John Kenneth Galbraith
Frank Stilwell and Kirrily Jordan:
The Political Economy of Land: Putting Henry George in His
Place
Enthusiastic proponents of Henry George’s ideas
have often presented them as a panacea for the economic,
social and environmental problems that beset contemporary
society. Indeed, the Georgist analysis does have much to
offer. By more adequately addressing land as a unique
economic, social and ecological resource, it can help to
reveal underlying causes of currently pressing issues
such as declining housing affordability, growing economic
inequality, and environmental decay.
The Georgist land tax ‘remedy’ can also
play an important role in the redress of these problems.
However, there are limitations to the modern application
of George’s ideas, as outlined in this article.
While a uniform land tax is a necessary component in
addressing contemporary political economic problems, it
is not sufficient. It needs to be set in the context of a
broader political economic analysis and policy program,
also addressing public housing, urban and regional
policies, environmental taxes and regulations,
‘floors and ceilings’ to limit income
inequalities and macroeconomic stabilisation.
While the Georgist analysis redresses the general
neglect of land in modern economic orthodoxy, it is
important not to go too far to the other extreme. In
other words, the important emphasis on land should not
come at the expense of attention to problems associated
with labour and capital and to the complex forms of
government policy necessary for the balancing of
contemporary economic, social and ecological concerns.
The Georgist analysis needs to be integrated into a
comprehensive political economic analysis of contemporary
capitalism.
So what does ‘putting Henry George in his
place’ entail? It means recognising the political
economic importance of land and the potential social
gains from the extension of land taxation. Equally, it
means recognising the necessity of relating Georgist
ideas and policy prescriptions to a broader canvas of
modern political economy, including the analytical
traditions associated with Karl Marx, J. M. Keynes, and
J. K. Galbraith, and modern environmental economics.
Henry George’s place is in good company.
read the whole article
Peter Barnes:
Capitalism 3.0 — Chapter 2: A Short History of
Capitalism (pages 15-32)
Sometime around 1950, capitalism entered a new phase.
Until then, poverty was a widely shared American
experience. Wages were low, hours were long, and
unemployment was a wolf at almost every door. In the
1930s, it reached 25 percent.
This changed in the period following World War II. In
1958, economist John Kenneth Galbraith wrote a
best-seller called The Affluent Society in which he noted
that scarcity of goods was now a thing of the past for a
majority of Americans. “The ordinary individual has
access to amenities — foods, entertainment,
personal transportation and plumbing — in which not
even the rich rejoiced a century ago,” Galbraith
observed. “So great has been the change that many
of the desires of the individual are no longer even
evident to him. They become so only as they are
synthesized, elaborated, and nurtured by advertising and
salesmanship, and these, in turn, have become among our
most important and talented professions.”
This was a major phase change for capitalism. Before,
people wanted more goods than the economy could provide.
Demand, in other words, exceeded supply, and we lived in
what might be called shortage capitalism. We could also
call it Capitalism 1.0.
After the change, we shifted into surplus capitalism,
or what I call Capitalism 2.0. In this version,
there’s no limit to what corporations can produce;
their problem is finding buyers. A sizeable chunk of GDP
is spent to make people want this unneeded output. And
credit is lavishly extended so they can buy it.
This historic shift can be described another way. A
century ago, our chief scarcity was goods. It thus made
sense to sacrifice other things in pursuit of goods, and
capitalism was masterful at doing this. Today we’re
waist-deep in thneeds, and our scarcities are different.
Among the middle classes, the top scarcities, I’d
say, are time, companionship, and community (see figure
2.2). Among the poor, there remains a lack of goods, but
that lack isn’t due to a shortage of production
capacity — it’s due to the poor’s
inability to pay. The critical scarcity here, in other
words, is income. ...
read the whole chapter
|
To share this page with a friend:
right click, choose "send," and add your
comments.
|
related
themes:
see_also
|
Red links have not been
visited; .
Green links are pages you've seen
|
Essential Documents pertinent
to this theme:
essential_documents
|
|