landlord. Any attempt to shift it to tenant or buyer
would be promptly checked by the competition of
neighboring but cheaper land.
"A land-tax, levied in proportion to the
rent of land, and varying with every variation of rent,
is in effect a tax on rent; and as such a tax will not
apply to that land which yields no rent, nor to the
produce of that capital which is employed on the land
with a view to profit merely, and which never pays
rent; it will not in any way affect the price of raw
produce, but will fall wholly on the landlords."
— McCulloch's Ricardo (3d ed.), p. 207
2. THE TWO KINDS OF DIRECT
TAXATION
Direct taxes fall into two general classes: (1) Taxes
that are levied upon men in proportion to their ability
to pay, and (2) taxes that are levied in proportion to
the benefits received by the tax-payer from the public.
Income taxes are the principal ones of the first class,
though probate and inheritance taxes would rank high. The
single tax is the only important one of the second
class.
There should be no difficulty in choosing between the
two. To tax in proportion to ability to pay, regardless
of benefits received, is in accord with no principle of
just government; it is a device of piracy. The single
tax, therefore, as the only important tax in proportion
to benefits, is the ideal tax.
But here we encounter two plausible objections. One
arises from the mistaken but common notion that men are
not taxed in proportion to benefits unless they pay taxes
upon every kind of property they own that comes under the
protection of government; the other is founded in the
assumption that it is impossible to measure the value of
the public benefits that each individual enjoys. Though
the first of these objections ostensibly accepts the
doctrine of taxation according to benefits,12 yet, as it
leads to attempts at taxation in proportion to wealth,
it, like the other, is really a plea for the piratical
doctrine of taxation according to ability to pay. The two
objections stand or fall together.
12. It is often said, for instance, by
its advocates, that house owners should in justice
contribute to the support of the fire departments that
protect them and it is even gravely argued that houses
are more appropriate subjects of taxation than land;
because they need protection, whereas land needs none.
Read note 8.
Let it once be perceived that the value of the service
which government renders to each individual would be
justly measured by the single tax, and neither objection
would any longer have weight. We should then no more
think of taxing people in proportion to their wealth or
ability to pay, regardless of the benefits they receive
from government than an honest merchant would think of
charging his customers in proportion to their wealth or
ability to pay, regardless of the value of the goods they
bought of him." 13
13. Following is an interesting
computation of the cost and loss to the city of
Boston of the present mixed system of taxation as
compared with the single tax; The computation was
made by James R. Carret, Esq., the leading
conveyancer of Boston:
Valuation of Boston, May 1,
1892 Land... ... . ..
... .. ... .. $399,170,175 Buildings ... ... ... ... ..$281,109,700
Total assessed value of real estate
$680,279,875 Assessed
value of personal estate $213,695,829
.... .... ... ... ... ... ...
... .... .... .... ... .... ...
$893,975,704 Rate of
taxation, $12.90 per $1000
Total tax levy, May 1, 1892 $11,805,036
Amount of taxes levied in respect of
the different subjects of taxation and percentages of
the same:
Land .... .... .... .... $5,149,295 43.62%
Buildings .... .... .. $3,626,295 30.72%
Personal estate .. $2,756,676 23.35%
Polls ... .... ... .... .... ...272,750
2.31%
But to ascertain the total cost to the
people of Boston of the present system of taxation
for the taxable year, beginning May 1, 1892, there
should be added to the taxes assessed upon them what
it cost them to pay the owners of the land of Boston
for the use of the land, being the net ground rent,
which I estimate at four per cent on the land
value.
Total tax levy, May 1, 1892 ...
... ... ... .... .... .... .... .... ..... .... ....
.... .... .... .... ..$11,805,036
Net ground rent, four percent, on
the land value ($399,170,175)..... ... ...
...$15,966,807 Total
cost of the present system to the people of Boston
for that year ... $27,771,843
To contrast this with what the single
tax system would have cost the people of Boston for
that year, take the gross ground rent, found by
adding to the net ground rent the taxation on land
values for that year, being $12.90 per $1000, or 1.29
per cent added to 4 per cent = 5.29 per cent.
Total cost of present system as
above .. .... .... .... .... .... .... .... ....
....$27,771,843 Single
tax, or gross ground rent, 5.29 per cent on
$399,170,175 ... ..$21,116,102
Excess cost of present system, which
is the sum of taxes in
respect of buildings, personal property, and polls
.... ...... .. $6,655,741
But the present system not only costs
the people more than the single tax would, but
produces less revenue:
Proceeds of single tax ... ...
... ... ..... .... .... ..... .... .... .... .....
..... .... $21,116,102 Present tax levy ... ... ... ... ... .... ....
.... ..... .... .... .... .... .... .... ....
....$11,805,036 Loss to
public treasury by present system ... .... .... ....
.... .. ..... ..$9,311,066
This, however, is not a complete
contrast between the present system and the single
tax, for large amounts of real estate are exempt from
taxation, being held by the United States, the
Commonwealth, by the city itself, by religious
societies and corporations, and by charitable,
literary, and scientific institutions. The total
amount of the value of land so held as returned by
the assessors for the year 1892 is $60,626,171.
Reasons can be given why all lands
within the city should be assessed for taxation to
secure a just distribution of the public burdens,
which I cannot take the space to enter into here.
There is good reason to believe also that lands in
the city of Boston are assessed to quite an
appreciable extent below their fair market value. As
an indication of this see an editorial in the Boston
Daily Advertiser for October 3, 1893, under
the title, "Their Own Figures."
The vacant lands, marsh lands, and
flats in Boston were valued by the assessors in 1892
(page 3 of their annual report) at $52,712,600. I
believe that this represents not more than fifty per
cent of their true market value.
Taking this and the undervaluation of
improved property and the exemptions above mentioned
into consideration, I think $500,000,000 to be a fair
estimate of the land values of Boston. Making this
the basis of contrast, we have:
Proceeds of single tax 5.29 per
cent on $500,000,000 ... .... .... ....
$26,450,000
Present tax levy ... .... ... .... .... .... ....
.... ..... .... .... .... .... ..... .... ....
..$11,805,036
Loss to public treasury by present system ... ... ...
... .... .... .... ....$14,644,974 ...
read the
book
Charles B. Fillebrown: A Catechism of
Natural Taxation, from Principles of Natural
Taxation (1917)
Q36. How much does this particular form of
privilege amount to?
A. It amounted for 1914 to approximately $40 million for
Boston and more than $200 million for Greater New
York.
Q52. In old cities, it is not nearly all the
land in use?
A. About one half the area of New York and Chicago is
classed by the assessors as vacant. In Boston the
proportion is: occupied, 45 percent; vacant, 43
percent; marsh, 12 percent.
Q62. Would it be wise to take gradually in
taxation, say, 1/4, one half, or 3/4 of the future
increase in economic rent?
A. One hundred and one professors of political economy
have answered "Yes." Twenty-nine have answered
"No."
Q63. How could the single tax be put into
operation?
A. By gradually transferring to land all taxes not
already on it.
Q64. How might such a plan be worked
out?
A. If fifty cents per thousand should be deducted
yearly for 30 years from the rate on all property other
than land, the reduction would finally amount to $15
per thousand, and it would then be practically exempt
from all taxation.
Q65. But how could it be worked out in case of
the land?
A. Recognizing that a right thing may be done in a
wrong way, it is insisted that a right way ought to be
found to do a thing that ought to be done. The
following is presented as a natural and convenient
unit of calculation: To be
exact, an average of about 20 percent
of the gross ground rent of land is now taken in
taxation, for instance, in Boston, as well as for the
whole state of Massachusetts. If an additional one
percent should be taken each year for 30 years, it
would amount at the end of that period to 30 percent,
which, added to 20 percent, would make 50 percent, or
one half, which is about the average proportion that
present taxes levied on all property bear to gross
ground rent. Meantime few landowners would feel the
change, much less be prejudiced by it.
The following variable illustrations, A, B, and C, make
clear.
A "Modus
Operandi"
A Increase of Present Tax
For instance, applied to the assessment of a
specific lot of land for which the user pays a gross
ground rent of say ...... $68.00
Of which amount there is taken in taxation, 1915 .....
$18.00
Leaving a net income to the owner of ....
$50.00
The selling value (presumably also the assessed
valuation) would be at 5 per cent ... $1,000.00
Proceeding to take yearly from now on 1 per cent
additional of the gross ground rent of $68 for a period
of thirty years would amount in all to 30 per cent of
$68, equal to .... $20.40
Which, added to the tax already taken .... $18.00
Would give at the end of thirty years, from the $1,000
worth of land alone, everything else being exempted, a
total tax of .... $38.40.
Which is not much more than one half of the gross
ground rent of ... $68.00
The opening exhibit in detail would stand as
follows:
In 1915 the tax on this $1,000 worth of land was
$18.00
In 1916 the tax would be $18 plus 68 cents (1 per cent
of the gross ground rent, $68); equal to ....
$18.68
Reducing the owner's net rent from $50 to $49.32
In 1917 the tax would be $18 plus $1.36 (2 per cent of
the $68), totaling .... $19.36
Reducing the owner's net rent from $50 to $48.64,
In 1918 the tax would be $18 plus $2.04 (3 per cent of
the $68) or $20.45
Reducing the owner's net rent from $50 to $47.96
In 1945 the tax on the land would be $18 plus $20.40
(30 per cent of the $68) or ... $38.40
With all improvements exempted.
Reducing the owner's net rent from $50 to $29.60.
B
For a Future Increment
Tax
The taking in taxation of any desired proportion
of the future increment could be accomplished simply by
continuing the present valuation and present rate as
constant factors, and making a separate individual
assessment of the increment tax after the following or
similar formula, according to the proportion to be
taken. For instance, to take in taxation 50 per
cent of the future increase:
Year
|
Valuation
|
Increment
|
Rate Per M.
|
Tax for Each Year
|
1915 |
$1,000 |
|
|
|
1916 |
$1,040 |
$40 |
$25 |
Tax for year 1916, $1 |
|
1915 |
$1,000 |
|
|
|
1917 |
$1,080 |
$80 |
25 |
Tax for year 1917, $2 |
|
1915 |
$1,000 |
|
|
|
1918 |
$1,120 |
$120 |
25 |
Tax for year 1918, $3 |
|
1915 |
$1,000 |
|
|
|
1919 |
$1,160 |
$160 |
25 |
Tax for year 1919, $4 |
|
1915 |
$1,000 |
|
|
|
1920 |
$1,200 |
$200 |
25 |
Tax for year 1920, $5 |
In applying this formula it would be necessary after
the first few years at least to increase the rate to
correspond to the decrease in assessed valuation due to
this new tax. For computations upon this and
related points, see the Report of the
New York City Commission on New Sources of City
Revenue (1913), p. 7 and Appendices X to
XV.
C
The Assessment of Rent
It should be reiterated that inasmuchas gross
ground rent, actual or potential, is the initial factor
in getting at the value of land, it cannot be
unprofitable to become familiar with a more correct
formula as expressed in terms of rent.
Starting with the present unit of annual value for use
to take in taxation in 25 years 50 per cent of the
future increase in ground rent:
Year
|
Net Ground Rent
|
Increment
|
Percentage of Rent
|
Tax for Each Year
|
1915 |
$50 |
|
|
|
1916
|
$52 |
2 |
50 |
Tax for year 1916, $1 |
|
1915 |
$50 |
|
|
|
1917 |
54 |
4 |
50 |
Tax for year 1917, $2 |
|
1915 |
$50 |
|
|
|
1918 |
56 |
6 |
50 |
Tax for year 1918, $3 |
|
1915 |
$50 |
|
|
|
1919 |
58 |
8 |
50 |
Tax for year 1919, $4 |
|
1915 |
$50 |
|
|
|
1920
|
60
|
10
|
50
|
Tax for year 1920, $5 |
|
1915 |
$50 |
|
|
|
1940 |
100 |
50 |
50 |
Tax for year 1940, $25 |
... read the whole
article
|
To share this page with a friend:
right click, choose "send," and add your
comments.
|
related
themes:
see_also
|
Red links have not been
visited; .
Green links are pages you've seen
|
Essential Documents pertinent
to this theme:
essential_documents
|
|