land and buildings have value but only land increases in value

Nothing to see here, just an international investment concern making $120 million dollars simply by having the $370 million to invest. The working people of Seattle did the rest.

Kilroy Realty bought the building from a Deutsche Bank-affiliated real estate fund, according to documents filed Monday with King County. The building was built in 2009 and last sold in 2016 for $370 million.

Maybe some halo effect from Amazon but more from Seattle itself…

Despite an overall decline in office leasing in the United States, technology companies gobbled up more space in the Seattle area than they had the previous year.
[…]
Among the 100 largest technology leases, 14 were in the Seattle area, totaling 3.4 million square feet, about 85 percent more space than in Manhattan, the No. 2 market on the list.

This is just silly…

Downtown Seattle is “closer to capacity build-out,” said Mr. Yasukochi, but the so-called Eastside has room for companies to expand. Some businesses are creating mini-campuses, and others are flocking to new developments like Bellevue’s Spring District.

Downtown parking lots, a acre+ hole in the ground across from City Hall, and all manner of other underused land, but go off, I guess.

“It’s the talent pool that drives the real estate market,” Mr. Yasukochi said. It’s easier to hire specialists in cloud computing, machine learning or virtual reality when so many live in the area.

Large companies also attract start-ups. “If you want to be part of the tech industry, you’ll want to be where the action is,” Mr. Paolone said.

And the speculator/rentier will be there with their hand out, doing nothing, making money while working people sleep.

land rents/leaseholds in action: Oak Island NY

I am always looking for examples of land rents, examples of home ownership without the need to buy increasingly expensive land. I didn’t expect to find one off the coast of New York’s Long Island.

The town of Babylon owns the island; homeowners pay a $1,800 fee to lease their land, which is added to the town’s annual taxes. Homeowners also pay an annual fee of $2,500 to the Great South Bay Isles Association for maintenance of community property, such as a repair to the floating docks off the parking lot. The association’s directors are elected by and composed of island homeowners. The lease, expected to be automatically renewed in 2065, limits occupancy to seasonal summer use.

[…]
Imagine what these homes would sell for if they came with land:

Houses here don’t often come up for sale because “people keep them in the family,” said Lisbeth English, an associate agent with Netter Real Estate in West Islip. She is the listing agent of 24 Oak Street, a two-bedroom built in 1914, on the market for $249,880.

A red shingled house is under contract for above its asking price of $399,000, said Matthew Arnold, an agent at Netter. And Listing Pro has a four-bedroom, two-bath house listed on the island for $485,999.

Maybe not the most practical example, as this is a summer-only community. Yet it exists. And $1800/year for the land lease plus $2500 as a quasi-HOA isn’t onerous. The article mentions other taxes (likely on the buildings) but $360/month plus whatever that is seems to be something the residents are willing to pay. Here in Seattle, I would gladly pay the current property tax on a house and land as a ground rent if I only had to take on a mortgage for the house. That could cut the cost of an $800,000 property in half. Sure, you’d lose some of the benefits of a mortgage interest deduction but you’d also have more money each month, instead of waiting for the taxman to cough it up once a year.

location, location, location

I wonder how this property became so valuable? From land valued at $4.5 million with negligible improvements to a quarter of a billion in five years.

Alexandria Real Estate Equities has sold a 70% interest in its 400 Dexter life sciences building in the South Lake Union neighborhood for $254.8 million, or $1,255 per rentable square foot.

Could it be the development taking place nearby?

“This transaction marks another strong data point reflective of the current demand for core life science product in Seattle,” said Kevin Shannon, co-head of U.S. capital markets for Newmark. “Life science fundamentals are faring better than the overall office fundamentals with rents that are now ranging from $65 to $80 (including operating expenses) annually, which allowed us to achieve record-setting pricing for the Puget Sound marketplace.”
[…]
“The Puget Sound ranks third nationally for life science growth over the past five years with venture capital having increased 200% during that time frame,” Jesse Ottele, executive managing director for Newmark, said in a statement.

What doesn’t make sense to me is how the building, shown here as improvements, is assessed at higher values each year while the land rises more slowly. The building was assessed at $24,330,400 in 2015, $230 million in 2020, while the land was assessed as being worth $5,160,000 in 2015 and $9,114,000 in 2020. The land — the location — is what become more valuable, not the building. And we know the rents charged by the landlord haven’t stayed where they were in 2015 while the land and location remained the same.

The property taxes are $1,773,255.28/year on property valued at $212,266,000 on about .27 of an acre. If the 1% rule holds, that should be about $2.1 million but I think the balance between the value of land and improvements is what needs recalibrating. That rise in value should be assessed on the land, not the improvements: the location is what’s making the money for the landlord and that value should be remitted back to the original investors — the taxpayers and those who live and work here.

what is the capital of the USA?

New transit stations open in Seattle tomorrow (Oct 2, 2021) and I am reminded that one of them is in a neighborhood called Brooklyn (after one of the five boroughs) and not far from neighborhoods called Morningside and Chelsea.

“Somebody told me this: In New York, your world will be within a four-block radius,” she said. “It’s true. You get lazy to walk beyond four blocks.” She rarely needs to, as Target and plenty of other stores are within that range.

“There are always people outside,” she said. “I really like to feel surrounded by people. I have a new circle of friends as a result of living here.”

New York remains the cultural capital of the USA, no matter what Atlanta or LA or Seattle do. And people in those cities really want that experience, a world within walking distance, but aren’t willing to give up their addiction to the “independence” of cars and the big lots and single family housing that cars require.

terms and vocabulary

Thinking about how to explain ground rents/land rents/land value taxation…

Economic rents differ from shelter rents, the checks many of us write on the first of the month. Economic rent is what landlords claim from the ownership of land, the proceeds of the work performed on that land. A residential tenant’s wages are the crop harvested each month, as they represent the labor that tenant sells in the market. It’s economic rent and the related term rentier — defined as “[a]n individual who receives an income, usually interest, rent, dividends, capital gains, or profits from his or her assets and investments” — that we are concerned with here.

Going back to the notion of economic rent, not shelter rent, what apartment or house tenants pay, here is the Ricardian definition.

“Portion of the produce of the earth which is paid to a landlord on account of the original and indestructible powers of the soil, Ricardo in his theory of rent has emphasized that rent is a reward for the services of land which is fixed in supply. Secondly, it arises due to original qualities of land which are indestructible”. (The original indestructible powers of the soil include natural soil, fertility, mineral deposits, climatic conditions etc., etc.).

To this we add Adam Smith’s description:

“The rent of land, therefore, considered as the price paid for the use of the land, is naturally a monopoly price. It is not at all proportioned to what the landlord may have laid out upon the improvement of the land, or to what he can afford to take; but to what the farmer can afford to give.” — Adam Smith, An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, Book I, Chapter XI “Of the Rent of Land”

We have to recall the times in which they lived and their focus on or simplification of land for agriculture. What Ricardo formulated was the idea that land’s value was based on what it could produce from its location and other properties (bottomland vs hillsides, sun exposures vs shade, rain or access to water). So the landlord can rent an acre of bottomland with access to the river for more than he will get for an acre on the hillside where water has to be carried uphill. Also included in his definition is that land is finite, fixed in supply, and that it is original (ie, not made by man) and indestructible.

Smith’s explanation is more direct: the landlord owns a monopoly on the land she owns and can charge what she likes for the use of it. If her tenant brings in a good crop, she can demand more rent from her tenant based on the higher income from the land.

What Henry George saw was that the price to acquire land to work in a given area, either as farmland or to site a factory, became more expensive as more people moved to that area. Supply and demand for a monopoly good can only benefit the owner.

So as the cost to acquire land rises, who pockets the increase? The landowner. But who created that value? Everyone else. All the investment by the taxpayers — roads, utilities, public safety — and those who work their land nearby accrues to the landowner’s benefit. As nearby or adjacent land is developed, the value of land increases, partly through scarcity and partly through the increased desirability of it for new or existing businesses. If I am in business, I will pay more for land near businesses or markets I need access to. And rather than the public whose taxes and consumer spending created that value, the landowner — the rentier — reaps the benefit.

When a fraction of an acre sells for millions of dollars, that’s all unearned income. That windfall should be subject to a ground/land rent or land value tax that returns that value to those who created it, derived as it was from “the original and indestructible powers of the soil.” In this case we don’t care so much about the power of the soil so much as the value of the location, its proximity to other commercial interests. Once a city develops a presence in some industry — banking in New York or London, for example — that location becomes more valuable and the land under it more expensive. The idea that someone can live off the proceeds of land their long-dead ancestors bought as farmland sounds a lot like feudalism. Land speculation is as corrosive to social mobility and a free market as dynastic wealth. They are not unrelated.

The ideal price to acquire land for commercial use is $0, with the value of the land payable as a ground rent to the municipality. This is the premise of ground rents, that the map is not the territory. The map coordinates are not the land itself, and we can allow someone to hold, buy, or sell the exclusive rights to a set of map coordinates but the value of the land belongs to no one or everyone:

I do not propose either to purchase or to confiscate private property in land. The first would be unjust; the second, needless. Let the individuals who now hold it still retain, if they want to, possession of what they are pleased to call their land. Let them continue to call it their land. Let them buy and sell, and bequeath and devise it. We may safely leave them the shell, if we take the kernel. It is not necessary to confiscate land; it is only necessary to confiscate rent.

So does this mean that home prices will rise even higher in overheated markets? That depends. If commercial property is assessed and taxed on its highest and best use, residential rates may well go down. There is no reason why a downtown office block pays the same tax rate as a family home. One of those two properties is using the land expressly to make money and it should pay a higher rate to use the land. If there is a monopoly in land, the value should be held in common with the proceeds being returned to those who created it.

There is really no reason to own land, other than to extract economic rents through scarcity. Imagine a home purchase that didn’t include land in a city like Seattle: it could cut the price in half, with the current property tax being assessed as a ground rent. A look into the King County property database makes clear that land prices have risen faster than home prices (yes, they are tracked separately, in preparation for a ground rent/land value tax).

The ideal tax model would be split-rate, with a higher tax on the land (higher than the current 1%) than on the improvements, to both discourage land speculation and encourage development. If the cost to hold land is increased to discourage speculation but can be defrayed by developing it, that’s what we will see. Accepting surface parking lots or single story buildings downtown in the face of homeless emergency and a housing affordability crisis should be unacceptable but Seattle and other cities can’t seem to find their way out of this mess. We already know that developers will pay close to $1,000,000/acre per year to rent land: putting an equivalent ground rent on surface parking lots and other disused or underused land might impoverish a few parking lot operators but cars have reached their peak anyway. The reality is anyone holding land downtown in many of our expensive cities will make out just fine. Let them cash in their winnings and go.

location has value, networks add value

In his kitchen at Cedar’s of Lebanon Restaurant, owner John Khalil expects more customers, but fears growth and high property values will someday shove him out of his monthly lease.

“It’s like we’re digging in a mine and finding the gold, and don’t know what to do with it. Do we mine it, or split it, or fight over it?” Khalil said.

He’s saying what many of us have saying…that the wealth of cities is in the land, and we don’t even have to dig for it. As Tyrone Beason pointed out a few years ago, Seattle is in the midst of a new Gold Rush but the people getting fleeced aren’t going to the Klondike. They are staying here.”We wanted workers…but we got people instead.

City zoning reflects the push from small business to “Save the Ave.” All blocks surrounding U District Station are upzoned to allow buildings 240 or 320 feet tall — except University Way itself, which remains capped at 65 feet.

Current construction projects include eight tower cranes. A tiny-house village will move into a Sound Transit surplus construction lot along 45th, until bigger plans hatch. The U District added 2,173 new housing units since 2015, with 2,480 more permitted or under construction.

This is good but 2,000 units over 6 years seems little slow: the additional 2,500 over that time wouldn’t be all that impressive, tbh. A ground rent that reflected a higher and better use than what’s there now might drive development a little harder. Those “bigger plans” could be farther along. These transit stations have been under construction for years and a good business reporter would have pulled all the tax records for all the land that has changed hands around those three stations since ground was broken. The higher sales prices reflect value created by the people who live and work around those stations, all of which should flow back to the community through a ground rent.

pop-up holiday shops and downtown parking lots

How many pop-up Halloween shops are there near you? I make 6 of them within 10 miles.

The argument here (or arguments) is that these are an example of how poor use of land can look like dynamic growth but is really just predatory profit-seeking.

“While I might once have just seen run-down buildings through my windshield and kept on driving, now I see people doing what they can with what they have,” he writes. “It’s not perfect. […] But it’s better than abandonment and blight.” He has a point. I would much rather see an old Kmart used as a Halloween costume store, even if it’s only temporary, than have that store go empty in perpetuity, and I’m sure the owners of the building would, too.

Ok, that sounds fine…

Today’s Spirit is pretty much a bottom-feeder business that works only at the expense of other stores; if there weren’t vacant storefronts, this business wouldn’t exist. Or, as the Times puts it, “Spirit is merrily feasting on the corpses of its fallen foes.”

Huh. That’s not so good.

Maybe seasonal shops could take turns with a rotating storefront downtown; there’s no reason a single space couldn’t be a Halloween store from September–October, a Christmas store from November–December, and a beach-gear store from May–August. Or maybe these shops would fill in during temporary vacancies of commercial spaces, between random store tenants.

You know what used to fill this role? Department stores. And what was once thriving in the vacant spaces where these seasonal shops now appear? Department stores. And they employed local people year round, not just a few weeks at a time. They were often a local destination, with a restaurant or coffee shop inside, and specialty services (repairs and alterations) that are now hard to find.

We shouldn’t be building a world where it’s normal to have dozens of vast empty stores propped up by millions of taxpayer dollars in public infrastructure.

Or empty spaces, like parking lots downtown. We should be angry when we see these shops coming in to scoop up a few dollars and leaving no trace, no investment, nothing behind.

failure of imagination is how we get into these situations

3D printed buildings are in the news again…

[New Story] was started in 2015, shortly after Mr. Hagler took a trip to Haiti and saw families still living in tents years after the 2010 earthquake there. Across the globe, 1.6 billion people live with inadequate housing, according to Habitat for Humanity.

Anything is better than a tent over that kind of time span, and those 1.6 billion people live in all kinds of sub-standard structures that could be replaced by something more durable and safe.

Single-family homes are a good testing ground for the durability of 3-D printed construction because they are small and offer a repetitive design process without much height, said Henry D’Esposito, who leads construction research at JLL, a commercial real estate firm. They can also be constructed to tolerate natural disasters: Nacajuca sits in a seismic zone, and the homes there have already withstood a magnitude 7.4 earthquake.

Apartments/flats also offer those advantages, with the added challenge of fitting them together, but the added reward of better land use through greater density.

“It really is a very effective and efficient way to build a small segment of properties, but it’s not something that applies across the broader commercial real estate ecosystem,” Mr. D’Esposito said. “We don’t know exactly how these buildings will perform over decades or what the long-term value retention will be for them. So if you’re talking to an investor or lender, that’s a big yellow flag.”

That’s a weak argument that assumes single family homes are the be all and end all. There is no reason, other a failure of imagination, why these couldn’t be built as part of a larger structure, either on their own as bricks within that structure or suspended on some kind of metal skeleton.

It would be informative to compare the costs of a regular apartment building vs one assembled from modules from a machine like this. As described that’s a 1,000 sq ft unit but one could easily have different modules or varying sizes — a 500 sq foot core with additional suites or other spaces, all designed to fit together and then be added to a larger community.

3D printed houses solve a problem we don’t have

Does anyone still think construction costs or materials are the reason why affordable housing is such a thorny problem?

TALLAHASSEE, Fla. — The three-bedroom, two-bath home has a corduroy-patterned exterior, rounded corners — and a cement pour that oozed from an industrial-sized toothpaste tube. And most intriguing of all, it comes from a 3D printer.

When the house is finished around November, Kyndra and James Light, a husband-wife development team, will be asking between $175,000 and $225,000 for the 1,440-square-foot dwelling.

No mention of land in the piece…but I knew that before I checked. There never is. But that’s what’s needed, not new technology.

3D printing isn’t the solution because construction costs aren’t the problem. If someone were to apply this to a design like Habitat 67, that would be interesting. Print homes that are designed to fit together in a structure, stack them up, lather/rinse/repeat.

By Taxiarchos228, CC BY-SA 3.0, Link

Ugly? Maybe. But I’m sure improvements could be made, given that design is almost 60 years old. Or we could just try to replicate the single family home asset model.

Alexa, define “vigilante”

vigilante: a member of a volunteer committee organized to suppress and punish crime summarily (as when the processes of law are viewed as inadequate)

Seattle business attempts to clear homeless camp, backtracks after advocates step in
A Seattle business is facing heat from homeless advocacy groups after they attempted to clear out an encampment off of Lake City Way.

I have walked past this growing encampment for a couple of weeks. I expect it’s a lot of folks who were cleared out of the one in the mini-park at 30th and 125th, just a few blocks away.

“Apparently the people from Pierre decided that they didn’t want this anymore,” says Karen Whittle, an advocate for the homeless.

An attorney for Bill Pierre says his business, along with other businesses and residents in the community took matters into their own hands to clear out the encampment.

At least they admitted to it.

Their attorney sent this statement to KIRO 7, which reads in full; “The Pierre Family have been contributing members of the Lake City community for 74 years, the love for their community is generational and runs deep. They along with other community members made numerous pleas to the City and Police Department to help address issues like the vandalism, theft, property damage and threats of violence coming out of this encampment and were told that something like a shooting needs to occur before the City will respond. After hearing this several members of the business and residential community made the hard decision to come together and help clean up a non-permitted encampment filled with human excrement, rodents, criminal activity and used needles that were unsafe for everyone. The Pierre’s support was driven only by the love they have for the community in which they live and work.”

Not sure what contributions they refer to…I suppose they have paid their taxes like everyone else, and sold a lot of cars and trucks through their sprawling dealerships. I know Pierre Properties owns all of this:

And some of those lots are either vacant or abandoned, unused. The two parcels adjacent to the encampment (the two small pieces of the triangle, top right) are derelict, a few vehicles parked there but sometimes empty with no staff/employees. The largest of them, right across the street, is just under an acre in size and right on Lake City Way NE. It is assessed at $3,535,500 and taxed at just under $40,000/year. It’s empty. Not even used for commercial parking. What could a developer do with that, if the zoning permitted and the land value demanded it?

This is the solution to homelessness, not the solution that Pierre Properties felt compelled to enact by force. Land needs to be developed along busy developed roads in high commercial traffic areas. Today was the “1st annual custom car and motorcycle show” just a couple of blocks away from the scene of this incident (I wonder if the imminence of the show was part of this…) and it would be great if that land and the other disused parcels there were developed into something useful.

“If they’re allowed to get away with it other people will do it to other homeless encampments,” says Whittle. “Do something constructive rather than destructive. Give us a chance to show you that we can be neighbors.”

Opening up that land for development would be better. Do what the Seattle School District does with its disused parcels and rent it out: lower the cost to acquire the land and get some project underway.

Setting the rent might take some thinking. It’s not downtown but it is on a busy state highway in a commercial district surrounded by established neighborhoods. But surely we can expect more than $40,000 a year. The highest and best use of that land could be ten times that. The apartment building behind it pays $50,000/year for 1/4 the land. So why not set a ground rent of $200,000/year with a 1% annual increase? That would bring in $67,121,339.78 over the 99 year term, $677,993.33 annualized.

This is where Seattle’s progressive bona fides (legal weed, LGBTQ rights) aren’t enough to carry Seattle as a “progressive” city. It’s still, at heart, a propertarian city, where property rights outweigh human rights and land value is more important than land use that benefits all.

What the news reports don’t tell us is what exactly the propertarians did here. Did they physically move the belongings of the people in the encampment? Did they put their hands on people? Seems like anyone deeply concerned or committed to property rights would have a hard time squaring that kind of action with their beliefs. I never saw any reaction to the cars that have been parked along that street in the Before Times or the RVs that preceded the tents.

Again, if the issue is with tents — not necessarily people being reduced to living in those circumstances — housing is the solution. Social housing alongside market-rate housing could be built right across the street from where this mob decided to act on its worst impulses.