Common Property Trusts
Peter Barnes:
Capitalism 3.0 — Chapter 6: Trusteeship of Creation
(pages 79-100)
A trustee isn’t the same thing as a steward.
Stewards care for an asset, but their obligations are
voluntary and vague. By contrast, trustees’
obligations are mandatory and quite specific. Trusteeship
is thus a more formal and rigorous responsibility than
stewardship.
Trusts can be in charge of financial as well as
physical assets. In this chapter, my concern is natural
assets — gifts we inherit from creation. One of my
premises is that each generation has a contract to pass
on such gifts, undiminished, to those not yet born. If we
are to keep this contract, someone must act as trustee of
nature’s gifts, or at least of the most endangered
of them. The question is, who?
The candidates are government, corporations, and
trusts. I argued earlier that neither corporations nor
government can fulfill this function; they’re both
too bound to short-term private interests. That leaves
trusts.
Common Property Trusts
The Trebah Garden Trust isn’t a rarity. Across
Britain, the National Trust — a nongovernmental
charity founded in 1895 — owns over six hundred
thousand acres of countryside, six hundred miles of
coastline, and two hundred historic buildings and
gardens. It has over three million members who elect half
of its fifty-two-person governing council (the other half
are appointed by nonprofit organizations that share the
trust’s goals). In the United States, there are now
over fifteen hundred Trebah-like trusts, protecting over
nine million acres. On top of that, the
fifty-five-year-old Nature Conservancy protects more than
fifteen million acres.
Let’s posit, then, a generic institution, the
common property trust. It’s a special kind of trust
that manages assets that come from the commons and are
meant to be preserved as commons. Common property trusts
manage these assets first and foremost on behalf of
future generations. They may have secondary
beneficiaries, such as public education or residents of a
particular locale, but such living beneficiaries take
backseats to the yet-to-be-born. These trusts carry out
their missions by owning and managing bundles of property
rights. Here are two examples from my own backyard: the
Marin Agricultural Land Trust (MALT) and the Pacific
Forest Trust (PFT). The demise of family farms and the
loss of open space around cities are seemingly
unstoppable trends. Yet in Marin County, just north of
San Francisco, family-owned dairy, sheep, and cattle
ranches have survived. A big reason is that ranchers
there have an option: selling conservation easements to
MALT.
A conservation easement is a voluntary agreement
between a landowner and a trust that permanently limits
uses of the land. The owner continues to own and use the
land and may sell it or pass it on to her heirs. However,
the owner gives up some of the rights associated with the
land — for example, the right to build additional
houses on it or to clear-cut trees. The trust that
acquires the easement makes sure its terms are followed
by the current as well as future owners.
In Marin County, MALT has preserved nearly forty
thousand acres of farmland by buying conservation
easements from ranchers. This represents about a third of
the land currently farmed. The ranchers receive the
difference between what the land would be worth if
developed and what it’s worth as a working farm. In
effect, they’re paid to be land stewards and to
forgo future capital gains.
Most of MALT’s money comes from public sources.
What the public receives isn’t an old-fashioned
commons of shared pasturage, but a lasting pastoral
landscape and a viable agricultural economy. That’s
not a bad alternative to suburban sprawl.
In much the same way, the Pacific Forest Trust
acquires what it calls working forest conservation
easements from private woodlands owners. Some of the
easements are purchased, others are donated by owners in
exchange for tax benefits. Here again, owners keep their
land but agree to forgo nonforest development and to
harvest trees sustainably.
PFT’s goal is to protect not only forests
themselves but the many species that live in them, as
well as the ecosystem services — such as clean
water and carbon absorption — that forests provide.
As with MALT, some of PFT’s money comes from public
sources. In return, the public gets healthy forests for
considerably less than it would cost to buy and manage
them outright. ...
read the whole chapter
Peter Barnes:
Capitalism 3.0 — Chapter 7: Universal Birthrights
(pages 101-116)
Dividends from Common Assets
A cushion of reliable income is a wonderful thing. It
can be saved for rainy days or used to pursue happiness
on sunny days. It can encourage people to take risks,
care for friends and relatives, or volunteer for
community service. For low-income families, it can pay
for basic necessities.
Conversely, the absence of reliable income is a
terrible thing. It heightens anxiety and fear. It
diminishes our ability to cope with crises and
transitions. It traps many families on the knife’s
edge of poverty, and makes it harder for the poor to
rise.
So why don’t we, as Monopoly does, pay everyone
some regular income — not through redistribution of
income, but through predistribution of common property?
One state — Alaska — already does this. As
noted earlier, the Alaska Permanent Fund uses revenue
from state oil leases to invest in stocks, bonds, and
similar assets, and from those investments pays yearly
dividends to every resident. Alaska’s model can be
extended to any state or nation, whether or not they have
oil. We could, for instance, have an American Permanent
Fund that pays equal dividends to long-term residents of
all 50 states. The reason is, we jointly own many
valuable assets.
Recall our discussion about common property trusts.
These trusts could crank down pollution and earn money
from selling ever-scarcer pollution permits. The scarcer
the permits get, the higher their prices would go. Less
pollution would equal more revenue. Over time, trillions
of dollars could flow into an American Permanent
Fund.
What could we do with that common income? In Alaska
the deal with oil revenue is 75 percent to government and
25 percent to citizens. For an American Permanent Fund,
I’d favor a 50/50 split, because paying dividends
to citizens is so important. Also, when scarce ecosystems
are priced above zero, the cost of living will go up and
people will need compensation; this wasn’t, and
isn’t, the case in Alaska. I’d also favor
earmarking the government’s dollars for specific
public goods, rather than tossing them into the general
treasury. This not only ensures identifiable public
benefits; it also creates constituencies who’ll
defend the revenue sharing system.
Waste absorption isn’t the only common resource
an American Permanent Fund could tap. Consider also, the
substantial contribution society makes to stock market
values. As noted earlier, private corporations can
inflate their value dramatically by selling shares on a
regulated stock exchange. The extra value derives from
the enlarged market of investors who can now buy the
corporation’s shares. Given a total stock market
valuation of about $15 trillion, this socially created
liquidity premium is worth roughly $5 trillion.
At the moment, this $5 trillion gift flows mostly to
the 5 percent of the population that own more than half
the private wealth. But if we wanted to, we could spread
it around. We could do that by charging corporations for
using the public trading system, just as investment
bankers do. (For those of you who haven’t been
involved in a public stock offering, investment bankers
are like fancy doormen to a free palace. While the public
charges almost nothing to use the capital markets,
investment bankers exact hefty fees.)
The public’s fee could be in cash or stock.
Let’s say we required publicly traded companies to
deposit 1 percent of their shares each year in the
American Permanent Fund for ten years — reaching a
total of 10 percent of their shares. This would be our
price not just for using a regulated stock exchange, but
also for all the other privileges (limited liability,
perpetual life, copyrights and patents, and so on) that
we currently bestow on private corporations for free.
In due time, the American Permanent Fund would have a
diversified portfolio worth several trillion dollars.
Like its Alaskan counterpart, it would pay equal yearly
dividends to everyone. As the stock market rose and fell,
so would everyone’s dividend checks. A rising tide
would lift all boats. America would truly be an
“ownership society.” ...
read the whole chapter
|