Corporations and
Government
Peter Barnes:
Capitalism 3.0: Preface (pages ix.-xvi)
I’m a businessman. I believe society should
reward successful initiative with profit. At the same
time, I know that profit-seeking activities have
unhealthy side effects. They cause pollution, waste,
inequality, anxiety, and no small amount of confusion
about the purpose of life.
I’m also a liberal, in the sense that I’m
not averse to a role for government in society. Yet
history has convinced me that representative government
can’t adequately protect the interests of ordinary
citizens. Even less can it protect the interests of
future generations, ecosystems, and nonhuman species. The
reason is that most — though not all — of the
time, government puts the interests of private
corporations first. This is a systemic problem of a
capitalist democracy, not just a matter of electing new
leaders.
If you identify with the preceding sentiments, then
you might be confused and demoralized, as I have been
lately. If capitalism as we know it is deeply flawed, and
government is no savior, where lies hope? This strikes me
as one of the great dilemmas of our time. For years the
Right has been saying — nay, shouting — that
government is flawed and that only privatization,
deregulation, and tax cuts can save us. For just as long,
the Left has been insisting that markets are flawed and
that only government can save us. The trouble is that
both sides are half-right and half-wrong. They’re
both right that markets and state are flawed, and both
wrong that salvation lies in either sphere. But if
that’s the case, what are we to do? Is there,
perhaps, a missing set of institutions that can help us?
...
For much of this time I was president of Working
Assets, a company that donates 1 percent of its gross
sales to nonprofit groups working for a better world.
These donations come off its top line, not its bottom
line; the company makes them whether it’s
profitable or not (and many years we were not). It
occurred to me that 1 percent is an exceedingly small
portion of sales for any business to return to the larger
world, given that businesses take so much from the larger
world without paying. How, for example, could we make any
goods without nature’s many free gifts? And how
could we sell them without society’s vast
infrastructure of laws, roads, money, and so on? At the
very least, I liked to think, we ought to pay a 1 percent
royalty for the privilege of being a limited liability
corporation. ...
In retrospect, I realized the question I’d been
asking since early adulthood was: Is capitalism a
brilliant solution to the problem of scarcity, or is it
itself modernity’s central problem? The question
has many layers, but explorations of each layer led me to
the same verdict. Although capitalism started as a
brilliant solution, it has become the central problem of
our day. It was right for its time, but times have
changed.
When capitalism started, nature was abundant and
capital was scarce; it thus made sense to reward capital
above all else. Today we’re awash in capital and
literally running out of nature. We’re also losing
many social arrangements that bind us together as
communities and enrich our lives in nonmonetary ways.
This doesn’t mean capitalism is doomed or useless,
but it does mean we have to modify it. We have to adapt
it to the twenty-first century rather than the
eighteenth. ...
The dramatis personae throughout the
book are corporations, government, and the
commons. The plot goes something like this. As
the curtain rises, corporations are gobbling up the
commons. They’re the big boys on the block, and the
commons — an unorganized mélange of nature,
community, and culture — is the constant loser. It
has no property rights of its own, so must rely on
government for protection. But government is a fickle
guardian that tilts heavily toward corporations.
Fortunately, corporations only dominate government
most of the time; every once in a while, they lose their
grip. So it’s possible to imagine that the next
time corporate dominance ebbs, government — acting
on behalf of commoners — swiftly fortifies the
commons. It assigns new property rights to commons
trusts, builds commons infrastructure, and spawns a new
class of genuine co-owners. When corporations regain
political dominance, as they inevitably will, they
can’t undo the new system. The commons now has
safeguards and stakeholders; it’s entrenched for
the long haul. And in time, corporations accept the
commons as their business partner. They find they can
still make profits, plan farther ahead, and even become
more globally competitive.
read the whole chapte
Peter Barnes:
Capitalism 3.0 — Chapter 3: The Limits of Government
(pages 33-48)
Limits of Regulation
The idea of regulation is that, while markets should
ideally be as free as possible, there are times when an
external actor, not driven by profit maximization, must
impose some rules for the common good. When it comes to
nature, government has many ways to regulate.
* It may require timely disclosure of toxic
releases.
* It may grant, sell, or deny rights to use public
resources.
* It may ban some pollutants altogether, limit others, or
tell polluters what technologies to use.
* It may divide the landscape into zones and specify what
kinds of activities can take place in each zone.
* It may tax certain activities and subsidize others.
This wide array of tools — plus the power to
prosecute rulebreakers — seemingly creates in
government a formidable counterweight to corporations.
Yet history has shown that government isn’t the
regulatory tiger it appears to be. It faces fierce
corporate resistance whenever it tries to exercise its
powers. And time after time, its regulatory agencies have
been captured by the industries they were intended to
regulate.
The process of regulatory capture has been described
by many scholars. Details vary, but the plot is always
the same. A new agency is created to regulate an industry
that’s harming the public. At first the agency acts
boldly, but over time its zeal wanes. Reformers who
originally staffed the agency are replaced by people who
either worked in the industry earlier, or hope to do so
after a stint in government. Industry-packed
“advisory committees” multiply, while
industry-funded “think tanks” add a veneer of
legitimacy to profit-driven proposals. Lobbyists meet
constantly with agency staffers. The public, meanwhile,
has no clue about what’s going on.
This process has reached extreme proportions in recent
years. As I write, the head of public lands in the
Interior Department is a former mining industry lobbyist,
the head of the air division at the EPA is a former
utility lobbyist, the second in command at EPA is an
ex-Monsanto lobbyist, and the head of Superfund cleanups
at EPA (which makes industry clean up its toxic wastes)
formerly advised companies on how to evade Superfund.
Although today’s pro-industry bias may be more
egregious than usual, the absence of outrage or
resistance suggests it’s not far from the norm.
And it’s not just regulatory agencies that have
been captured. Congress itself, which oversees the
agencies and writes their controlling laws, has been
badly infected. According to the Center for Public
Integrity, the “influence industry” in
Washington now spends $6 billion a year and employs more
than thirty-five thousand lobbyists, some two hundred of
whom are former Congress members who enjoy easy access to
their erstwhile colleagues.
A glimpse at the corporate lobbying game shows just
how rewarding it is. MBNA, the nation’s largest
credit card bank, spent over $17 million on lobbying
between 1999 and 2004. This is pin money compared to the
sums it will reap from an industry-drafted bankruptcy
overhaul, passed in 2005, which precludes all but the
very poor from wiping out their debts and starting anew.
(The great majority of Americans who file for bankruptcy
are middle-class victims of job loss, huge medical bills,
or family breakup.) A New York Times reporter described
this scene as the bill was being marked up:
“Lawyers and lobbyists jammed Congressional hearing
rooms to overflowing. . . . During breaks, there was a
common, almost comical pattern. The pinstriped lobbyists
ran into the hallway, grabbed tiny cell phones from their
pockets or briefcases, and reported back to their
clients, almost always with the news they wanted to
hear.” ...
Three points are worth making here.
- First, ownership isn’t the same thing as
trusteeship. Owners of property — even
government owners — have wide latitude to do
whatever they want with it; a trustee does not.
Trustees are bound by the terms of their trust and by
centuries-old principles of trusteeship, foremost
among which is “undivided loyalty” to
beneficiaries.
- Second, in a capitalist democracy, the state is a
dispenser of many valuable prizes. Whoever amasses
the most political power wins the most valuable
prizes. The rewards include property rights, friendly
regulators, subsidies, tax breaks, and free or cheap
use of the commons. The notion that the state
promotes “the common good” is sadly
naive.
- Third, while free marketers are fond of saying
that capitalism is a precondition for democracy, what
they neglect to add is that capitalism also distorts
democracy. Like gravity, its tug is constant. The
bigger the concentrations of capital, the stronger
the tug.
We face a disheartening quandary here.
Profit-maximizing corporations dominate our economy.
Their programming makes them enclose and diminish common
wealth. The only obvious counterweight is government, yet
government is dominated by these same corporations.
One possible way out of this dilemma is to reprogram
corporations — that is, to make them driven by
something other than profit. This, however, is like
asking elephants to dance — they’re just not
built to do it. Corporations are built to make money, and
the truth is, as a society we want them to make money.
We’ll look at this further in the next chapter.
Another possible way out is to liberate government
from corporations, not just momentarily, but
long-lastingly. This is easier said than done.
Corporations have decimated their old adversary,
organized labor, and turned the media into their
mouthpiece. Occasionally a breakthrough is made in
campaign financing — for example, corporations are
now barred from giving so-called soft money to political
parties — but corporate money soon finds other
channels to flow through. The return on such investments
is simply too high to stop them.
Does this mean there’s no hope? I don’t
think so. The window of opportunity is small, but not
nonexistent. Throughout American history, anticorporate
forces have come to power once or twice per century. In
the nineteenth century, we had the eras of Jackson and
Lincoln; in the twentieth century, those of Theodore and
Franklin Roosevelt. Twenty-first century equivalents
will, I’m sure, arise. It may take a calamity of
some sort — another war, a depression, or an
ecological disaster — to trigger the next
anticorporate ascendancy, but sooner or later it will
come. Our job is to be ready when it comes. ...
read the whole chapter
|
To share this page with a friend:
right click, choose "send," and add your
comments.
|
related
themes:
government's role
|
Red links have not been
visited; .
Green links are pages you've seen
|
Essential Documents pertinent
to this theme:
essential_documents
|
|